6        Information and competitive tendering

         Gian Luigi Albano, Nicola Dimitri, Riccardo Pacini and
         Giancarlo Spagnolo



6.1. Introduction

         As stressed in the previous chapter by Bajari and Tadelis, it would be
         optimal for a procurer wishing to buy a sufficiently standardized, and
         contractually well-specifiable, good or service to elicit competition among
         potential suppliers. There are, however, many mechanisms she could use to
         elicit such competition. This chapter discusses and provides practical
         indications on how to choose between a sealed bid tendering and a dynamic
         auction to allocate procurement contracts between competing suppliers. It
         then suggests simple strategies to keep under control the duration of
         dynamic procurement auctions when this is a concern for the procurer.
            A crucial factor to consider in the optimal choice of a tendering format is
         the nature of uncertainty and the size of different types of costs the selected
         supplier will face when serving the contract. Therefore we begin with an
         example of such uncertain costs.
            Consider a procurement for cleaning services of a large company’s or
         public administration’s buildings. The contract may specify a variety of
         services including the cleaning of offices, corridors, halls and more
         demanding tasks such as the sanitation of laboratories. The contract also
         establishes that the contractor(s) will be paid a fixed amount of money per
         unit of surface (e/m2)1 regardless of the nature of the building. Therefore
         the unit price coincides across categories of surface, whereas the cost of


         The authors would like to thank Eric Van Damme for discussions and constructive comments on earlier
         versions of this chapter.
         1
             This is an example of fixed-price contract. The conditions under which such a contractual form may
             constitute the procurer’s optimal choice are investigated in Chapter 4. To simplify the exposition,
             throughout the chapter we shall also assume demand for service to be independent of the price at
             which the contract is awarded.

143
144   G.L. Albano, N. Dimitri, R. Pacini and G. Spagnolo



      performing the same task in different environments may vary substantially.
      The sanitation of a laboratory, for example, is presumably more time
      consuming and requires more expertise than cleaning an office furnished
      only with a desk and few bookshelves.
         When estimating the cost of performing the contract in order to place a
      bid for it, each supplier has to consider at least two different dimensions.
      The first dimension concerns the supplier’s efficiency in performing each
      single task specified in the contract. Efficiency results from the interaction of
      the personnel’s experience in similar tasks, managerial skills and the quality
      of the cleaning equipment. Thus the supplier’s efficiency captures a private
      component in his production cost. It is private in that it is entirely firm
      specific. The second dimension concerns the supplier’s ability to correctly
      estimate the mix of different tasks in the contract: cleaning few, large
      buildings with administrative offices requires a different combination of
      material and human resources than sanitizing a large number of small
      laboratories. If suppliers are not completely informed about the composi-
      tion of the demand for cleaning services at the time of bidding for the
      contract, they face a common uncertainty.
         Uncertainty about the common component of the cost of serving a
      contract matters since the contractor may find out that the ‘true’ cost of
      performing the contract differs from his initial estimate. This may happen if
      the contractor submitted a bid on the basis of too optimistic a forecast of
      the common component. More generally, if a supplier does not take this
      possibility into account at the time of bidding for the contract, he may
      suffer from the ‘winner’s curse’; that is, he may realize that actual pro-
      duction costs are higher than estimated ones. On the one hand, the danger
      of running losses ex post may induce suppliers to bid too cautiously for the
      contract, which implies potentially high awarding prices for the buyer. On
      the other hand, the suppliers’ inability to recognize the winner’s curse may
      generate a too aggressive bidding that results in low awarding prices for the
      buyer, but may induce the contractor to cut production costs by lowering
      the quality of the performance.
         In this chapter, we explain how the buyer can profit by inducing some
      ‘information production’ when uncertainty about the common component
      of the cost of serving a contract is relevant and when suppliers’ pieces of
      private information about the common component are (statistically) linked
      or correlated. The simple information-producing device is a dynamic
      auction format (section 6.3). A dynamic auction format, be it increasing
      in discounts/scores or decreasing in prices, allows each bidder to observe the
145     Information and competitive tendering



        identities of active competitors at different prices2 and, more important, the
        prices at which competitors quit the competition. Exiting times provide
        information about cost estimates of those bidders quitting the auction, thus
        helping remaining bidders revise their own estimates.
           When the nature of uncertainty concerns almost exclusively the private
        component of production costs, suppliers elaborate their bidding strategies
        on the basis of their private information only. Since learning is not an issue,
        the buyer can then adopt a sealed bid format that requires lower human and
        financial resources, is less exposed to the risk that suppliers collude, and has
        a duration that is perfectly determined (section 6.2). Auction length may
        become indeed a crucial issue in a dynamic format when bidders increase
        discounts (or lower prices) very slowly. In section 6.4, we will investigate
        how the buyer can streamline a dynamic auction without losing the benefits
        of information production.


