BROWN BOOK
                                                                                                                                                    ANDRÉS DOMINGO AND DOMÉNECH VILARIÑO /




                                                                                                                  XXVIII EDICIÓN DEL LIBRO MARRÓN
                                                                           The Future of the Euro
                                                                                                                                                    DÍEZ GANGAS / DONGES /
                                                                                                                                                    GARCÍA ANDRÉS / GROS Y ALCIDI /
                                                                                                                                                    MARTÍNEZ RICO / REQUEIJO GONZÁLEZ /
                                                                                                                                                    SÁNCHEZ FUENTES, HAUPTMEIER AND SCHUKNECHT /




 BROWN EDITION BOOK XXVIII                                                                                                                           The Future of the Euro
                                                                                                                                                    El futuro del euro
The Brown Book in 2012 meets his XXVIII edition. Year after year since
1984, this flagship publication of the Círculo de Empresarios has offe-
red the most varied backgrounds a platform from which to contribute
their ideas and proposals on economic policy that requires our
country to its further development. The Brown Book contributes to one
of the founding objectives of the Círculo as the center of the view that
encourages and promotes debate on key issues for the benefit of
Spanish society as a whole.




                                                                                                                  JULIO 2012
  CÍRCULO DE EMPRESARIOS
  C/ MARQUÉS DE VILLAMAGNA, 3, 10ª. 28001 MADRID
  TEL 915781472. FAX 915774871
  www.circulodeempresarios.org
                                                                                                    July 2012
The Future of the Euro

Brown Book
Madrid, July 2012




EDITION SPONSORED BY
© 2012, Círculo de Empresarios
C/ Marqués de Villamagna, 3, 28001 Madrid


The partial or total reproduction of this publication, or its hand-
ling by software, or its transmission under any circumstance or
by any means, whether electronic, mechanical, by photocopies,
recording or other means, without the express written consent
of the copyright holders, is strictly forbidden.


The articles reflect the opinions of the contributors, and not
necessarily those held by Círculo de Empresarios.




Legal deposit: M-24161-2012
Design of collection: Miryam Anllo
m.anllo@telefonica.net
Illustration: María José Ruiz
Publishing: Loft Producción Gráfica
C/ Martín Machío, 15-1º. 28002 Madrid (Spain)
Printed by Atig, S.L.
Parque Empresarial Neinor - Henares
edificio 3 - nave 10



4
The Future of the Euro



                                                    Index


Prologue                                             7




1. The future of the Euro
   after the Great Recession                         15
   Javier Andrés and Rafael Domenech


2. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis              63
   José Carlos Díez


3. The European crisis and the challenge
   of efficient economic governance                  97
   Juergen B. Donges


4. The turbulent adolescence of the euro
   and its path to maturity                          131
   Gonzalo García Andrés


5. Breaking the common fate of banks
   and governments                                   197
   Daniel Gros and Cinzia Alcidi




                                                          5
6. The fiscal institution in the
    Economic and Monetary Union:
    the contribution of Spain               227
    Ricardo Martínez Rico


7. The European Monetary Union:
    the Never-Ending Crisis                 265
    Jaime Requeijo


8. Public expenditure policies during the
    EMU period: Lessons for the future?     289
    A. Jesús Sánchez Fuentes,
    Sebastian Hauptmeier
    and Ludger Schuknecht




6
Prologue



   The crisis in Spain is, to a large extent, the crisis of the Euro. On
the one hand, the sustainability or otherwise of the monetary inte-
gration project hinges on Spain, as the fourth economy in the
Eurozone. On the other, Spain has no leeway available for fiscal sti-
mulus packages, and the success of its adjustments required stabi-
lity in the Eurozone. Hence, both crises are the two sides of the
same token.


   The crisis faced by Euro economies and the adjustments made
and which will be made in the most vulnerable ones, are coming at
a high price which has not yielded tangible results to date. Círculo
de Empresarios believes that the current situation calls for an impro-
vement in European institutional architecture, in regard to greater
integration and, above all, more commitment to reforms in Spain.
The natural environment of our country is the Eurozone.


   Over the last few weeks, citizens are beginning to live with the
different rescue modalities, as they had already done with the risk
premiums. Financial aid for troubled economies is quite diverse in
terms of implications, instrumentation, conditionality and scope of
application, therefore requiring detailed analysis for determination.
Although each carries its benefits and disadvantages, in the opi-


                                                                       7
nion of Círculo de Empresarios, the greater scope and conditionality
scenarios – known as country-rescue – are not a desirable option.
This is why these must be avoided.


    Indeed, an intervention or rescue, of its own accord, without
advancements made in the Eurozone architecture, shall not protect
any of its members from future scares. Domestic adjustment may
be less effective if no advancements are made in fiscal and banking
union, and in the European capacity to provide asymmetrical res-
ponses to national situations which are also different. The most
vulnerable countries in the Eurozone must no longer be perceived
as foreign currency debtors and it is imperative that the coordina-
tion of economic policies of Member States is improved. Without
such adjustments, a sustained growth path will not be possible to
achieve.


    On the other hand, the crisis in Spain is the result of an accu-
mulation of imbalances due to a series of inadequate signals and
policies. Spain must face up to its responsibilities in terms of fiscal
consolidation and structural reform. All in the interest of recove-
ring competitiveness and encouraging a suitable environment to
attract growth-contributing investments.


    In such circumstances, Círculo de Empresarios cannot help but
take part in the debate on the future of the Euro. The XXVIII edi-
tion of the Brown Book is dedicated to this matter and gathers a
varied number of authors, all with broad experience in the issue


8
and proven academic and professional records. Therefore, this
publication, with the sponsorship of BBVA as in previous years,
maintains its nature as a publication which is open to different
ideas and opinions, not necessarily shared by Círculo de Empresarios.


   As in previous editions, the articles appear in alphabetical order
by the surnames of their authors, although these can be grouped
into three broad categories: the crisis of the sovereign debt in
Europe and the future of the Eurozone; the reform of economic
governance and operations of the institutions in order to solve the
sovereign debt crisis in Europe; and the integration into the
Eurozone, the fiscal coordination mechanisms, Eurobonds and the
assignment of sovereignty.


   In their paper, Javier Andrés and Rafael Doménech analyse
the challenges faced by the Eurozone and the proposals to handle
them by improving economic governance. To this end, they begin
by reviewing the reasons underlying the accumulation of signifi-
cant imbalances in developed economies and among EMU coun-
tries, mainly from 2001 until the start of the crisis in 2007, as a
result of an unsustainable growth pattern in many developed eco-
nomies. Secondly, the magnitude and implications of such imba-
lances and the heterogeneity between EMU countries are closely
examined. Finally, the authors analyse the challenges involved in
the improvement of economic governance of the EMU on the fis-
cal, financial and economic integration fronts, which will determi-
ne its short and long term economic future.


                                                                    9
José Carlos Díez analyses the Euro crisis. He reviews the histori-
cal background of the European and single currency projects, and
the theory of exchange rates to provide conceptual support to ena-
ble an understanding of the nature and the causes of the crisis.
According to him, this is an infrequent, but highly destructive, dise-
ase found in economics, especially in developed countries, since it
causes devastating damage to the employment and public debt of
the affected countries. For this reason, he believes it is essential to
come up with the correct diagnosis in order to define the economic
policy that will put an end to the crisis. The main causes analysed
are financial integration, the under-assessment of risk, local imba-
lances within the Eurozone and the Great Recession.


     The aim of Juergen B. Donges is to bring the current debate on
the need for economic governance in the European Union, and par-
ticularly in the Eurozone, into the context of political realities. He
analyses the issue of governance from a historical and current pers-
pective, and highlights the significant fact that the Eurozone does
not constitute an optimal monetary area. He then moves on to
analyse the forms of governance to date and considers new approa-
ches to European governance. Finally, he ends his analysis with a
tone of moderate expectation. If the Governments of the Euro countries
understand that the solidity of public finances and the application of struc-
tural reforms are their responsibility and act in accordance, no State must
rush to the aid of another due to over-indebtedness and overspending, and
the ECB may stop indirectly funding the States and focus on its own duty,
which is to ensure the stability of the price levels within the Eurozone.


10
Gonzalo García Andrés highlights that, despite having taken
decisive steps in national policies and institutional framework
reform, the Euro crisis has worsened to the point of calling its sur-
vival into question; and no definitive solution is yet on the hori-
zon. In his article he attempts to offer an interpretation of what has
happened, assuming the extreme complexity both of the starting
point (with accumulated imbalances and structural deficiencies in
several countries), as of the outbreak, the contagion and the esca-
lation of the crisis. And he does so in the broader context of the
global financial crisis, which has affected economic and financial
development for five years, in order to determine which specific
aspects of the Euro have played a key role. All this with a view to
encouraging a reflection on solutions, bringing together the most
urgent and the ones with a longer term effect.


   Cinzia Alcidi and Daniel Gros point out that the Eurozone cri-
sis encompasses different dimensions, from foreign debt and
current account balance problems, to the weak situation of the ban-
king sector. The document focuses on this last issue, the situation
of the banking system, and attempts to show the way in which
current characteristics of the regulatory framework of the financial
market have influenced the development of the crisis. In addition,
they express their concern about the false idea that the recently sig-
ned fiscal convention shall become the fundamental ingredient of
the recipe to overcome the crisis, when the banking sector conti-
nues to be heavily indebted and exposed to the vicissitudes of sove-
reign States. For this reason, they present a few ideas to break the


                                                                    11
close ties between governments and banks, since these links them
in a common fate and constitute a clear impediment to recovery
from the crisis in the Eurozone.


     Ricardo Martínez Rico, throughout his work, analyses the way
in which the sustainability of public finances requires a sold fiscal
institution and a firm political commitment by European govern-
ments. Subsequently, he tackles the close relationship between fis-
cal rigour, macroeconomic stability and growth, concluding that, in
order to achieve a positive inter-relation, the establishment of fiscal
rules which are simple, transparent, automatically applied and with
preventive control mechanisms for all Public Administrations, is
essential. All these items are key when designing a fiscal policy
which contributes to recovering the credibility required by Europe
along its route towards greater integration to handle the sovereign
debt crisis. Lastly, he examines the measures taken in Europe and
Spain since the start of the sovereign debt crisis, and reflects on the
next steps that should be taken towards a fiscal institution.


     The work of Jaime Requeijo aims to provide a reasoned expla-
nation of the causes of the financial shocks affecting several
Eurozone countries, and which endanger the survival of the single
currency (the Monetary Union is a poorly built structure because
political urgency has prevailed over economic prudence; the fiscal
irresponsibility of many member state governments has translated
into the appearance of large public debt; such debts generate
doubts as to their holders; and, contributing factors such as the


12
effects of contagion or of the opinions of the rating agencies and
IMF predictions). In the article he also attempts to reply to three
questions on the measures taken, the results thereof, and the
impact of a potential decomposition of the euro. The article ends
with a brief final reflection on the solution to be applied in order
to maintain the Monetary Union.


   A. Jesús Sánchez-Fuentes, Sebastian Hauptmeier and Ludger
Schuknecht state in their article that an ambitious fiscal reform
within a broader programme of reforms would have highly positi-
ve effects insofar as it would provide for a safer fiscal position, in
line with the requirements of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP).
Expenditure control policies must therefore go hand in hand with
structural reforms, mainly focused on reducing rigidity in the
labour and product markets, on the correction of macroeconomic
imbalances, on the improvement of competitiveness and on sus-
taining potential growth. This becomes particularly key for the
most vulnerable countries in the Eurozone, which no longer have
the option of currency devaluation to increase competitiveness.


   Finally, and on behalf of Círculo de Empresarios, I wish to thank
all the authors for their contributions to this new edition of the
Brown Book and I trust that these articles help to shed light on a
solution to the European trilemma.


