1
The economic development of the world’s richest countries is not a case of
liberalization and free trade, as many monetary organizations would have people believe,
but one of protectionism and state intervention. It was sustained through resource
extraction from conquered colonies and forced deindustrialization of the global South to
create a large market for manufactured goods. An emphasis is placed on both trade and
foreign direct investment (FDI) in the development process, and while they are important,
both are often misrepresented in the current framework. The Washington Consensus
claims that policies such as lowering exchange rates, increasing foreign direct investment
by lowering barriers, and reducing the role of the state must be adopted to ensure
economic growth. This emphasis on trade and lowering barriers ignores the context of
colonialism and its influence on economic growth historically. Although new courses for
inducing growth through liberalization have been postulated, it is apparent that those
policies vital to the significant and rapid economic development of the West have been
import substituting industrialization, protectionism, and the forced liberalization and
deindustrialization of the global South.
The role of trade and FDI in development is overstated in the current context because
of the influence colonialism had on economic growth in the West. The extraction of
natural resources prompted FDI, stimulating trade and supporting industrialization, as
well as creating a market for manufactured goods. The three decades leading up to World
War I (WWI) saw a rapid increase in international trade, growing nearly 3.5% per year
and output growth reaching 2.7% (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996). There was a
definite North-South dimension to this trade, and although developing countries benefited
somewhat from export growth and significant increases in capital flows, it was much less
than any currently developed country. Trade and resource endowments were critical
because they allowed for industrialization to occur and made protectionism a viable
policy. Industrialization is still seen as one of the most essential conditions for economic
development. In the United States in particular, import-substituting industrialization was
the main driver of growth in the post-Civil War period, with the average annual growth of
manufacturing reaching 5.1% (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996). Nearly two decades
later, this extraordinary growth was surpassed by Japan, “whose manufacturing sector
grew at annual rate of 9.0 percent” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 14). Policies
2
that allow for the viability of industrialization have been crucial to economic
development, although they must be supported by internal natural resources or imports,
and foster infant industry through protection.
The nature of protectionism as a driving force in economic development has been
entirely disregarded many contemporary economists and international organizations, such
as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. England was the first
country to industrialize and to begin protecting its infant industries, as early as the 15th
century (Pacheco-López and Thirlwall, 2009: pp. 6). Many other countries have followed
this model, including the United States, and more recently South Korea and Japan. The
acceleration of industrialization in the United States after the Civil War was accompanied
by high levels of protectionism with, “import duties averaging 45% for manufactured
goods,” and the highest rates reaching 60%,” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 7).
Occurring concurrently with import substituting industrialization, which was largely
possible due to resource endowments from colonies, rising barriers allowed industry to
grow until goods reached a point of superiority over external commodities. Recently, East
Asian countries, such as Japan and South Korea, “whose comparative advantage once lay
in rice”, were able to transform, “themselves into industrial power-houses,” through
direct state intervention and selective protection (Pacheco-López and Thirlwall, 2009: pp.
6-7). Protectionism has been the most critical policy for economic development. It has
allowed states to industrialize and build industry without overwhelming competition from
other actors. This was to a large extent possible because of trade based in colonialism and
resource endowments.
By far, the most important policies for creating rapid economic growth in the West
were those of forced deindustrialization and liberalization of the global South. As
industrialization accelerated, colonies became a source for natural resources and the main
market for manufactured goods. In the decades preceding WWI, “developing country
share of world manufacturing production declined from over one-third to under a tenth,”
(Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 16). This deindustrialization coincided exactly
with increasing international trade and the rapid growth of imports from Europe. Without
protectionist policies, much of the global South’s industry was destroyed, due to the mass
production and superior quality of Western goods. This was possible because of treaties
3
that had been imposed, “in the first half of the 19th century which entailed the elimination
of customs and duties,” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 8). Although there are
many examples across several continents of forced liberalization causing
deindustrialization, the most prominent was the destruction of the Indian textile industry.
Policies that endorsed free trade and liberalization in the global South were, by far, the
most effective in increasing economic development in the North. They decreased
manufacturing and allowed for both the resource endowments and a growing market for
final goods.
The rapid economic development of the West was manufactured through considerable
state intervention, culminating in high tariff barriers and industrialization fuelled by
natural resources from developing countries. The Washington Consensus upholds free
trade as a critical guideline for growth, reinforcing the liberalization of the global South
that allowed many currently developed countries to grow rich. Protectionism allowed
many countries, like the United States and Japan, to gain technological superiority while
forced liberalization through treaties and colonialism gave them a market for
manufactured goods, in turn destroying infant industry and furthering economic gain.
Industrialization and protectionism both played a vital role in promoting the economic
development of the West, but would have had a much smaller impact without the forced
liberalization and deindustrialization of the global South.
4
References
Bairoch, Paul and Kozul-Wright, Richard. (1996). "Globalization Myths: Some Historical
Reflections on Integration, Industrialization, and Growth in the World Economy,"
Discussion Paper no. 113, UNCTAD.
Carkovic, Maria V. and Levine, Ross. (2002). Does Foreign Direct Investment
Accelerate Economic Growth? U of Minnesota Department of Finance Working Paper
Hagen, Everett E. (1958). “An Economic Justification of Protectionism.” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 72, No. 4 (Nov., 1958), pp. 496-514
Pacheco-López, Penélope and Thirlwall, A. P. (2009). “Has Trade Liberalisation in Poor
Countries Delivered the Promises Expected?” School of Economics discussion papers,
No. 09,11
Rodrik, D., Grossman, G., and Norman, V. (1995). “Getting Interventions Right: How
South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich.” Economic Policy. Vol. 10, No. 20 (Apr., 1995),
pp. 53-107
West, G. P., Bamford, C. E. and Marsden, J. W. (2008). “Contrasting Entrepreneurial
Economic Development in Emerging Latin American Economies: Applications and
Extensions of Resource-Based Theory.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32: 15–
36