6.2. Private and common dimensions in the cost function

        Several factors affect the cost of performing a procurement contract. Some
        of them are entirely firm specific while some others are common to all
        participating suppliers. A contract for supplying schools with heating oil
        involves different distribution costs depending on the distance between any
        single school and the location where a contractor stocks his oil reserves.
        Consequently, distribution costs are entirely firm specific. At the same time,
        when suppliers bid for the contract they are unable to predict the evolution
        of wholesale price for heating oil throughout the duration of the contract.
        Such an uncertainty is common in that it affects all suppliers.
           One simple way of capturing the private and common dimensions in the
        suppliers’ costs is by using the following general relation
        Cost = C(Private, Common)
        The relationship makes it clear that, in general, both components affect
        production costs, although the design of a procurement competitive ten-
        dering sometimes requires the buyer to establish which dimension is the
        more relevant, as we will see in the next two sections.


        2
            We are implicitly assuming that the open format takes the form of a Japanese auction rather than an
            English auction. See section 6.5 for the main features of these mechanisms.
146       G.L. Albano, N. Dimitri, R. Pacini and G. Spagnolo



          Table 6.1. PROPER’s costs with known common component

                                                                    A               B

          Reserve price                                                    70
          Private value component
          Estimated cleaning costs: (e/metre2)                     40               80
          Common value component with no uncertainty
          Surface to be cleaned: (metre2)                         30,000          10,000




6.2.1. The private component
          We consider again the contract for cleaning services, briefly discussed in the
          Introduction, and further develop it in order to illustrate how the private
          component in the suppliers’ production costs may affect their bidding for
          the contract. The contract for cleaning services comprises two main space
          categories; (A) offices and corridors and (B) laboratories. Table 6.1 sum-
          marizes the estimated costs per squared metre for PROPER Ltd (PROPER
          henceforth), one of the competing suppliers. The table also indicates the
          exact size of surfaces to be cleaned for both category A and B.l
             Thus we consider the simplest bidding environment where each supplier
          perfectly knows the composition of the final demand for cleaning services.
          Hence PROPER’s bid for the contract will depend only upon his (private)
          efficiency component and, arguably, upon his conjectures on other com-
          petitors’ efficiency levels. The cleaning contract for the two types of surface
          is awarded through a single-lot sealed-bid tendering process, with a reserve
          price of e70/m2, so that any bid above this level is rejected.
             PROPER’s cost for performing the contract is simply a weighted average
          of the two unit costs, where the weights reflect the fraction of each type of
          space in the contract,
          Unit Cost ¼ ðe40 · 30000 þ e80 · 10000Þ=40000 ¼ e50=m2
          PROPER can safely submit prices between e50 and e70, without losing
          money. The exact bid will depend on his conjectures about other compe-
          titors’ bids. For instance, if PROPER faces a group of rivals with large
          market shares and with an established reputation of high expertise in the
          business then he may anticipate intense competition for the contract. This
          would probably induce PROPER to bid closer to e50 than to e70.

More Related Content

PPTX
Cost Plus Contract
PDF
Type of Contracts.
PPTX
Presentation
PPTX
The Basics of Contracting
PPTX
rate contract
PPTX
PPT
Negotiating Carbon Trade & ERPA trabnsactions
PPTX
Contracts
Cost Plus Contract
Type of Contracts.
Presentation
The Basics of Contracting
rate contract
Negotiating Carbon Trade & ERPA trabnsactions
Contracts

What's hot (19)