                                                    Mónica de Oriol
                                   President of Círculo de Empresarios


                                                                    13
/JAVIER ANDRES * / RAFAEL DOMENECH**/




                                     The future of the Euro
                                after the Great Recession                                 1




Summary; 1. Introduction; 2. From the Great Moderation to the Great
Recession; 3. The imbalances in Europe and in the EMU; 4. The new
European governance and the future of the Euro; 4.1. Changes in fiscal
governance; 4.2. Financial integration; 4.3. Economic integration; 5.
Conclusions.


Summary


In this chapter we shall analyse the challenges the Eurozone is facing and

proposals to deal with them via improved economic governance. To do so,



* Javier Andrés is professor of Fundamentals of Economic Analysis at the University of
Valencia and visiting professor of the University of Glasgow. http://iei.uv.es/javierandres/
** Rafael Doménech is Chief Economist of Developed Economies, BBVA Research and
Professor of Fundamentals of Economic Analysis at the University of Valencia.
http://iei.uv.es/rdomenec


1 The authors thank A. Deligiannido, A. García, M. Jiménez, and E. Prades for their assis-
tance and comments on this work, as well as the help from CICYT projects ECO2008-
04669 and ECO2011-29050.



                                                                                 15
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


we shall first examine the reasons behind the accumulation of significant

imbalances in the developed economies and among the EMU countries,

mainly since 2001 until the crisis in 2007, as a result of a pattern of unsus-

tainable growth in many developed economies. Secondly, we shall offer an

in-depth analysis of the significance of such imbalances and the heteroge-

neity which exists between EMU countries. Lastly, we shall study the cha-

llenges presented by the improvement of the economic governance of the

EMU from a fiscal, financial and economic integration perspective, which

shall determine its economic future in the short and long term.



1. Introduction

     The international economic crisis which begun in 2007 is
having an extraordinary impact on the European economy, and for
the coming decades, will leave a deep mark in many of its mem-
bers. The crisis has shown that the growth process undergone bet-
ween 1994 and 2007, particularly following the creation of the
Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) in 1999, had entered into
an unsustainable dynamics in the long term. The appearance of
important macroeconomic imbalances among EMU members was
taking shape within the framework of steady growth, inflation
under control, very low interest rates and a very reduced risk assess-
ment (partly as a result of the disappearance of currency risk) in the
context of a world saving glut. Although the Eurozone as a whole
presents smaller aggregate imbalances in terms of deficit and pri-
vate, public and foreign debt than, for instance, the US or the
United Kingdom, the expectations of economic convergence


16
The Future of the Euro


among Eurozone countries and the appearance of financial bubbles
with the promise of high yields, led to very significant capital flows
among its members. This added to a spiralling increase in house-
hold debt and businesses in some of the member countries, gene-
rating very considerable and longstanding deficits in current
account balances. These expectations petered out sharply as of the
subprime crisis of 2007 and, since then, Europe has been experien-
cing different surges of financial crises, economic crises and sove-
reign debt crises, which have been following on and feeding off
each other over time.2 The result of this complex situation has been
that, albeit with differences in the intensity and the severity of the
problems (see, for instance, Doménech and Jiménez, 2010), a sig-
nificant number of European countries have experienced a situa-
tion similar to that of the sudden stops experienced in the past by
some emerging economies, leaving public and private sectors heavily
indebted and, in some cases, extremely high rates of unemployment.


  The aim of this chapter is to analyse the changes required by the
EMU and proposals with which to face such challenges with suc-
cess. In order to understand what the problems are and, therefore,
their possible solutions, in the second section we analyse the rea-
sons why important imbalances accumulated in the developed eco-
nomies and among the EMU countries during one of the most sta-
ble periods of economic prosperity in the last decades (the Great
Moderation), which nevertheless gave way to an unsustainable

2 Shambaugh (2012) performs an excellent analysis of the interaction between fiscal,
financial and economic crises in the Eurozone.



                                                                          17
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


growth pattern in many economies. In the third section, we offer
an in-depth analysis of the magnitude and implications of such
imbalances throughout the crisis, which are well summarised in the
Excessive Imbalance Procedure (EIP) recently implemented by the
EU, as well as the current heterogeneity among EMU countries. The
fourth section analyses the challenges of improvement of economic
governance of the EMU from a fiscal, financial and economic inte-
gration standpoint, which shall determine its short and long term
economic future. Lastly, the fifth section presents the main conclu-
sions reached in this paper.




2. From the Great Moderation to the Great Recession

     In the period between the mid-1990s and 2007, developed eco-
nomies enjoyed one of the greatest economic growth periods,
known as the Great Moderation due to the low volatility of growth
rates in those years. Graph 1 shows evidence of this for the US and
the EMU in terms of GDP per person of employable age. As can be
seen, from the mid-1990s to 2007 there was sustained growth, with
levels well above the historical trend estimated since 1970 for both
geographical areas. In fact, the growth in GSP per person of emplo-
yable age was slightly higher in the EMU than in the US, although
not enough to bridge the gap between both economies.


     The Great Moderation generated the perception that economic
cycles would have less volatility, as a result of better managed eco-


18
The Future of the Euro


nomic policy (see, for instance, Galí and Gambeti, 2009, or the
references appearing in this article). In fact, these high growth rates
with low volatility came hand in hand with inflation under con-
trol and low interest rates across the board of financial assets, with
practically inexistent risk premiums in many cases as a result of the
underassessment of the risk. In light thereof, some analysts went as
far as to proclaim the disappearance of the economic cycle and the
capacity to avoid significant economic recessions. It was the com-
binations of these forces which fed the financial imbalances which,
for economists like Rajan (2005) or Borio & White (2005), among
others, are behind the crisis which began in 2007.


   There are various economic factors which contributed to genera-
te this combination on which the Great Moderation was erected. In
the first place, the central banks of the developed economies carried
out a low interest rate policy or money glut, as a result of: i) the drop
in the inflation of sellable assets following the inrush of exporting
countries in the international economy with a very abundant and
cheap workforce and depreciated currencies; ii) the benign neglect
policy in regard to the high prices of financial and real estate assets
(Bordo & Jeane, 2002, or Bean 2004 & 2010); and iii) the attempt to
prevent the recession in the US, following the burst of the techno-
logical bubble, or in Germany, following the costly process of reu-
nification and the burst of its real estate bubble.


   Secondly a savings glut took place on a worldwide level in
China, Japan, Germany, oil producing countries or the pension


                                                                       19
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


funds of developed economies.


     Thirdly, and as a response the savings glut in some countries
and sectors, a formidable increase took place in the demand of safe
assets, moving from the pre-eminence of individual savers to that
of large sovereign funds, investment funds or pension funds which
prioritize safety over yield and which seek to channel savings
towards fixed income rather than towards the acquisition of any
other kind of asset. At the same time that the demand for safe
financial assets (i.e. AAA) increased, there was a relative scarcity of
such assets in the case of sovereign debt, due to the fiscal consoli-


     Chart 1
     GDP per person of employable age in the US and in the EMU




     Source: OEDC (2012) Economic Outlook Database.




20
The Future of the Euro


dation taking place simultaneous in many developed economies as
a result of the high growth in GDP. This surplus demand for safe
assets created enormous pressure in the financial markets and in
certain types of assets, which in turn led to the appearance of bub-
bles in certain market segments. The pressure was such that finan-
cial deregulation and engineering came to the rescue, enabling the
response of the financial markets to this scarcity in AAA assets to
be the creation of multiple derivatives and the issue of huge volu-
mes of asset backed securities, as shown in Graph 2. In turn, this
generated enormous liquidity to fund those assets acting as the
underlying assets (for example, mortgages on homes), thus crea-

   Chart 2
   Issue of Asset backed Securities 1985-2011




  Source: SIFMA




                                                                   21
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


ting a circle in which asset demand stimulated supply, which in
turn was fed back into the process by boosting demand with the
creation of new assets.


     As a result of this process, a specialization in asset production
took place on an international level, leading to enormous hetero-
geneity by country, sector and agents. Whereas some countries
generated a surplus in net savings, others (US, Spain or Ireland) res-
ponded to the very low interest rate incentive by generating the
real investments which served as the underlying assets for finan-
cial securities. The US produced assets on a world scale considered
safe by the markets, thanks to the specialization of its financial ser-
vices. Other countries, such as Spain and Ireland, carried out a
similar role, but on a European scale, producing assets backed by
safe collateral (homes) or with no collateral, but issued by financial
institutions deemed to be safe, which attracted savings funds or
large European banks.


     In fourth place, the creation of the EMU meant the disappearan-
ce of exchange rate risk among its members. This removed an impor-
tant barrier to capital flows within the EMU and encouraged the pre-
viously described process. But its effects went even beyond the disap-
pearance of currency risk. In the international financial markets, as
well as in the EMU countries, expectations that the greater monetary
and economic integration ensured the economic convergence of its
members were generated, which justified the disappearance of any
type of risk premiums (see Ehrmann et al, 2011).


22
The Future of the Euro


  Graph 3 clearly shows the almost full disappearance of risk pre-
miums for countries becoming part of the EMU. Without doubt,
Greece was a paradigmatic example of this process, going from fun-
ding at 25% in 1993 to do at the same interest rate as Germany, follo-
wing its entry into the Eurozone.


   Chart 3
   10 year public debt interest rates in the EMU, 1995-2011




   Source: ECB, Bloomberg


  The implications of such expectations of economic convergence
were very important in terms of imbalances in the current balance.
Under the assumption that a real and economic convergence pro-
cess was taking place, well beyond the nominal, it seemed natural
that capital should flow towards the economies with lower per capi-


                                                                         23
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


ta incomes, as economic theory predicts (see, for example, Barro,
Mankiw & Sala-i-Martin, 1995).


     In fact, as the risk premiums were disappearing, the correlation
between the savings rated and investment rate were reduced. As
was already anticipated by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002), since
1999 to the start of the crisis, the Feldstein-Horioka paradox disap-
peared completely, as shown in Graph 4. Coinciding with the
reduction in the typical deviation of risk premiums, which reached


     Chart 4
     Typical deviation of risk premiums and correlation between the rate of investment and
     the rate of savings, EMU, 1993-2011




     Source: Bloomberg




24
The Future of the Euro


almost zero as of 1998, the correlation between the national invest-
ment rate and the savings rate was observed to have been nil or
even negative, compared to the positive and statistically significant
values of the beginning of the nineties.


  In fifth place, a permissive regulation, together with reduced
interest rates and very high competition in the financial sector
generated the incentives required for the generation of profit to be
done via transaction volume instead of via price margins (mainly
interest rates), favouring a very important leveraging of broad seg-
ments of the private sector. One of the results of this process was
the intensification of a new banking business model, based on the
granting of collateral backed loans, the generation of financial
assets from such loans and the distribution thereof as asset-backed
securities in asset packages (originate to distribute) which transfe-
rred credit risk in full to the purchasers of these new generated
assets. Compared with the traditional bank business, in which
financial institutions that grant the credits keep the risk on their
balance sheets, this new business model led to greater intercon-
nection of the balance sheets among financial institutions all over
the world and a significant increase in contagion risk.




3. The imbalances in Europe and the EMU

  The financial crisis was preceded by a period of economic prospe-
rity, measured by conventional indicators of growth, macroecono-


                                                                     25
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


mic stability and inflation, during which enormous imbalances of a
financial and competitive nature have been created. However, a
glance of the macroeconomic picture of the EMU reflects a situation
of balance which we do not find in other important economic
regions of the world (Table 1). Both the deficit and public debt levels
and the net foreign positions and private indebtedness are generally
lower to those recorded in the United States or the United Kingdom.