More Related Content

PPTX
International fianace side for presentation
PPTX
International fianace side for presentation
PDF
Export-Oriented Industrialization (EOI): Arguments for and Against What Have ...
PDF
Trade War - An Overview
PDF
Export-Oriented Industrialization (EOI): Arguments For and Against What Have ...
PDF
Development of china's foreign trade
PPTX
Economy of u.s.a
International fianace side for presentation
International fianace side for presentation
Export-Oriented Industrialization (EOI): Arguments for and Against What Have ...
Trade War - An Overview
Export-Oriented Industrialization (EOI): Arguments For and Against What Have ...
Development of china's foreign trade
Economy of u.s.a

What's hot (20)

PPT
international biz chapter 4
PDF
Report Rostow development theory
PPTX
Global Economy
PPTX
Temario Rivera's Landlords and Capitalists
PPTX
Import substitution (Wind Power)
DOCX
Import Substitution Vs Export Orientation; Case Study of Korean Economy
DOC
International business chapter 1
PPTX
Politics and economy
PPTX
A2 CAMBRIDGE GEOGRAPHY: GLOBAL INTERDEPENDENCE - TRADE FLOWS AND TRADING PATT...
PPTX
G2 - US vs. China
DOC
Chen Deming
PPTX
Lect 1 international trade and economic growth
PPTX
13.1 Global Interdependence: Trade flows and trading patterns
PPTX
TUL 560-12-2 Rostow's Stages to Capitalist Takeoff
PPTX
relation between economics and politics
DOCX
Rostow Stages of Economic Growth
PDF
Globalization, Trade, and Interdependence
PDF
Globalisation essay
PPTX
Trade Wars are the New Battleground - March 2018
PPTX
China facing 21st century
international biz chapter 4
Report Rostow development theory
Global Economy
Temario Rivera's Landlords and Capitalists
Import substitution (Wind Power)
Import Substitution Vs Export Orientation; Case Study of Korean Economy
International business chapter 1
Politics and economy
A2 CAMBRIDGE GEOGRAPHY: GLOBAL INTERDEPENDENCE - TRADE FLOWS AND TRADING PATT...
G2 - US vs. China
Chen Deming
Lect 1 international trade and economic growth
13.1 Global Interdependence: Trade flows and trading patterns
TUL 560-12-2 Rostow's Stages to Capitalist Takeoff
relation between economics and politics
Rostow Stages of Economic Growth
Globalization, Trade, and Interdependence
Globalisation essay
Trade Wars are the New Battleground - March 2018
China facing 21st century
Ad

Viewers also liked (20)