PDF
Construction contract
PPT
Procurement Contract Types | PMP | iZenBridge - Webinar
PDF
09prc sg
PPS
Common contract types
PDF
Government Contracts 101 - Understanding the Basics of Contract Types
PPTX
Classification of contracts
DOC
Marginal costing synopsis
DOCX
2.12 procurement management 1
DOCX
Construction management 2
PPTX
Lump Sum Contract
PPTX
types of contracts
DOC
5.0 Subcontractor Selection Ass3 Sem2 '09
PPTX
Types of contracts
PPTX
Construction contract_Existing and Proposed Accounting Standards
PPT
Construction contracts docuements_08092008
PPTX
Construction contract
PPTX
Project Management-Project procurement Management
PPTX
Types and forms of contracts
Construction contract
Procurement Contract Types | PMP | iZenBridge - Webinar
09prc sg
Common contract types
Government Contracts 101 - Understanding the Basics of Contract Types
Classification of contracts
Marginal costing synopsis
2.12 procurement management 1
Construction management 2
Lump Sum Contract
types of contracts
5.0 Subcontractor Selection Ass3 Sem2 '09
Types of contracts
Construction contract_Existing and Proposed Accounting Standards
Construction contracts docuements_08092008
Construction contract
Project Management-Project procurement Management
Types and forms of contracts
Ad

Similar to Solo leer esto (20)

PPTX
1. Cost Modelling.pptx about life cycle costs
PDF
Can performance measurement systems be used to measure effectiveness of the p...
PDF
Mark-Jahn.Online-Auctions
PDF
Handbook of Procurement (Nicola Dimitrig
PDF
An agile cost_estimating_methodology_for_aerospace_procurement
DOCX
Project Management 2nd assignment
PDF
Economic model to determine the lowest price limit of fixed price contracts i...
PPT
Chapter 16
PDF
DYNAMICS OF GOVERNMENT CONTRACTING: PROPOSALS FOR EFFICIENCY AND SATISFACTION...
PDF
Pai 3-03
PDF
Privatization and Quality: Evidence from Elderly Care in Sweden
PDF
Advance 1020 1045
PDF
Price: Its Nature, Developing pricing strategy
PDF
1.benchmarking procurement
PDF
The International Journal of Engineering and Science (The IJES)
PDF
A Fuzzy Arithmetic Approach for Perishable Items in Discounted Entropic Order...
PPT
Recoverd ppt file(4)
PDF
Improving the efficiency of public procurement
PDF
INDAS2.pdf
PDF
Week12 Decision Support in E-Business Auctions.pdf
1. Cost Modelling.pptx about life cycle costs
Can performance measurement systems be used to measure effectiveness of the p...
Mark-Jahn.Online-Auctions
Handbook of Procurement (Nicola Dimitrig
An agile cost_estimating_methodology_for_aerospace_procurement
Project Management 2nd assignment
Economic model to determine the lowest price limit of fixed price contracts i...
Chapter 16
DYNAMICS OF GOVERNMENT CONTRACTING: PROPOSALS FOR EFFICIENCY AND SATISFACTION...
Pai 3-03
Privatization and Quality: Evidence from Elderly Care in Sweden
Advance 1020 1045
Price: Its Nature, Developing pricing strategy
1.benchmarking procurement
The International Journal of Engineering and Science (The IJES)
A Fuzzy Arithmetic Approach for Perishable Items in Discounted Entropic Order...
Recoverd ppt file(4)
Improving the efficiency of public procurement
INDAS2.pdf
Week12 Decision Support in E-Business Auctions.pdf
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

DOCX
Handbook of entrepreneurship- Chapter 10 - Feasibility analysis by Subin K Mohan
PPTX
Enterprises are Classified into Two Categories
PDF
Nante Industrial Plug Socket Connector Sustainability Insights
PDF
The Influence of Historical Figures on Legal Communication (www.kiu.ac.ug)
PPT
BCG内部幻灯片撰写. slide template BCG.slide template
PDF
Chembond Chemicals Limited Presentation 2025
PPTX
PwC consulting Powerpoint Graphics 2014 templates
PDF
COVID-19 Primer for business case prep.pdf
PDF
The Impact of Immigration on National Identity (www.kiu.ac.ug)
PDF
The Impact of Policy Changes on Legal Communication Strategies (www.kiu.ac.ug)
PPTX
Hospitality & tourism management.pptxHospitality & tourism management.pptx
PPTX
Biomass_Energy_PPT_FIN AL________________.pptx
PPTX
OS ALL UNITS MATxtdtc5ctc5cycgctERIAL.pptx
PDF
The Dynamic CLOs Shaping the Future of the Legal Industry in 2025.pdf
PDF
Не GPT єдиним: можливості AI в бізнес-аналізі | Вебінар з Тетяною Перловською
 