     However, the EMU has had other problems hanging over it which
have led the economy of the region – and that of the whole of the
EU by extension – to the situation of stagnation which it is currently
undergoing. Some of these problems are of a structural nature, and
others are related to the extraordinary disparities between member
states in their key indicators to which, until very recently, we had
paid little attention. Among the first are demographic evolution and
low productivity growth which in turn have provoked a limited rate
of growth in employment. But the disparities and the heterogeneity
within the EMU are the most outstanding imbalances, as they call
for a serious amendment in the operation of the Euro, whose main
objective was to accelerate convergence among countries who adop-
ted the single currency along with other common institutions.


     The European Commission has recently implemented a pro-
gramme to monitor a number of indicators to detect and track
macroeconomic and financial imbalances in countries within the
EU (the EIP). One of these indicators summarises, over all others,
the nature of the main problem facing the European economy:


26
The Future of the Euro


the gradual and persistent disparity in the current account of its
member countries. Although the EMU and the EU are economies
which can be described as economies which contribute (and
demand) little net savings to (and from) foreign savings, their
aggregate results is the sum of extremely disparate realities. As
Lane (2010) points out, in 2010 European countries accounted for
approximately one third of all current account deficits and sur-
pluses worldwide. As can be seen in Graph 5, the current account
deficits and surpluses of the EMU have gradually polarised from
levels ranging between the [-3%-, +3%] interval, in proportion to
the GDP to position itself outside of this range and even persis-
tently above it by 5%. The underlying causes and macroeconomic
implications of this type of imbalance are extremely complex.


   Table 1
   Debts and deficits in the EMU, US and United Kingdom (% GDP)

                                             EA17           US         UK

   Budget balance of
                             2011           -4.4           -9.6        -8.9
  public administrations
      Debt of public
                             2011           87.6           100.0       84.8
     administrations

     Household debt          2010           67.3           92.1       106.1


     Corporate debt          2010           119.1          74.6       123.7

     Current account
                             2011            0.1           -3.1        -2.7
         balance

     Net international
                             2010           -7.2           -17.0       -13.9
         position

   Sources: AMECO, Haver, IMF, national sources and BBVA Research




                                                                               27
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


     It is true that this polarisation is not an exclusively European
phenomenon, as it happens in parallel with the so-called “global
imbalances” generated during the recent globalisation process.
However, in contrast to what is happening on a world scale and par-
ticularly in a series of developed countries (the Anglosphere) and
emerging countries (particularly China) in Europe there is a positi-
ve correlation between levels of income per capita and sales deficit,
so that the capital flows from the more advanced countries to the
less developed. This has rendered such imbalances less conspicuous,
as they have been associated with the real convergence process. The
traditional view considered foreign indebtedness as a natural con-
sequence of the catching up process during which the countries
undergoing rapid growth required foreign savings to fund strong
domestic investment in commercial goods. Thus, the availability of
savings and the Euro allowed for the funding of the productivity
convergence without financial and exchange rate strangulation.
The international allocation of savings was deemed to be optimal
(“consenting adults”, Obstfeld, 2012), and there was no reason for
public political intervention – what became known as “benign
neglect” by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002) or Edwards (2002).


     It is not easy to determine an optimal level, or even an adequate
one, for the current account deficit which already reflects the gap
between domestic savings and investment in a country which is
assumed to have been optimally determined by consumers and busi-
nesses, unless it is associated with high public deficit, in which case
we would be dealing with a fiscal problem. Moreover, a country may


28
The Future of the Euro


have a deficit current account without having a serious foreign
financing problem, or may have it despite having a regularised
account, in this case because despite a reduced net capital flow, what
matters in the event of a financial crisis is the size of the gross flows,
as nothing guarantees that national savers are willing to fund
domestic liabilities should the international markets become una-
vailable. However, the evolution of the current account of EMU coun-
tries (EU) reflects more deep-rooted problems where the adjustment
role of the market mechanism has proven insufficient and in which
gross financial flows have grown in a fast and imbalanced way.


   Chart 5
   Current account balance (% GDP)




   Source: BBVA Research with data from national sources




                                                                        29
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


     The deficits have not been linked with productivity convergen-
ce, as is evident in the cases of Spain, Portugal and, to a certain
extent, Ireland, which accumulated growing deficits despite the
slow growth of total productivity of the factors. As can be seen in
Graph 6, productivity grew by 1% on average, whereas the current
account balance varied between surpluses over 5% (the
Netherlands and Germany) and deficits of 10% (as in Portugal and
Spain). In fact, it has not only been the lure of investment but
mainly the fall in savings in peripheral countries which has caused
the gap in commercial deficit which has exceeded both in volume
– percentage of GDP – and in persistence, that observed in many
emerging countries prior to the crisis of the eighties and nineties.
Moreover, much of the foreign financing to the receiving countries
has not been channelled through direct and portfolio investment,
but by way of bank bonds, which increases the risk of bank crises
and ‘sudden stops’ (Jaumotte and Sodsriwiboon, 2010; Land,
2010).


     However, the most worrying characteristic of the unequal per-
formance of the current account in Europe is its persistence. Far
from being a transitory phenomenon, the divergence between
commercial balances has sharpened until 2007 (see Graph 5). The
design of the Euro took into account that the absence of own
currency would hinder the traditional adjustment to which most
countries resorted in times of crisis in the balance of payments.
The impossibility of this recourse to devaluation has not come
hand in hand with the strengthening of real devaluation mecha-


30
The Future of the Euro


nisms, that is, with a more flexible response by prices and salaries.
Between 2000 and 2010, enough time has lapsed to have expected
that the countries with most foreign debt and strong real apprecia-
tions should have begun a process of correction towards a surplus
in the commercial balance. Nevertheless, this has not been the
case. The correlation between the commercial deficit and the net
foreign position was positive in 2011 and in 2010 (Graph 7) as it
had been in the last decade, indicating that the private
savings/investment balance does not seem to respond to the cumu-
lative net foreign position.

   Chart 6
   Current Account Balance in 2007 (% of GDP) and average productivity growth bet-
   ween 2000 and 2009.




   Source: BBVA Research based on AMECO




                                                                                     31
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


     In 2010 only four EMU countries had a net positive foreign posi-
tion – Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands and Finland – and only
Finland had managed it after correcting a very negative position in
2001 (that is, after a decade of foreign rapid growth and surplus).
Practically all other EMU countries saw their net indebtedness
increase substantially or, at best, such as in France or Austria, they
managed a moderate reduction thereof within the first ten years of
the single currency.


     Therefore, the performance of the current account is a very use-
ful indicator – although naturally not infallible – of the way in
which a country responds to the commercial and financial globa-
lisation process and to the existence of other types of imbalances
associated with private sector debt, both financial and non-finan-
cial. Before reviewing these indicators for the EMU (EU), it is worth
asking why the (market) adjustment mechanisms have failed in
this case and what the risk of this situation is happening again in
the future.


     The conventional current account approach indicates that
financial flows are a mere counterpart of commercial flows, so that
sustainability of foreign debt must be guaranteed by the expecta-
tion of future current account surpluses or, what is the same, by a
significant proportion of the commercial goods production in the
economy. Foreign financing is no at risk while foreign investors
consider the economy to be competitive. The domestic economy
must maintain a high productivity growth rate and competitive


32
The Future of the Euro


labour costs, as the opposite would render the foreign deficit
unsustainable, foreign investment would drop, reducing prices and
salaries and improving the foreign balance. In this way, given rea-
sonable elasticity in the demand of exports and imports, the
periods of real appreciation and foreign deficit can be reversed wit-
hout deep structural changes.


  However, this market mechanism has not worked in peripheral
Europe. Foreign funding has been used to a large extent to fund



   Chart 7
   Current account balance and net international position




   Source: BBVA Research based on Eurostat




                                                                       33
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


non-commercial goods, leading to strong expansion of demand, of
prices and of labour costs (see Graph 8). Despite the loss of com-
petitive capacity, the appeal for foreign lenders continues provided
the value of the asset with real guarantees – such as homes – con-
tinues, which is perceived as relatively safe. Thus, the worsening
competitiveness is the effect and not only the cause for the dete-
rioration of the current account. But the existence of high com-
mercial deficit is not corrected of its own accord nor is it done in a
smooth and orderly manner. When the bubble bursts and prices of
the assets used as guarantees plummet, foreign investors perceive
that the national economy is no longer able to guarantee their
debt, leading to the well-known processes of flight to quality,
increase in the cost of debt and, in extreme cases, to sudden stops.


     This integration process has led to a number of other imbalan-
ces in the European economies. The objective of the EIP is to go
beyond the control of deficit and debt, and to follow a number of
economic indicators which enable the detection of inadequate
macroeconomic development in a country and can lead to locali-
sed financial crises and even contagion in the future. Such indi-
cators come hand in hand with a number of ‘limits’ that are con-
sidered to be security measures which, when exceeded by a
country, special tracking must be carried out by the Commission.
If an economy is showing imbalance in several of these indicators,
it must propose a plan of action for correction thereof which, if
not suitably applied, might result in some form of political or eco-
nomic penalty. The list of indicators is the following (the limits


34
The Future of the Euro


above which a form of relevant imbalance is detected appear in
brackets): current account balance (% GDP, -4%, 6%); net inter-
national position (% GDP, -35%); real effective exchange rate
(variation rate, -5%, 5%); export market share (growth rate, -6%);
nominal unitary labour cost (growth rate, 9%); cost of housing
(growth rate, 6%); credit flow to private sector (% GDP, 15%); pri-
vate sector debt (% GDP, 1605); public debt (% GDP, 60%); and
unemployment rate (10%).


   Chart 8
   Growth of nominal salaries and real productivity




   Source: BBVA Research based on Eurostat




                                                                  35
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


            The first report issued on the monitoring of these indicators
       shows that in the third year since the start of the crisis (2010), the
       imbalances accumulated in recent years are far from being correc-
       ted, some of them having worsened since 2007 (Table 2). Greece,
       Portugal, Ireland and Spain are the countries with worse qualitati-
       ve results. They belong to the Eurozone periphery, where they fail
       in at least five of the ten criteria.3


            It is within the framework of such imbalances that we must
       interpret the fiscal crisis that has been reflected in the general
       growth of risk premiums of sovereign debt in Europe, especially in
       peripheral countries – although not exclusively. The levels of public
       debt in the EMU are comparable to those in the rest of the develo-
       ped world, both if we consider the region as a whole or the coun-
       tries within it separately. As is shown in Graph 6, only in 2008
       three EMU countries (Greece, Italy and Belgium) had a public debt
       above that of the US and in any case much lower than that of
       Japan. The growth in public debt during the crisis period places
       EMU countries – with the exception of Greece and Ireland – in the
       realm of 20%, similar to what had happened in most of the deve-
       loped countries. Therefore, behind the sovereign debt crisis there
       are issues related to the economic governance of the EU in general
       and the Eurozone in particular. But also, deeper reasons which have


3 The situation is worse if we take into account that indicators such as the growth rate
of housing prices and credit for the private sector are nowadays within the limits accep-
ted by the MIP as a result of the extraordinary restriction on credit suffered by most EU
economies.



       36
The Future of the Euro


become evident following the segmentation of the financial mar-
kets due to the crisis. On the one hand, we have the demographic
and structural characteristics of most of the countries, which
herald for the future a scenario of lesser growth than that before
the crisis. Graph 9 shows the growth rates up to 2007 and the fore-
casts made by the IMF up to 2015 for EMU countries, the United
Kingdom, Japan, and the US.


  The aging population and its effects on participation in the
labour market, the low savings rates – with the ensuing difficulties
in funding investments – and the slow rate of productivity growth
explain such expectations, which in turn severely affect the capa-
city to absorb the strong increase in public indebtedness.