PPT
Oxford Brookes History MA Economic History Lecture 6/11/2007
PPTX
Economic Development 101
PPTX
Economic theories
POT
Economic development
PPTX
PPT
[SKARtec Digital Marketing Academy] - Operations Management
PPT
PDF
World Development Report 2011
PPTX
Economic Development
PPTX
OM GROUP PPT
PPT
Post war usa
PPTX
PPT
Industrial Age Economic Theories
PPTX
Open stax history_ch02 early globalization 1492-1650_imageslideshow.ppt
PDF
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
PPTX
Production management
PPTX
5.1 Development Economics Introduction
PPT
20 century art chapter 14
PPTX
Open stax history_ch23 americans and the great war, 1914-1919_imageslideshow.ppt
PPTX
Developmentalist theories of economic development
Oxford Brookes History MA Economic History Lecture 6/11/2007
Economic Development 101
Economic theories
Economic development
[SKARtec Digital Marketing Academy] - Operations Management
World Development Report 2011
Economic Development
OM GROUP PPT
Post war usa
Industrial Age Economic Theories
Open stax history_ch02 early globalization 1492-1650_imageslideshow.ppt
Strategic Local Economic Development: A Guide for Local Governments
Production management
5.1 Development Economics Introduction
20 century art chapter 14
Open stax history_ch23 americans and the great war, 1914-1919_imageslideshow.ppt
Developmentalist theories of economic development
Ad

Similar to The History of Economic Development in the West (20)

PDF
Developmental state and africa elly series 2013.Should Africa Learn from Asia...
DOCX
Industrialization in Bangladesh, Current status of industrialization of Bangl...
PDF
Presentatie German Calfat 4x4
DOCX
Another institution in the news is the G20. Established in 1999, the.docx
PPT
Newly Industrialised Countries
PPT
Newly Industrialised Countries
PDF
Causes and possible consequences of the us china trade war
PDF
3lb oz2blpp
PDF
The State and the Market in the Building of African Economies
PDF
Kicking Away the Ladder -- the “Real” History of Free Trade
DOCX
Globalization The Concept, Causes, and Consequences.docx
PDF
Asia shows to brazil ways of development
PPTX
G&P - Chapter 13 - International Development
PPTX
Economic Theories of Development presentation.pptx
DOCX
Kevin Hellestad Senior Paper Project FINAL
PDF
11.globalization and economic growth in india a granger causality approach
PDF
Globalization and economic growth in india a granger causality approach
PDF
Brazil sean-1
DOCX
PDF
Notes Global Poverty Presentation 15 May 08
Developmental state and africa elly series 2013.Should Africa Learn from Asia...
Industrialization in Bangladesh, Current status of industrialization of Bangl...
Presentatie German Calfat 4x4
Another institution in the news is the G20. Established in 1999, the.docx
Newly Industrialised Countries
Newly Industrialised Countries
Causes and possible consequences of the us china trade war
3lb oz2blpp
The State and the Market in the Building of African Economies
Kicking Away the Ladder -- the “Real” History of Free Trade
Globalization The Concept, Causes, and Consequences.docx
Asia shows to brazil ways of development
G&P - Chapter 13 - International Development
Economic Theories of Development presentation.pptx
Kevin Hellestad Senior Paper Project FINAL
11.globalization and economic growth in india a granger causality approach
Globalization and economic growth in india a granger causality approach
Brazil sean-1
Notes Global Poverty Presentation 15 May 08