PDF
BeMetals_Presentation_September_2025.pdf
PPTX
Side hustles: 14 powerful tips to embrace the future of work
PDF
Handouts for Housekeeping.pdfhsjsnvvbdjsnwb
PDF
757557697-CERTIKIT-ISO22301-Implementation-Guide-v6.pdf
PDF
Handouts for Housekeeping.pdfbababvsvvNnnh
Handbook of entrepreneurship- Chapter 10 - Feasibility analysis by Subin K Mohan
Enterprises are Classified into Two Categories
Nante Industrial Plug Socket Connector Sustainability Insights
The Influence of Historical Figures on Legal Communication (www.kiu.ac.ug)
BCG内部幻灯片撰写. slide template BCG.slide template
Chembond Chemicals Limited Presentation 2025
PwC consulting Powerpoint Graphics 2014 templates
COVID-19 Primer for business case prep.pdf
The Impact of Immigration on National Identity (www.kiu.ac.ug)
The Impact of Policy Changes on Legal Communication Strategies (www.kiu.ac.ug)
Hospitality & tourism management.pptxHospitality & tourism management.pptx
Biomass_Energy_PPT_FIN AL________________.pptx
OS ALL UNITS MATxtdtc5ctc5cycgctERIAL.pptx
The Dynamic CLOs Shaping the Future of the Legal Industry in 2025.pdf
Не GPT єдиним: можливості AI в бізнес-аналізі | Вебінар з Тетяною Перловською
 
BeMetals_Presentation_September_2025.pdf
Side hustles: 14 powerful tips to embrace the future of work
Handouts for Housekeeping.pdfhsjsnvvbdjsnwb
757557697-CERTIKIT-ISO22301-Implementation-Guide-v6.pdf
Handouts for Housekeeping.pdfbababvsvvNnnh