  In second place, the economic crisis itself has generated an
additional burden on public finances by way of contingent liabili-
ties, the realisation of which shall depend on the performance of
the private debt and the need to apply measures to assist in the
reconversion of the financial sector. As stated by Reinhart & Rogoff
(2008 and 2009), one of the main consequences of financial crises
is that a large part of the private sector debt becomes public. Table
3 (ECB, 2012) shows the impact on public finances of the two
main contingent-type averages within the EMU: provisions for the
European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and the guarantees for
the banking sector. The sum of both would mean an additional
impact on the public debt in the EMU of almost 13% of the GDP.
It is true that such contingencies do not necessarily have to mate-


                                                                    37
38
     Table 2
     Imbalances at the EMU




     Source: European Commission (2012): First Alert Mechanism Report (moving averages, 3 or 5 years)
                                                                                                        The future of the Euro after the Great Recession
The Future of the Euro


rialise, but it is also true that provisions have proven insufficient
and have had to be extended in successive programmes.



   Chart 9
   GDP Growth in 2007 and 2015




   Source: IMF (2012)



  Lastly, the aging of the population gives way to the generation
of implicit liabilities which are not considered in public debt figu-
res but should be taken into consideration when evaluating the
sustainability of public finances (Cecchetti, Mohanty and
Zampolli, 2010). In 2009 the IMF (IMF, 2009) calculated the sum of
implicit and contingent liabilities in securities exceed – in present
value – 400% of the average GDP of the G20. Of these, those of a
contingent nature associated with the crisis account for approxi-


                                                                    39
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


mately one tenth, whereas that associated with an aging popula-
tion – pensions and social security – account for much higher
implicit obligations. As a whole, this type of liability will demand
a remarkable effort from public finances in the future. Cecchetti,
Mohanty and Zampolli (2010) place the additional permanent
financing required to meet such obligations at between 5 and 10
GDP points assuming a public debt at levels similar to the current
ones in developed countries.


     In summary, some European economies may have reached debt
levels which exceed or are dangerously close to their fiscal limits,
defined as the maximum level of debt which a country is able to
fund. The fiscal limit depends on the political will of its citizens
and the capacity to increase income by means of tax rate rises (Bi,
2012 and Leeper & Walker 2011) which makes it specific to each
country. This might explain, at least in part, the differences obser-
ved in risk premiums between countries with similar levels of debt
or even that some countries pay a higher cost of financing that
others with much higher levels of debt. Moreover, the relationship
between the risk premium and the fiscal limit is non-linear, incre-
asing rapidly when fiscal performance places debt at such levels
that the likelihood of reaching the limit is significant (Bi, 2012).
That is to say, in order to observe significant risk premiums, it is
enough for investors to understand that the fiscal strategy of a
country leads it to a fair likelihood of reaching the maximum level
of debt financed, even if the probability of this taking place in the
short term is very small. This probability in turn grows over the


40
The Future of the Euro


economic cycle, which obliges countries with greater volatility in
economic activity and unemployment to opt for stricter fiscal
rules.4




    Table 3
    Contingent Obligations of the governments 2008-2010

                                                          Banking sector
                                        EFSF
                                                           guarantees
    Belgium                              7,3                   12,7
    Germany                             8,22                    3
    Estonia                             12,46                   0
    Ireland                                                    42,8
    Greece                                                     25,8
    Spain                               8,61                   6,2
    France                              7,97                   3,1
    Italy                               8,78                   2,7
    Cyprus                              8,78                   15,7
    Luxembourg                          4,66                   3,2
    Malta                               10,91                   0
    The Netherlands                     7,32                   6,1
    Austria                             7,19                   5,7
    Portugal                                                    9
    Slovenia                            10,23                  4,4
    Slovakia                            11,05                   0
    Finland                             7,34                    0
    EMU                                  7,71                  5,2

   Source: BCE


4 When the economies reach this limit, the efficacy of the fiscal and monetary policy
is substantially reduced and both instruments no longer have the expected effects on
economic activity. The fiscal multipliers are reduced and the monetary authority loses
the capacity to control inflation, irrespective of the aggressiveness of its monetary
policy.



                                                                                 41
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


4. The new European governance and the future of the Euro

     The economic crisis has highlighted the need to carry out
important changes in European governance. It is obvious that
there have been failures in coordination in the economic policy
and mistakes in the policies adopted by national government,
which have generated a sovereign debt crisis and a financial crisis.
And it is also obvious that Europe was not first resorting to the
supranational institutions and bodies to prevent the crisis and to
provide a rapid and efficient response once it had begun. The EU,
and particularly the EMU, need to improve their economic gover-
nance in at least three areas: fiscal, financial and economic inte-
gration. Below we shall analyse each of these aspects and the cha-
llenges faced in each by the EMU.


4.1. Changes in fiscal governance


     In regard to fiscal integration, over recent months important
inroads have been made, among which are the Stability,
Coordination and Governance Treaty and the creation of the
European Stability Mechanism (ESM). The new Treaty, which shall
come into force on 1 January 2013, has been signed by all EU coun-
tries except for the United Kingdom and the Czech Republic, and
aims to make public finances sustainable and prevent the onset of
excessive public deficits, in order to safeguard the stability of the
Eurozone as a whole. In fact, this Treaty can be interpreted as a
second version of the Maastricht Treaty of 1992, with the differen-


42
The Future of the Euro


ce that whereas the former determined the conditions to enter the
EMU, the new treaty can be said to detail the conditions to be met
by the members of the EMU to continue to belong to the Eurozone.
To this end, the Treaty introduces specific rules (the structural defi-
cit may not exceed 0.5% of the GDP, as of a date to be determined
by the European Commission, and a public debt below 60% of
GDP) and automatic mechanisms which enable the adoption of
corrective actions in the event of deviation from targets.


   The rules introduced by the Treaty are in general well designed.
When establishing an objective in terms of structural fiscal balance it
allows for the influence of automatic stabilisers, the minimum being
between 0.5% of structural deficit and the deficit limit of 3%.
However, a good design does not necessarily guarantee a good imple-
mentation, as was the case with the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP).
It is true that the new Treaty entails a criterion of “reverse majority”:
from now on the adoption of corrective or disciplinary mechanisms
proposed by the European Commission must be rejected by a majo-
rity, whereas in the SGP the majority needed to be reached in order
to approve such proposals. It is also the experience of the current debt
crisis has led to an accumulation of collective knowledge which shall
prove very useful when adopting the right decisions in the future to
prevent new crises of this kind. Just as eighty years later the Federal
Reserve is currently preventing some of the well-known mistakes
which were made during the Great Depression of the 1930s, the
European Commission and the European Council shall endeavour to
prevent imbalances similar to those we are currently undergoing.


                                                                       43
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


     Available empirical and theoretical literature (see, for instance,
Andrés & Doménech, 2006, and the references included in this
paper), indicates that use of fiscal rules has proven useful in the
containment of public debt and the deficit, without the effective-
ness of the automatic stabilisers adversely affecting the effective-
ness of the discretionary fiscal policies. Therefore, the fiscal rules
like those included in the Stability Treaty do not have to be an
impediment for the fiscal policy to carry out its duty of stabilisa-
tion of economic cycles. Quite the opposite: when the economic
agents know, that as a consequence of the existence of such rules,
expansive fiscal policies in the short term shall be offset in the
medium term by counter-adjustment measures in order to prevent
the accumulation of public debt, the effectiveness of these discre-
tionary stabilisation policies increases, as has been proven by
Corsetti, Meier and Müller (2011).


     In any event, it shall be very difficult to achieve an optimal
implementation of the Treaty. In the first place, because all govern-
ments are often too complacent when allocating probabilities to
possible risk scenarios which may render public finances unsustai-
nable. Secondly, because it is difficult that sanctions may come
about from the European Union Court of Justice on the basis of fai-
lure to meet the structural deficit targets, which depend of estima-
tes of the cyclical position of the economies and the elasticity of
public income and expenses to this cyclical position. Nevertheless,
what the Stability Treaty does provide is that, prior to reaching
sanctions, the Commission may exert much greater pressure on


44
The Future of the Euro


national governments and alert markets about excessive imbalan-
ces, so that it is the markets themselves that impose discipline via
higher interest rates.


   As for the ESM, at the ECOFIN on 30 March the decision was
taken to extend it to 500 thousand million euros, which shall be
provided over two years, and beginning on 1 July 2012. The extent
to which this fund will be sufficient is still unknown, in that it
shall depend on how it is used and whether it allows for fund leve-
raging. Without leveraging, the fund shall only be enough to cover
the financing needs of small or medium sized economies in the
EMU, but not of the big four. However, it may prove effective for
specific, selective but highly intensive interventions designed to
reduce risk premiums, that is, to replace the ECB in its Securities
Market Programme (SMP). In addition, if the ESM should obtain
liquidity from the ECB itself, each of these entities might be able to
separately specialise in the management of a risk: the SMP would
manage the ‘solvency risk’ of sovereign debt and the ECB would
managed the ‘liquidity risk’, thus enabling the central bank to resu-
me the natural role for which it was created, as it would be creating
an EU fund, with a joint and several guarantee, instead of sove-
reign debt with a national guarantee.


   It is very important that the intervention of the SMP is as effi-
cient as possible. To this end, the Commission must be clear about
which countries are solvent, with adoption of any necessary adjust-
ment measures and structural reforms, and which countries need


                                                                    45
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


some kind of debt restructuring. In the first case, which is clearly
applicable to countries such as Spain and Italy, SMP intervention
on risk premiums should be as intense as necessary until market
doubt and uncertainty have been obliterated. It would otherwise
be very difficult to convince sovereign, pension or investment
funds to purchase the public debt of such countries if Europe is not
the first to refrain from doing so.


     Obviously, a more decisive intervention by the SMP, which
would lead to a rapid relaxation of the European sovereign debt
markets, requires the adoption and follow-up of the necessary
adjustments and reforms, but with sufficient time frame so as not
to asphyxiate the economic growth of the countries adopting such
policies. Specifically, the EU could change the fiscal consolidation
strategy which is currently being demanded from member states.
The obsession for nominal deficit targets should be replaced by a
more plausible, rigorous multi-annual fiscal policy strategy which,
in seeking to prevent a spiralling negative growth, truly contribu-
tes towards supporting sustainability in the long term of the public
finances of all countries. Specifically, the European consolidation
strategy should be based on the following principles:


1. Deficit reduction targets should refer to structural deficit inste-
     ad of nominal deficit, as proposed by the new Stability Treaty.
     This implies that countries should be asked to take specific and
     detailed measures to ensure a certain amount ex ante in terms
     of reduction in expenditure or increase in income in the


46
The Future of the Euro


   coming years. If, as a result of such measures, the economic
   activity should be adversely affect with an impact on nominal
   deficit (by the mere intervention of the automatic stabilisers),
   the member states should not be obliged to take new savings
   measures in that same financial year.


2. The pace of structural consolidation should be ambitious
   enough to ensure sustainability in the medium to long term of
   public finances, and gradual enough to prevent excessively
   adverse effects on activity and employment in the short term.


3. The long term balance of public finances requires reforms
   which guarantee the sustainability of public systems of pen-
   sions and social protection.


   Blanchard (2011) recently recommended that, in order to return to
prudent levels of public debt, it would be advisable to apply the pro-
verb of “slow and steady wins the race”. A similar recommendation to
that of De Long and Summers (2012), for whom a fiscal consolidation
which is too intense and too fast might endanger the very sustainabi-
lity of public finances instead of guaranteeing it.