The History of Economic Development in the West

  • 1. 1 The economic development of the world’s richest countries is not a case of liberalization and free trade, as many monetary organizations would have people believe, but one of protectionism and state intervention. It was sustained through resource extraction from conquered colonies and forced deindustrialization of the global South to create a large market for manufactured goods. An emphasis is placed on both trade and foreign direct investment (FDI) in the development process, and while they are important, both are often misrepresented in the current framework. The Washington Consensus claims that policies such as lowering exchange rates, increasing foreign direct investment by lowering barriers, and reducing the role of the state must be adopted to ensure economic growth. This emphasis on trade and lowering barriers ignores the context of colonialism and its influence on economic growth historically. Although new courses for inducing growth through liberalization have been postulated, it is apparent that those policies vital to the significant and rapid economic development of the West have been import substituting industrialization, protectionism, and the forced liberalization and deindustrialization of the global South. The role of trade and FDI in development is overstated in the current context because of the influence colonialism had on economic growth in the West. The extraction of natural resources prompted FDI, stimulating trade and supporting industrialization, as well as creating a market for manufactured goods. The three decades leading up to World War I (WWI) saw a rapid increase in international trade, growing nearly 3.5% per year and output growth reaching 2.7% (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996). There was a definite North-South dimension to this trade, and although developing countries benefited somewhat from export growth and significant increases in capital flows, it was much less than any currently developed country. Trade and resource endowments were critical because they allowed for industrialization to occur and made protectionism a viable policy. Industrialization is still seen as one of the most essential conditions for economic development. In the United States in particular, import-substituting industrialization was the main driver of growth in the post-Civil War period, with the average annual growth of manufacturing reaching 5.1% (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996). Nearly two decades later, this extraordinary growth was surpassed by Japan, “whose manufacturing sector grew at annual rate of 9.0 percent” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 14). Policies
  • 2. 2 that allow for the viability of industrialization have been crucial to economic development, although they must be supported by internal natural resources or imports, and foster infant industry through protection. The nature of protectionism as a driving force in economic development has been entirely disregarded many contemporary economists and international organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. England was the first country to industrialize and to begin protecting its infant industries, as early as the 15th century (Pacheco-López and Thirlwall, 2009: pp. 6). Many other countries have followed this model, including the United States, and more recently South Korea and Japan. The acceleration of industrialization in the United States after the Civil War was accompanied by high levels of protectionism with, “import duties averaging 45% for manufactured goods,” and the highest rates reaching 60%,” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 7). Occurring concurrently with import substituting industrialization, which was largely possible due to resource endowments from colonies, rising barriers allowed industry to grow until goods reached a point of superiority over external commodities. Recently, East Asian countries, such as Japan and South Korea, “whose comparative advantage once lay in rice”, were able to transform, “themselves into industrial power-houses,” through direct state intervention and selective protection (Pacheco-López and Thirlwall, 2009: pp. 6-7). Protectionism has been the most critical policy for economic development. It has allowed states to industrialize and build industry without overwhelming competition from other actors. This was to a large extent possible because of trade based in colonialism and resource endowments. By far, the most important policies for creating rapid economic growth in the West were those of forced deindustrialization and liberalization of the global South. As industrialization accelerated, colonies became a source for natural resources and the main market for manufactured goods. In the decades preceding WWI, “developing country share of world manufacturing production declined from over one-third to under a tenth,” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 16). This deindustrialization coincided exactly with increasing international trade and the rapid growth of imports from Europe. Without protectionist policies, much of the global South’s industry was destroyed, due to the mass production and superior quality of Western goods. This was possible because of treaties
  • 3. 3 that had been imposed, “in the first half of the 19th century which entailed the elimination of customs and duties,” (Bairoch and Kozul-Wright, 1996: pp. 8). Although there are many examples across several continents of forced liberalization causing deindustrialization, the most prominent was the destruction of the Indian textile industry. Policies that endorsed free trade and liberalization in the global South were, by far, the most effective in increasing economic development in the North. They decreased manufacturing and allowed for both the resource endowments and a growing market for final goods. The rapid economic development of the West was manufactured through considerable state intervention, culminating in high tariff barriers and industrialization fuelled by natural resources from developing countries. The Washington Consensus upholds free trade as a critical guideline for growth, reinforcing the liberalization of the global South that allowed many currently developed countries to grow rich. Protectionism allowed many countries, like the United States and Japan, to gain technological superiority while forced liberalization through treaties and colonialism gave them a market for manufactured goods, in turn destroying infant industry and furthering economic gain. Industrialization and protectionism both played a vital role in promoting the economic development of the West, but would have had a much smaller impact without the forced liberalization and deindustrialization of the global South.
  • 4. 4 References Bairoch, Paul and Kozul-Wright, Richard. (1996). "Globalization Myths: Some Historical Reflections on Integration, Industrialization, and Growth in the World Economy," Discussion Paper no. 113, UNCTAD. Carkovic, Maria V. and Levine, Ross. (2002). Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Economic Growth? U of Minnesota Department of Finance Working Paper Hagen, Everett E. (1958). “An Economic Justification of Protectionism.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 72, No. 4 (Nov., 1958), pp. 496-514 Pacheco-López, Penélope and Thirlwall, A. P. (2009). “Has Trade Liberalisation in Poor Countries Delivered the Promises Expected?” School of Economics discussion papers, No. 09,11 Rodrik, D., Grossman, G., and Norman, V. (1995). “Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich.” Economic Policy. Vol. 10, No. 20 (Apr., 1995), pp. 53-107 West, G. P., Bamford, C. E. and Marsden, J. W. (2008). “Contrasting Entrepreneurial Economic Development in Emerging Latin American Economies: Applications and Extensions of Resource-Based Theory.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32: 15– 36