Solo leer esto

  • 1. 6 Information and competitive tendering Gian Luigi Albano, Nicola Dimitri, Riccardo Pacini and Giancarlo Spagnolo 6.1. Introduction As stressed in the previous chapter by Bajari and Tadelis, it would be optimal for a procurer wishing to buy a sufficiently standardized, and contractually well-specifiable, good or service to elicit competition among potential suppliers. There are, however, many mechanisms she could use to elicit such competition. This chapter discusses and provides practical indications on how to choose between a sealed bid tendering and a dynamic auction to allocate procurement contracts between competing suppliers. It then suggests simple strategies to keep under control the duration of dynamic procurement auctions when this is a concern for the procurer. A crucial factor to consider in the optimal choice of a tendering format is the nature of uncertainty and the size of different types of costs the selected supplier will face when serving the contract. Therefore we begin with an example of such uncertain costs. Consider a procurement for cleaning services of a large company’s or public administration’s buildings. The contract may specify a variety of services including the cleaning of offices, corridors, halls and more demanding tasks such as the sanitation of laboratories. The contract also establishes that the contractor(s) will be paid a fixed amount of money per unit of surface (e/m2)1 regardless of the nature of the building. Therefore the unit price coincides across categories of surface, whereas the cost of The authors would like to thank Eric Van Damme for discussions and constructive comments on earlier versions of this chapter. 1 This is an example of fixed-price contract. The conditions under which such a contractual form may constitute the procurer’s optimal choice are investigated in Chapter 4. To simplify the exposition, throughout the chapter we shall also assume demand for service to be independent of the price at which the contract is awarded. 143
  • 2. 144 G.L. Albano, N. Dimitri, R. Pacini and G. Spagnolo performing the same task in different environments may vary substantially. The sanitation of a laboratory, for example, is presumably more time consuming and requires more expertise than cleaning an office furnished only with a desk and few bookshelves. When estimating the cost of performing the contract in order to place a bid for it, each supplier has to consider at least two different dimensions. The first dimension concerns the supplier’s efficiency in performing each single task specified in the contract. Efficiency results from the interaction of the personnel’s experience in similar tasks, managerial skills and the quality of the cleaning equipment. Thus the supplier’s efficiency captures a private component in his production cost. It is private in that it is entirely firm specific. The second dimension concerns the supplier’s ability to correctly estimate the mix of different tasks in the contract: cleaning few, large buildings with administrative offices requires a different combination of material and human resources than sanitizing a large number of small laboratories. If suppliers are not completely informed about the composi- tion of the demand for cleaning services at the time of bidding for the contract, they face a common uncertainty. Uncertainty about the common component of the cost of serving a contract matters since the contractor may find out that the ‘true’ cost of performing the contract differs from his initial estimate. This may happen if the contractor submitted a bid on the basis of too optimistic a forecast of the common component. More generally, if a supplier does not take this possibility into account at the time of bidding for the contract, he may suffer from the ‘winner’s curse’; that is, he may realize that actual pro- duction costs are higher than estimated ones. On the one hand, the danger of running losses ex post may induce suppliers to bid too cautiously for the contract, which implies potentially high awarding prices for the buyer. On the other hand, the suppliers’ inability to recognize the winner’s curse may generate a too aggressive bidding that results in low awarding prices for the buyer, but may induce the contractor to cut production costs by lowering the quality of the performance. In this chapter, we explain how the buyer can profit by inducing some ‘information production’ when uncertainty about the common component of the cost of serving a contract is relevant and when suppliers’ pieces of private information about the common component are (statistically) linked or correlated. The simple information-producing device is a dynamic auction format (section 6.3). A dynamic auction format, be it increasing in discounts/scores or decreasing in prices, allows each bidder to observe the
  • 3. 145 Information and competitive tendering identities of active competitors at different prices2 and, more important, the prices at which competitors quit the competition. Exiting times provide information about cost estimates of those bidders quitting the auction, thus helping remaining bidders revise their own estimates. When the nature of uncertainty concerns almost exclusively the private component of production costs, suppliers elaborate their bidding strategies on the basis of their private information only. Since learning is not an issue, the buyer can then adopt a sealed bid format that requires lower human and financial resources, is less exposed to the risk that suppliers collude, and has a duration that is perfectly determined (section 6.2). Auction length may become indeed a crucial issue in a dynamic format when bidders increase discounts (or lower prices) very slowly. In section 6.4, we will investigate how the buyer can streamline a dynamic auction without losing the benefits of information production. 6.2. Private and common dimensions in the cost function Several factors affect the cost of performing a procurement contract. Some of them are entirely firm specific while some others are common to all participating suppliers. A contract for supplying schools with heating oil involves different distribution costs depending on the distance between any single school and the location where a contractor stocks his oil reserves. Consequently, distribution costs are entirely firm specific. At the same time, when suppliers bid for the contract they are unable to predict the evolution of wholesale price for heating oil throughout the duration of the contract. Such an uncertainty is common in that it affects all suppliers. One simple way of capturing the private and common dimensions in the suppliers’ costs is by using the following general relation Cost = C(Private, Common) The relationship makes it clear that, in general, both components affect production costs, although the design of a procurement competitive ten- dering sometimes requires the buyer to establish which dimension is the more relevant, as we will see in the next two sections. 2 We are implicitly assuming that the open format takes the form of a Japanese auction rather than an English auction. See section 6.5 for the main features of these mechanisms.
  • 4. 146 G.L. Albano, N. Dimitri, R. Pacini and G. Spagnolo Table 6.1. PROPER’s costs with known common component A B Reserve price 70 Private value component Estimated cleaning costs: (e/metre2) 40 80 Common value component with no uncertainty Surface to be cleaned: (metre2) 30,000 10,000 6.2.1. The private component We consider again the contract for cleaning services, briefly discussed in the Introduction, and further develop it in order to illustrate how the private component in the suppliers’ production costs may affect their bidding for the contract. The contract for cleaning services comprises two main space categories; (A) offices and corridors and (B) laboratories. Table 6.1 sum- marizes the estimated costs per squared metre for PROPER Ltd (PROPER henceforth), one of the competing suppliers. The table also indicates the exact size of surfaces to be cleaned for both category A and B.l Thus we consider the simplest bidding environment where each supplier perfectly knows the composition of the final demand for cleaning services. Hence PROPER’s bid for the contract will depend only upon his (private) efficiency component and, arguably, upon his conjectures on other com- petitors’ efficiency levels. The cleaning contract for the two types of surface is awarded through a single-lot sealed-bid tendering process, with a reserve price of e70/m2, so that any bid above this level is rejected. PROPER’s cost for performing the contract is simply a weighted average of the two unit costs, where the weights reflect the fraction of each type of space in the contract, Unit Cost ¼ ðe40 · 30000 þ e80 · 10000Þ=40000 ¼ e50=m2 PROPER can safely submit prices between e50 and e70, without losing money. The exact bid will depend on his conjectures about other compe- titors’ bids. For instance, if PROPER faces a group of rivals with large market shares and with an established reputation of high expertise in the business then he may anticipate intense competition for the contract. This would probably induce PROPER to bid closer to e50 than to e70.