   In regard to the debate on Eurobonds, although not necessary
or sufficient, these can indeed become a useful tool in the con-
text of streamlined national finances. They are not necessary, as
the Eurozone can operate without them, if the Stability Treaty
and the mechanism for the prevention and correction of excessi-


                                                                    47
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


         ve imbalances work properly. And they are not sufficient to pre-
         vent debt crises if the fiscal or current account imbalances are not
         corrected. If growth is imbalanced (private indebtedness, current
         account balance deficit), they imply a permanent transfer of
         income from one country to another, which is unsustainable in
         the long term. But they are convenient as an efficient mechanism
         to ensure and pool risks in the face of asymmetric shocks and,
         above all, as an element of political legitimacy of the European
         project: European citizens must see that there are specific bene-
         fits to belonging to the EMU. And Eurobonds are one of these
         benefits, particularly now when many countries need to make
         considerable sacrifices and carry out adjustments and reforms.


              In this regard, the Eurobond proposal (blue and red) of Delpla
         and von Weizsäcker (2010), has the advantage that it would allow
         countries to benefit from risk pooling and the creation of a more
         liquid asset (the blue bond) than that of the debt of each of the
         EMU members, which would strengthen the euro as an internatio-
         nal reserve currency, but with the benefit of preserving market dis-
         cipline for national debt issued over and above 60% of GDP (red
         bonds).5 This proposal consists of the EMU countries pooling their



5 Attinasi, Checherita and Nickel (2009) believe that this market discipline is behind
the increase in sovereign spreads between 2007 and 2009, as a result of the increase in
risk aversion and the concern for the sustainability of public finances. However, Favero
and Misale (2012) believe that this market discipline acts in an interrupted fashion over
time and, occasionally, in an exaggerated way, which in fact justifies the issue of euro-
bonds.



         48
The Future of the Euro


public debt up to 60% of their GDP as senior debt under the joint
and several responsibility of all members, whereas the issue of
national debt beyond such a limit would be junior debt under indi-
vidual responsibility. From this perspective, it is easy to conclude
that the decision of the European Council reached in December
2010 to ensure the solvency of the debt issued until June 2013, but
not that issued as of that date was a mistake, as the decision should
have been the opposite: ensure as of a given date all debt issued
under 60%, which would in effective terms be equal to the creation
of the Eurobonds proposed by Delpla and von Weizsäcker (2010).


4.2. Financial integration


   As Pisany-Ferri and Sapir (2010) have pointed out, to date the
EMU has worked without a European institution able to rescue
transnational financial entities and without authentic European
stress tests for its banking institutions. Oversight duties have
remained with national authorities and coordination problems
have been managed by means of a combination of discretionary
cooperation and dependence on rules approved by the EU.


   One of the lessons to be learned from the current crisis is that
it is difficult to manage a financial crisis on a European scale wit-
hout supranational regulators, supervisors and insurance mecha-
nisms. A large part of the head start that the US has over Europe
in terms of crisis management and resolution is precisely due to
the non-existence or the delay in creating such bodies. The US has


                                                                    49
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


federal institutions to manage banking crises, whereas Europe
does not, which renders true the saying that banks are internatio-
nal when expanding and national upon demise. The problem is
that, for some governments (Ireland is a perfect example of this),
banks are too large in relation to their public budgets.


     Likewise, the US has a federal regulation, whereas Europe has
enormous national dispersion of its regulations, despite the
efforts of the European Commission and regulators to homoge-
nise and converge towards a common financial regulation.
Occasionally, headways made in certain rules give rise to inequa-
lities among the agents who intervene in the markets, due to
other rules continuing to be different. This was the case, for ins-
tance, of the requirement of the European Banking Authority
that potentially systemic banks must exceed a capital ratio of 9%
before 30 June 2012, when the measurement of risk weighted
assets is regulated by different rules.


     Banking oversight in Europe is furthermore carried out via
national supervisors instead of via a single European institution,
which introduces heterogeneity in oversight levels of the financial
system. The result of this financial fragmentation is that one can-
not speak of a single market, which generates the possibility of
regulatory arbitrage, different conditions of competency, ineffi-
ciencies and, in general, a disadvantage in regard to other world
financial areas.




50
The Future of the Euro


   In summary, financial integration requires an improvement to be
made in the mechanisms through which information is shared on
the financial systems of each country and the way in which their
activities are supervised, the harmonisation of the guarantees on
bank deposits and of consumer protection regulations, the creation
of European bank restructuring and rescue mechanisms, and the
advancement towards a Single Market not with more, but with a bet-
ter, European regulation which, instead of adding to and prevailing
over national legislation, should simplify and replace it.


4.3. Economic integration


   With greater fiscal and financial integration the Eurozone could
operate with less tension in the future, without ensuring the economic
convergence among countries. Is convergence of income or welfare
levels in European countries necessary? Probably not, but it is still con-
venient, as has been stated earlier, to enable societies to believe that
being within an economic and monetary union has advantages well
beyond those which are provided by monetary stability. One of les-
sons to be learned from the Eurozone crisis is precisely that monetary
integration does not ensure economic convergence, as this requires an
advancement in convergence of the determining factors (economic,
social and institutional) of economic growth.


   Table 4 shows that the differences in medium and long term
determinants of per capita income are very significant. The relati-
ve position of each country has been obtained on the basis of the


                                                                        51
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


IMF analysis (2010), whereas the allocation of each country to one
of three groups under consideration has been carried out on the
basis of the criteria put forward by Hall and Soskice (2001). On the
basis of a number of criteria, both institutional and based on the
workings of economic relations, Hall and Soskice classify the varie-
ties of capitalism into liberal economies (the US being the pro-
totype) and coordinated economics (Scandinavian countries are
the paradigm). In both models (either with high or minimum
coordination), the economies can function efficiently. Market eco-
nomies which cannot be classified into either group are classified
as mixed economies.


     In order to transform the qualitative IMF indicator into a quan-
titative one, such as analysing its correlation with per capita inco-
me, values of 1 to 3 have been allocated for each of the three levels
considered by the IMF, where a higher score suggests a greater need
for implementing structural reforms. This enables the obtention of
an average for each country and for each of the nine indicators
which are shown in Table 4. The differences shown in this table are
very marked, not only between developed economies, but also bet-
ween European ones. In light of this evidence it is not surprising
that, except in the case of Ireland, the countries which have accu-
mulated the most imbalances and which are suffering more form
the tensions in the debt market are precisely those which shown
greater structural weaknesses and the ones which must implement
the most reforms. Countries which in turn have been classified as
mixed market economies, presenting more inefficient institutions.


52
Table 4
      Structural capacity of the developed economies




     Source: BBVA Research (2010) based on IMF (2010) and Hall & Soskice (2010)




53
                                                                                  The Future of the Euro
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


     The changes in the regulations which affect the operation of the
labour, goods and services markets, trade, telecommunications
markets, are easier to implement in the short term, although the
changes thereof are felt in the medium term. An example of this
can be found in the recent reform of the labour market in Spain,
which is bringing its operation in line with that of countries like
Germany (in terms of internal flexibility mechanisms) or to that of
free market economies (by prioritising company agreements and
opt out clauses for collective bargaining agreements). Making
headway in these types of reforms (for example, linking salaries to
productivity) is crucial to remove the differences in competitive-
ness which exist between EMU countries, particularly bearing in
mind that the crisis may have had an effect on the potential
growth of these economies (see, for example, the European
Commission analysis, 2009).


     However, in long term indicators such changes can take a lot
longer and, in some cases, even decades. This is the case with
human capital. Even in the event that the many younger workers
of countries such as Spain, Italy, Greece or Portugal should enter
into the labour market with the same human capital as in better
placed countries, 25 years would be needed to half the distance for
the whole of the population of employable age.




54
The Future of the Euro


5.Conclusions

  The economic crisis has highlighted the excessive complacency
of the markets, agents, supranational institutions and governments
when interpreting the imbalances which were being generated in
the previous expansion period and the absence of supranational
institutions and mechanisms, firstly to prevent the imbalances
which led to the crisis and secondly, to provide a fast and efficient
response once they had happened. Such institutions and mecha-
nisms are necessary because the evidence shows that the markets
react in a discontinuous way, and occasionally in an exaggerated
way, are pro-cyclical and do not generate of their own accord suf-
ficient disciplinary mechanisms in the short and medium term
whenever these are needed. Insofar as the current Eurozone crisis
has taken place mainly in three areas (debt crisis, banking crisis
and crisis in growth and competitiveness, with huge heterogeneity
between countries), the EU and, particularly the EMU, need to
improve their economic governance in at least three areas: the fis-
cal, the financial and that of economic integration.


  As for the improvement in fiscal governance, the Treaty of
Stability, Coordination and Governance needs to be effectively
applies in a preventive way and that, during its transition towards
medium and long term structural deficit targets, this is done with
sufficient rigor and the right flexibility to prevent that countries
required to make the most efforts in the short term should enter
into a negative growth spiral. In this regard, intervention by the


                                                                    55
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


ESM on risk premiums should be as intense as necessary until
market doubts and uncertainty have been removed, so that the
countries which are implementing fiscal adjustments and structu-
ral reforms have a sufficiently broad time period to enable such
measures to have positive effects on economic growth. As for the
Eurobonds, although they are not necessary or sufficient to ensu-
re the operation of the EMU, they are indeed convenient as an
efficient mechanism providing assurance and pooling risk in the
face of asymmetrical shocks and, above all, as a political legiti-
macy item in the European project: European citizens must disco-
ver that there are specific benefits to being part of the EMU.
Although it is difficult for such Eurobonds to become a viable ins-
trument in the current situation of divergence, they must become
an essential part of the future European Treasury when the main
imbalances are well under way to being corrected through the
decisive application of the reforms in the various countries in the
EU.


     The second area where headway must be made is that of finan-
cial integration, in order to prevent future banking crises and to
manage them in a more efficient and rapid way. Europe must have
supranational financial institutions, regulators and supervisors, as
the current financial fragmentation prevents us from speaking of a
single market. An important limitation which gives rise the regu-
latory arbitrage, different competency conditions, inefficiencies
and, in general, a disadvantage in regard to other world financial
areas competing against the European entities.


56
The Future of the Euro


   Lastly, although greater fiscal and financial integration may suf-
fice to enable the Eurozone to operate with less tension in the futu-
re, it is worth establishing the bases for greater economic conver-
gence among its members, in order to increase the political legiti-
macy of the economic and monetary union project, with benefits
which go beyond those provided by economic stability. The diffe-
rences between the EMU countries in the workings of factor, goods
and services markets are very significant, as well as in long term
growth determinants. The structural reforms undertaken to enable
the markets to work more efficiently can bring positive effects in a
relatively reasonable period of time, enabling competitiveness to
improve and the imbalances accumulated during the expansion
and the crisis to disappear more rapidly. In this regard, it is essen-
tial to ensure the success of the Excessive Imbalances Procedure
and other imbalance monitoring mechanisms, ensuring a more
efficient preventive and corrective action than that provided by
the Stability and Growth Pact. However, in terms of long term
growth determinants, such changes can take longer and, in some
cases, even decades; it shall therefore be necessary for Europe to
boost the solidarity mechanisms required to accelerate this conver-
gence process in a more effective and efficient way than that done
in the past.


   To simultaneous progress on all these fronts, both at suprana-
tional and national levels, is a necessary condition for the Euro to
overcome this crisis and for its members to continue to form part
of this project in the future. Insofar as the starting point is very


                                                                    57
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


different in each country, the main challenge now facing the
EMU is to combine in a fair way the rigor and the ambition of the
adjustments and structural reforms, on the one hand, with an
appropriate time frame and solidarity with all other members of
the Eurozone, on the other.


     If, on the contrary, the member states should fail to show such
determination, any attempt towards European economic gover-
nance will be due more an intention than a hard reality. The
Eurozone would have an uncertain future. The alternative of a
Political European Union, in which all necessary economic policies
could be implemented from a community Executive under the
control of a European Parliament and with all democratic rights, is
currently not expected for the time being.




Bibliography

- Attinasi M. G., C. Checherita y C. Nickel (2009): “What Explains
the Surge in Eurozone Sovereign Spreads during the Financial Crisis
of 2007-09?”, ECB Working Paper no. 1131/2009.


- Barro, R. J., N. G. Mankiw y X. Sala-i-Martin (1995): “Capital
Mobility in Neoclassical Models of Growth”. The American
Economic Review, 85(1), 103-115.




58
The Future of the Euro


- BBVA Research (2010): Spain Economic Watch. Noviembre.


-     Bean, Ch. (2004): “Asset Prices, Financial Instability, and
Monetary Policy”. The American Economic Review, 94(2), 14-18.


- Bean, Ch. (2010): “The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and
the Great Contraction”.


- Bi, H. (2012): “Sovereign Default Risk Premia, Fiscal Limits, and
Fiscal Policy”. European Economic Review, 56 (2012) 389–410.


- Blanchard, O. y F. Giavazzi (2002): “Current account deficits in
the euro area: the end of the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle?” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 147-186.


- Blanchard, O. (2011): “Blanchard on 2011’s Four Hard Truths”.
Vox EU.


- Bordo, M. y O. Jeanne (2002): “Monetary Policy and Asset Prices:
Does 'Benign Neglect' Make Sense?” International Finance, 5(2), 139-
64.


- Borio, C. y W. White (2004): “Whiter monetary and financial sta-
bility? the implicatios of evolving policy regimes”. BIS Working
Papers No 147.




                                                                   59
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


- Cecchetti, S., M. Mohanty y F. Zampolli (2010): “The Future of
Public Debt: Prospects and Implications”. BIS Working Paper No.
300.


- Comisión Europea (2009): "Impact of the Current Economic and
Financial Crisis on Potential Output". European Economy
Occasional Papers, 49.


- Comisión Europea (2012): First Alert Mechanism Report.


- Corsetti, G., A. Meier y G. J. Müller (2011): “Fiscal stimulus with
spending reversals“. The Review of Economics and Statistics (en prensa).
- DeLong, J. B. and L. H. Summers (2012): “Fiscal Policy in a
Depressed Economy”. Mimeo.


- Delpla, J. y J. von Weizsäcker (2010): “The Blue Bond Proposal”.
Bruegel Policy Brief.


- Doménech, R. y M. Jiménez (2010): ”La Primera Gran Crisis de la
Unión Económica y Monetaria”, Pensamiento Iberoamericano, 6, 49-
80.


-     Edwards, S., 2002. "Does the Current Account Matter?," en
Sebastian Edwards y Jeffrey A. Frankel, eds, Preventing Currency
Crises in Emerging Markets, pages 21-76 NBER.




60
The Future of the Euro


-   Ehrmann, M., M. Fratzscher, R.S. Gurkaynak y E.T. Swanson
(2011). ‘Convergence and Anchoring of the Yield Curves in the
Euro Area’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(1), 350–64.


-   Favero, C. y A. Missale (2012): “Sovereign Spreads in the
Eurozone: Which Prospects for a Eurobond?” Economic Policy,
27(70), 231–273.


- FMI (2010), “Regional Economic Outlook. Europe”.


-   Galí, J. y L. Gambetti (2009): "On the Sources of the Great
Moderation." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1):
26–57.
- Hall, Peter A. y David Soskice, 2001a: An Introduction to Varieties
of Capitalism. In: Peter A. Hall y David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of
Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–70.


-   Florence J. y P. Sodsriwiboon (2010): “Current Account
Imbalances in the Southern Euro Area”. WP/10/139. IMF.


- Lane, P. (2010): A European Perspective on External Imbalances.
Swedish Institue for European Policy Studies. Report nº 5.


- Leeper, E. M. y T. B. Walker (2011): “Fiscal Limits in Advanced
Economies”. Working Paper 16819. NBER.




                                                                     61
The future of the Euro after the Great Recession


- Obstfeld, M. (2012): “Does The Current Account Still Matter?”
Working Paper 17877. NBER.


- Pisani-Ferry, J. y A. Sapir (2010): "Banking crisis management in
the EU: an early assessment". Economic Policy, 341-373.


- Rojan, R. (2005): “Has Financial Development Made The World
Riskier?”. NBER WP 11728.


- Reinhart, C. M. y K. Rogoff (2008): “Is the 2007 US Sub-Prime
Financial Crisis So Different? An International Historical
Comparison”. American Economic Review, 98(2), 339–344.


- Reinhart, C. M. y K. Rogoff (2009): This Time is Different: Eight
Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press.


- Shambaugh, J. C. (2012): “The Euro’s Three Crises”. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity (de próxima publicación).




62
/JOSÉ CARLOS DÍEZ * /




                                              Nature and Causes
                                                of the Euro crisis




Summary; 1. Introduction; 2. Historical background of the Euro; 3. Nature
of the Euro crisis; 4. Fixed versus flexible exchange rates: a review; 5. Causes
of the Euro Crisis; 6. Conclusions; Bibliography



Summary

    This work analyses the Euro crisis. It includes a review of its his-
torical background and the exchange rate theory to provide con-
ceptual arguments to help understand the nature and causes the-
reof. It is an infrequent pathology in economics, particularly in
developed countries, but with an enormous destructive capacity.


* José Carlos Díez is an economist who has combined his academic and corporate roles
throughout his professional career. His academic activity is linked to the University of
Alcalá, where he was an undergraduate and PhD student and now is Professor of
Fundamentals of Economic Analysis.
He is currently the Chief Economist at Intermoney, a company founded in 1979 and
leader in Spain in money market brokerage. He contributes with his forecasts to the
panel of experts of the ECB on European economy and the panel of FUNCAS on the
Spanish economy, and advises companies, financial entities and institutions both natio-
nal and international.



                                                                             63
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


For this reason, it is important to get the right diagnosis when defi-
ning the economic policy that will solve the crisis. The main cau-
ses analysed herein are financial integration, the under-assessment
of risks, local imbalances within the Eurozone and the Great
Recession.


1. Introduction

     The world financial crisis, whose first symptom was the collap-
se of the subprime asset-backed securities market at the start of
2007, has been changing. It is currently focused on Europe, and is
calling into question the future viability of the Euro and the
European project itself. This work aims to classify the nature of the
Euro Crisis and to identify the main causes thereof. Although the
objective is not to analyse potential economic measures designed
to solve the crisis, without an accurate diagnosis of the origin and
dynamics of the crisis, finding the right solution would be an exer-
cise in chance.


     To this end, section 2 includes the history of the European pro-
ject and the single currency. Section 3 describes the nature of the
crisis, which is a seldom seen pathology in economics but which
causes devastating damage to unemployment and public debt of
affected countries. In order to provide the conceptual arguments
required to analyse the crisis, section 4 contains a review of the lite-
rature on exchange rates. Section 5 analyses the main causes of the
crisis, which are: i) financial integration and under-assessment of


64
The Future of the Euro


risk; ii) local imbalances; and iii) the Great Recession. Finally, sec-
tion 6 includes the main conclusions reached in the article and
establishes the requirements to be met by the roadmap in order to
put an end to the Euro Crisis.




2. Historical Background of the Euro

   The Euro is the first monetary experiment of the 21st century. It
is not the first in history and shall not be the last, but it affects an
economy like that of the Eurozone which accounts for 15% of the
GDP and for 40% of world exports. The European Union is a poli-
tical project designed to prevent a third world war in Europe. The
first assignment of sovereignty was control by a supranational
body of the coal and steel production in France and Germany, basic
raw materials to produce weaponry. Europe was not an optimal
monetary area; therefore, if a country suffered from an asymmetri-
cal disturbance which did not affect the rest and it saw the effects
thereof on tis unemployment rate, this could not be offset by wor-
kers migrating to other countries with lower unemployment rates.
The bubble in Spain is a good example of this. Spain created one
third of the jobs in the Eurozone during the boom years, but wor-
kers from Germany, where the unemployment rate was reaching
historical levels, did not come: instead, it was workers from outsi-
de the Eurozone who came. When the bubble burst, our unem-
ployment rate shot up, but very few Spanish workers have gone to
work in Germany.


                                                                      65
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


     The example of an optimal monetary area is always the US.
However, we tend to forget that in order to get there; they first
had to annihilate the original settlers and then have a civil war
which led to a default on payment of foreign debt. The European
project belongs to the 21st century and when in Asia, America or
Africa integration processes begin, they look to Europe for inspi-
ration. Nevertheless, the Euro was a risky headlong rush. Since the
end of the Bretton Woods agreement, Europe has tried to avoid
the unfair competition of competitive devaluations within a cus-
toms union. Germany, with the strongest currency in the system,
has always led the monetary agreements, as its companies suffe-
red the industrial delocalisation created by devaluations, mainly
that of the Italian Lira, a country a few hours away by lorry from
Bavaria. After the fall of the Berlin Wall, the acceleration of the
monetary union was decided so that it would become the striker
of the political union. However, the political union reached stag-
nation after the severe German crisis of 2000, and the single
currency project began to crack.




3. Nature of the Euro Crisis

     The nature of the crisis which is hitting the European Union is
a classical debt deflation crisis (Fischer, 1933). Since the Great
Depression, this type of crisis had mainly taken place in emerging
countries and was associated with countries with financial vulne-
rability, with little tradition of macroeconomic stability and insti-


66
The Future of the Euro


tutional fragility. Japan had suffered a crisis of this kind in the
nineties and its economy is today trapped under deflation and
liquidity, but it was viewed as an exotic case in the Far East. In
2008, the Great Recession led to an abrupt disruption of the paths
of growth in developed economies, and the ghost of the Great
Depression began to haunt the world. By contrast, the decisive and
coordinated action of global economic policies prevented another
Great Depression (Eichengreen, 2010). Since then, world trade and
industrial production are 10% higher to levels prior to the Great
Recession, although the MSCI world stock index continues to be
20% below the levels of spring 2008.


   Nonetheless, the crash of Lehman Brothers led to the collapse of
world trade, and all countries and areas entered abruptly into reces-
sion, which favoured policy coordination. But the recovery from
2009 was asymmetric, and the coordination of world economic
policies was conspicuously absent. In the Eurozone, from summer
of 2008 to spring of 2009, the euphoria in support of an interven-
tion to avoid a depression gave way to exit strategies in autumn of
that same year and to begin implementing these in spring of 2010.
The debt crisis affected a country with huge imbalances in the
balance of payments and high level of indebtedness such as
Greece, which accounts for 2% of the GDP and population of the
Eurozone, and has extended first to Ireland, then to Portugal, and
now to Italy and to Spain. One third of the GDP of the area is alre-
ady affected, and it has thus become a systemic and global pro-
blem. This is a crisis in the balance of payments, but the existence


                                                                    67
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


of a currency and the high level of indebtedness mean the lack of
any comparable historical precedents, which in turn makes the
diagnosis and the search for policies to solve it much harder. For
this reason, we must carry out a review of classical literature on
exchange rates in order to establish the conceptual bases for the
explanation of the crisis, without which the search for a solution
would become a random wander.




4. Fixed exchange rates versus flexible exchange rates: a review

     An exchange rate is a relative price between two hypothetical
shopping baskets of two countries. However, exchange rates are
closely related to interest rates (Keynes, 1992), and we are therefo-
re speaking of a relative price which is essential when explaining
economic development. Probably for this reason and as a result of
the advance of globalisation, both commercial and financial since
the fifties, in recent decades economists have paid special attention
to exchange rates. Exchange rates can be:


i. Free floating: the exchange rate is set freely in the market on the
     basis of supply and demand, without the intervention of the
     central bank or the government of a country. The Euro and the
     Dollar are the closest free floating currencies.


ii. Dirty or managed float: the government or central bank suppo-
     sedly does not intervene but there are verbal interventions or


68
The Future of the Euro


   changes in monetary policy which attempt to alter the bases of
   supply and demand in the currency market. At times of maxi-
   mum volatility both the US government and the European ones
   verbally intervene in the market. During the Great Recession,
   the Federal Reserve, without expressly acknowledging this, has
   applied a monetary policy which has significantly weakened the
   dollar. The ECB has always followed in the footsteps of the Fed
   but in 2011 it managed to exceed its action by weakening the
   Euro, also without express recognition thereof. Japan is without
   question the best example of dirty flotation. The country sup-
   posedly enjoys free exchange rates but when there is tension in
   the markets and the savers repatriate capital, the central bank
   intervenes massively in the currency market to counteract the
   pressures of appreciation on its currency, which would have a
   very negative repercussion on activity and employment.


iii. Fluctuation bands: the European Monetary System or EMS, the
   predecessor of the Euro, was the clearest example of this system.
   A central parity and fluctuation bands were established. Whilst
   the exchange rate in the market fluctuated within the bands,
   the system behaved like a flexible currency rate, but if it reached
   the bands then the central bank intervened to prevent these
   being exceeded, therefore becoming a fixed Exchange rate.


iv. Fixed on a currency basket: equal to a fixed rate, but instead of
   fixing the anchor on one single currency it is fixed on a basket.
   It has been speculated for some time that China wants to apply


                                                                    69
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


     this system. It makes more sense that just fixing it against the
     dollar, as the basket should replicate the composition of the
     current account and financial balance and would allow for bet-
     ter stabilisation of real exchange rates, which are the ones
     which determine the impact on activity and employment.


v. Fixed adjustable: this is a fixed exchange rate which allows
     for adjustments. These may be discretionary or else subject
     to rules such as in the Bretton Woods system, or periodically
     adjustable. The latter were used in emerging countries which
     had sustained soaring inflation rates in the eighties and
     nineties during their stabilisation programmes, especially in
     Latin America.


vi. Non-adjustable or true fixed rate: the country fixes a nominal
     anchor with a fixed rate relative to another currency with no
     possibility of change. Middle Eastern countries have fixed
     exchange rates against the dollar, which is justified by income
     from oil being collected in dollars. China had a fixed exchange
     rate against the dollar until 2005, when it moved onto daily
     fluctuation bands which it has recently broadened to +/- 1%
     daily.


vii. Cash conversion: the monetary supply of a country is determi-
     ned by the level of currency reserves, and thus monetary sove-
     reignty is subject to capital flows. This was the exchange system
     in Argentina until 2001.


70
The Future of the Euro


viii.Exchange Union: the countries waive their national sove-
   reignty and assume a new currency. This may be a dollarization
   as has been proposed in some Latin American countries, or else
   a Euroization where the dollar would be adopted but without
   representation in the central bank. Or else a monetary and
   exchange union such as the Eurozone, where countries assume
   the same currency and are represented in the central bank and
   in monetary and exchange decision making processes.


  The debate on fixed or floating exchange rates is as old as macroe-
conomics. During the happy twenties and then during the Great
Depression, capital movements were accused of being speculative due
to the extreme volatility of exchange (Nurkse 1942). Subsequently,
another school of thought argued that the volatility was caused by
destabilising economic policies and that freedom and speculation had
stabilising effects (Friedman 1953). Rudiger Dornsbush opened up a
new avenue of research according to which, even with investors with
rational expectations, there was volatility in exchange rates. An incre-
ase in the money in circulation by the central bank would increase
inflation expectations and lead to a depreciation in the exchange rate.
However, for investors to buy once again there should be expectations
of appreciation; the exchange rate should therefore over-react and
exceed its level of equilibrium to enable capital flows to return to the
country.


  The truth is that neither the theory nor the empirical evidence
are conclusive in this debate. The problem facing the countries is


                                                                      71
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


threefold: exchange rate stability, monetary independence and
financial aperture. Conceptually speaking, flexible exchange rates
are the optimal solution, but for these to be stable the country
must have monetary credibility. Flexible exchange rates provide
leeway to the central bank in terms of fiscal policy, whereas the
fixed exchange rate means this is lost and it becomes dependent on
the decisions made by the central bank to which it has anchored
its currency. The problem is that credibility takes a long time to
achieve and takes very little time to lose. Moreover, it cannot be
imposed; it is the society of the country in question which must
understand stability to be a public asset and to accept sacrifices and
limitations in order to preserve it.


     Countries lacking monetary credibility have hardly any leeway in
monetary policy, and this reduces the costs of accepting a fixed
exchange rate. If the country has suffered from hyperinflation or a
spiralling inflation, a nominal anchor on a stable currency allows for
stabilisation of the prices of imported goods in the shopping basket
and, combined with a stabilisation plan, proves to be highly effecti-
ve to get the economy out of hyperinflation. This is what happened
in Argentina in 1990, but then the fixed exchange rate allowed imba-
lances to go beyond what was sustainable and ended up by explo-
ding in mid-air and amplifying the effects of the severe crisis of 2001.


     During the nineties the debate in Europe prior to the creation of
the Euro was very intense (Rodríguez Prada, 1994). Most econo-
mists did not call into question the fact that Europe was an opti-


72
The Future of the Euro


mal monetary area (Meade 1957 and Mundell 1961). Although
much progress has been made in the freedom of movements of
capital and people, the labour markets continue to be segmented,
mainly due to language and cultural differences, and when a region
suffers an asymmetric disturbance with an increase in unemploy-
ment, this is not offset by transferring workers from another region
as they do, for example, in the US. In this scenario, the country
needs to transfer capital and work to the sector of non-corporate
goods to the corporate goods sector and needs to depreciate the real
exchange rate. Without the capacity to devaluate the nominal
exchange rate, all the adjustment must be made via inflation or
productivity. When the central country has inflation rates close to
2% the strategy must be deflationist, which is where the problems
start, as many economists warned prior to the creation of the Euro
and has been proven since the Great Recession (Obstfeld 1998).


Nevertheless, the lack of an optimal monetary union is clearly a
downside to the creation of the euro, but in the nineties it was the
benefits that were highlighted (De Grauwe 2009). The main bene-
fit is that we Europeans already had a customs union and high
level of commercial integration. Nowadays, approximately 70% of
the Spanish exports are concentrated in the European Union and
60% of what we import comes from our partners. Therefore, natio-
nal exchange policies were very destabilising in this scenario, put-
ting the European project at risk.




                                                                   73
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


     The main benefits were concentrated in the financial area.
Integration would enable the removal of currency risk and risk pre-
miums, leading to a drop in real interest rates and therefore incre-
asing the potential growth of the Eurozone and of each of the
countries therein, in turn allowing for convergence in income per
inhabitant with the US, which experience a sharp boom in pro-
ductivity in the nineties. Chart 1 shows how the introduction of
the euro did not achieve the desired convergence, except in the
case of Spain.



     Chart 1
     Gross Domestic Product per inhabitant




     Source: Eurostat structural indicators and own work




74
The Future of the Euro


In the debate of costs and benefits prior to the creation of the Euro,
many economists warned of institutional problems in the design of
the monetary union. The main ones were the absence of a fiscal
union which would offset the asymmetric disturbances that might
take place in some states and, that in the absence of exchange rates
and monetary policy, the country would be left without economic
policy leeway to counteract them (Eichengreen 1998). The other
main limitation was the absence of a true lender of last resort which
the statutes imposed on the ECB (Obstfeld 1998).




5. Causes of the Euro Crisis

   The Euro crisis is extremely complex like all debt deflation cri-
ses in history (Díez 2012), which is why we shall now review the
main events to enable us to understand the fundamentals of the
over-indebtedness without which we shall not be able to come up
with appropriate economic policies to help digest this.


5.1. Financial integration and under-assessment of risk


   When a country adopts a fixed exchange rate and investors con-
sider it sustainable in the future, the risk premium drops. A rational
investor must choose between an infinite variety of international
assets in which to invest his savings, but his yield estimates are
made in local currency as the objective of purchasing financial
assets is to protect against the impairment of purchasing power


                                                                     75
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


caused by inflation during the investment period. If an investor
purchases an asset in another currency that then appreciates
during the investment period, his yield will increase in the local
currency, but if it depreciates it will drop, which explains the direct
relationship between interest and exchange (Dornbusch 1976).


     In the case of the Euro we are dealing with the exchange rate
with the largest commitment and greatest exit costs; therefore its
added credibility is also greater, just as the drop in risk premiums is
also highly intense. Chart 2 shows the intense process of financial
integration which took place in Europe following the creation of
the single currency. Investment funds and financial institutions in
the Eurozone went from having 20% of assets from other countries
in the region in their portfolios in 1998, to 45% and 40% respecti-
vely in 2007. This means a huge transfer of capitals from countries
with a savings surplus, mainly Germany, to countries with savings
deficits and especially those with higher risk premiums.


     This arrival of capital flows, along with the credibility granted
by the investors to the Euro since its inception, help to explain the
intense convergence of interest rates between the public debt of the
various member countries that can be observed in Chart 3.
However, as is the case with all bubbles, at the beginning there are
fundamentals which justify investor behaviour, but usually, follo-
wing such sharp changes in financial flows, there is usually and
over-reaction and asset prices move away from the fundamentals.




76
The Future of the Euro



   Chart 2
   Financial integration




   Source: European Central Bank



   Chart 4 shows how not only did convergence take place in
public debt interest rates, but that the process was more intense in
private debt. Covered bonds are the assets with the least likelihood
of default following the public debt of a country and it might even
be the case, in extreme cases, of default on Treasury bonds but not
on covered bonds, as has happened in Greece. The covered bond is
a bond with a senior guarantee from the financial institution that
issues it, but which also has a second guarantee. The issuing entity
selects its highest credit quality mortgages, those for the main resi-
dence, with a debt under 80% of appraisal and a monthly instal-
ment below 35% of the household income, and these are attached
as bond guarantees. Therefore, in the event of bankruptcy of the


                                                                    77
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


     Chart 3
     10 years Public debt spread v. Germany




     Source: Bloomberg and own data



entity, the buyers of the covered bond would prevail over the rest
of creditors to collect on such mortgages until recovery of their
investment, irrespective of whoever purchases the bankrupt entity.
This is what distinguishes them from asset-backed securities where
the investor assumes the direct default of the mortgages. In the
case of the covered bond, the risk belongs to the entity and, second
to the default of the mortgages, and thus they have a dual guaran-
tee and lesser likelihood of default. Moreover, the rating agencies
require the over-collateralisation of the issue, so that if an institu-


78
The Future of the Euro


tion issues a covered bond worth 1000 million euros, they would
be required to provide between 1300 and 1500 in mortgage portfo-
lio as a guarantee. Hence, the entity would first have to be declared
bankrupt and then it should have to have a default in the mortga-
ge portfolio of over 50% for the investor not to recover 100% of his
investment. This helps one to understand that since 2007 no cove-
red bond issued by a European entity has experienced default.
These types of assets do not exist in the US, as the Fannie Mae and
Freddy Mac played the same role, but evidence has shown that the
European system, by maintaining the risk in each institution, was
more efficient and, in fact, there are legislative proposals under way
to develop a covered bond market in the US.


  Until 1997, the companies of peripheral countries such as Spain
found it difficult to issue bonds on the international markets. The
Peseta was a currency which had experienced several devaluations
over the last few decades, its financial markets were very narrow
and were practically taken over in full by public debt. The entry of
the Euro enabled Spanish financial entities to access an organised
market of covered bonds with a longstanding tradition and depth
in Germany, which rapidly spread to all other countries in the area.
As we shall explain shortly, this coincided with a deep and complex
debt crisis in Germany, as a result of the excesses of its Unification,
which increased the savings rate in a structural way, and thus the
supply of top quality credit assets for its financial institutions, insu-
rance companies and pension funds, which in turn boosted the
rapid growth of this market as well as its (Díez 2012b).


                                                                       79
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


     Chart 4
     Spanish covered bonds spreads




     Source: Bloomberg and own data



     In Chart 5 we can see how such structural changes in the fun-
damentals led to a credit boom in the Spanish economy. The ori-
gin of the boom was justified by the fundamentals, but in the end
the only fundamentals were the self-realisable expectations, lea-
ding to the bubble. In 1995, when the likelihood assigned by inves-
tors that Spain would form part of the founder members of the
Euro was very low, practically all of the Spanish bonds in the hands
of non-residents were public. Since then, the percentage of public
debt over GDP had become constant, but when our incorporation


80
The Future of the Euro


into the single currency was approved in 1998, the international
issues market opened up for the private sector and grew exponen-
tially until it doubled that of public debt in terms of GDP. The hea-
ding “other resident sectors” includes the asset-backed securities
funds, rendering most of debt as pertaining to banks.


   Chart 5
   Spanish bonds in the hands of non-residents




   Source: Bank of Spain, INE and own data




   Covered bonds are purely a bank product, despite carrying a
second mortgage guarantee, and are accounted for as bank debt. The
most developed covered bond market in the world was the German


                                                                    81
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


one of Pfandbrife but in Chart 6 one can see how in 2006 the
Spanish banks issued 70,000 million euros in covered bonds, 30%
less than the German banks which had a balance three times as
large as that of Spanish banks. In summer 2007, before the start of
the financial crisis, the outstanding balance of covered bonds issued
by Spanish banks exceeded 300,000 million euros, 30% of the GDP
and an amount equal to the outstanding balance of Spanish public
debt. In 2006, the issues of covered bonds and asset-backed securi-
ties by Spanish banks comfortably exceeded the current account
deficit which was approaching 100,000 million and were the main
financing instrument of our economic, without which it is not pos-
sible to explain the credit and real estate bubble.


     The dynamics were straightforward. The Spanish banks used the
loans granted in retail banking as a guarantee for new issues which
allowed the granting of new credits. The issues of covered bonds
were carried out at variable interest rates of Euribor plus 10 basis
points and the mortgages were granted at Euribor plus 50 basis
points. A strong growth in credit, low rate of default and spreads
between stable asset and liability rates constituted the basis of the
demand for funds of Spanish banks. What were the fundamentals
of the supply of funds? The key lay in the Shadow Banking System
(FSB 2011, European Commission 2012). This consisted mainly of
vehicles created by international banks, based in tax havens and
not consolidated in their balance sheets and thus outside the peri-
meter of oversight by the central banks. The vehicles purchased
assets, mainly of high credit quality and were funded by the com-


82
The Future of the Euro



   Chart 6
   Issues of Covered Bonds




   Source: International Monetary Fund



mercial paper market using those assets as guarantees. Let us assu-
me that the vehicle bought a covered bond at Euribor plus 10 basis
points and was funded by Euribor commercial paper. This resulted
in a profit of 10 basis points per transaction. If the vehicle only had
5% of capital and 95% of debt, this meant a 20-fold leverage, such
that the yield over equity was Euribor plus 200 basis points.


   The growth of the shadow banking system was exponential and
in 2007 in the US reached 20 billion dollars, whereas the non-sha-
dow banking system supervised by the Federal Reserve amounted


                                                                     83
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


to 16 billion dollars. The asset-based leverage which used mortgage
guarantees already granted enabled the banking system to generate
liquidity in an endogenous manner without having to resort to the
central bank, leading to the loss of monopoly by the monetary aut-
horities of the issue of money in circulation. When in February
2005 Alan Greenspan, then President of the Federal Reserve,
announced that there was an enigma in the behaviour of the bond
market, he was responsible for this for allowing the development of
the shadow banking system. Until 2009, no statistics were publis-
hed on the shadow banking system but, once they became public,
it was much easier to understand the causes of the largest global cre-


     Chart 7
     Current account balance




     Source: International Monetary Fund




84
The Future of the Euro


dit bubble burst since the Great Depression and which was parti-
cularly severe in some Eurozone countries, including Spain.


5.2. Local imbalances:


   Over the last few decades, the economic paradigm has analysed
the real economy and the financial economy separately. The Great
Recession has proven the failure of the paradigm and, as we were
shown by Luca Paciolo in the 13th century, when an economy is
analysed, the assets and liabilities cannot be separated. Therefore,
although it is evident that the hurricane began in the financial
realm, there are imbalances in the real economy which also help
to explain the crisis. Chart 7 shows the divergence between
current account balances among developed and emerging coun-
tries in the last decade. Several causes help explain this phenome-
non which the literature has called “global imbalances” (Caballero
2009).


   The main cause was the aftermath of the Asian crisis of 1997.
The affected countries had large current account deficits and low
levels of currency reserves before the crisis, and subsequently they
geared their economic policy towards exports. This led to current
account surpluses and high currency reserves, and the ensuing
structural increase of the world savings rate (Bernanke 2005). The
accumulation of reserves was concentrated on sovereign funds and
central banks with a conservative approach, which significantly
increased the demand for fixed income funds of top credit quality,


                                                                   85
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


known as AAA. Without understanding the Asian crisis and its con-
sequences it is not possible to understand the intense development
of the shadow banking system and the strong increase in leverage
in the world banking system which has been analysed in the pre-
vious section (Caballero 2008).


     Chart 8 shows how the Eurozone was hardly affected by the
phenomenon of Global Imbalances, with a current account balan-
ce close to equilibrium since the Asian crisis. However, Chart 8
shows that there have indeed been huge differences between the
countries within the Euro and, for this reason, the phenomenon
has now been called Local Imbalances. In 2001 Germany suffered a
debt crisis similar to the one suffered at present in Spain, although
it hardly translated into a current account or foreign debt deficit.
Germany, as was the case in Japan in the eighties, suffered from a
problem of over-indebtedness of households and businesses, with
real estate bubble, burst and depression all thrown in to the packa-
ge. Following the burst of the bubble in 2000, German households
were reluctant to take on debt and structurally increased their
savings rate to reduce such a debt. Private consumption plumme-
ted and businesses sought the supply that was absent in the domes-
tic market in the export market. The fiscal revenue dropped dra-
matically and Germany failed to meet the Stability Pact and wat-
ched its public debt increase significantly until 2005.


     The birth of the euro and the credit boom in peripheral coun-
tries enabled Germany to overcome the severe recession thanks to


86
The Future of the Euro


the strength of its exports. Moreover, German savings found an
easy path without assuming exchange rate risk with its partners in
the Eurozone. The causes of the Euro crisis are focused on the
analysis of the imbalances of debtor countries, but it is not possi-
ble to understand and explain the crisis without analysing the
saver countries, particularly Germany. Debtor countries are facing
a prolonged period of debt reduction, which will ensure a weak
internal demand, and shall be obliged to show a current account
surplus as was the case in Asia in 1998 and in Germany in 2001.
But this will not be possible if the creditor countries reduce their
current account surpluses and boost internal demand.



   Chart 8
   Current account balance




   Source: International Monetary Fund and own data




                                                                   87
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


5.3. The Great Recession:


     The European Monetary Union was born with institutional pro-
blems but these did not become evident and to put its viability at
risk until 2009. Chart 9 shows how the Great Recession which rava-
ged the world and Europe in 2008 has been the worst for seventy
years, although it did not reach the depth and length of the Great
Depression, which it is being called the Great Recession. Without
an earthquake of this force, it is possible that the institutional flaws
of the European project could have endured for longer, but the cri-
sis has highlighted them and the Euro is now at a crossroads.


     In 2007 it was financial disturbances which anticipated the
recession. Chart 6 shows how the covered bond market practically
dried up for Spanish banks as well as for all other indebted coun-
tries. This brought the credit boom to a halt and acted as the trig-
ger for the recession. In 2008 the disorderly collapse of Lehman led
to the worst global run since the Great Depression. The investors
quickly resorted to short term public debt of the internal reserve
currencies, the money markets dried up as did the currency mar-
kets, and world trade collapsed in a matter of weeks. The coordi-
nated reaction of the G20 with the most expansive monetary, fis-
cal and financial policy in history prevented the world from ente-
ring into a depression and enabled a V-shaped recovery of world
economy and trade in 2009.




88
The Future of the Euro



   Chart 9
   GDP EU 15




   Source: Angus Maddison. University of Groningen




  Economics is an empirical science but it is difficult to find
homogeneous experiments to compare policies, but this crisis has
provided one. The Great Recession was synchronized and most
countries entered into recession at the same time. However, the
recovery since 2009 has been disparate and the economic policies
have been very different between the US and the Eurozone, which
enables a comparison of its effects to be drawn. Europe began fis-
cal consolidation at the beginning of 2010, despite the boost
given in 2008 to get out of the recession, whereas the US has con-
tinued to renew its fiscal incentive plans. The ECB has been reluc-
tant to intervene and has only done so when the markets have
been on the edge of collapse and it even took the liberty of incre-


                                                                  89
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


asing the interest rated in July 2011, making the same mistake as
in July 2008, anticipating the recession. The Federal Reserve has
kept its rates at 0% and has renewed its quantitative policies.


     After two years of experimenting, what has the result been? The
growth in the US has been twice that of Europe, its inflation has
also doubled and its unemployment rate has reduced to 8.5%,
whereas in Europe it has exceeded 10%. In the US, several states,
among them California and Florida, burst their real estate bubbles
and California defaulted on payments and created its own
currency, what was known in Argentina as Patacones. Therefore,
the Euro crisis is not the cause of the problems in Europe but
simply the result of mistakes made in economic policy in Europe
since 2009. Neither is the argument of the greater rigidity of
European labour markets and the mobility problems between
countries valid. In the US, the unemployment rate increased with
equal intensity in states which did not have a real estate bubble,
thus confirming that the cause of the growth in unemployment
was a sharp drop in demand caused by an intense banking crisis
and credit restriction. But the most spectacular result of the expe-
riment is probably what happened with public finances. The US,
without resorting to raising taxes, without great cuts and simply by
freezing public expenditure has managed to increase fiscal revenue
by 12% and has reduced the deficit by four percentage points of
GDP. Europe, by raising taxes and cutting costs has managed a
revenue increase of 6% and a reduction of the deficit of two points
of GDP.


90
The Future of the Euro


   The emergence of almost ten points of public deficit in a new
Government in Greece was the spark which ignited the Euro crisis
which we currently face. The Greek Tragedy spread first to Portugal,
then to Ireland, and currently threatens Spain and Italy, thus
having affected one third of the GDP of the Eurozone, (Díez, 2012).
Chart 2 shows how the Great Recession began a process of finan-
cial disintegration in the Eurozone which was intensified by the
Greek Tragedy and the contagion of all other economies. In a
monetary union, the outflow of capital is equal to a contractive
monetary policy and, on the contrary, the inflow of capital is
expansive. This helps us to understand why the countries subjected
to financial tension entered once again into deep recession in 2011
whereas Germany, the main receiver of capital flows, has continued
to grow.


6. Conclusion

   The European project is a political one and it is born out of the
need to end wars and conflicts which had ravaged Europe in the
20th century. The Euro was an attempt to accelerate the political
union but has ended up being a headlong flight.


· The Euro is the most extreme version of a fixed exchange rate.
  Indeed, it is reinforced and with high cost of departure, which
  renders it more credible, but while it lacks a political union there
  will always be doubts as to whether it will be a single currency.




                                                                    91
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


· In the nineties the benefits – and there were some which have
     been clearly demonstrated – of the creation of the euro were
     overvalued. But at the same time there was an under-assessment
     of the costs which reality has proven were also there. The two
     main institutional problems which must be solved are: i) the
     absence of a fiscal union to complement the monetary union
     and ii) the absence of a lender of last resort due to the limita-
     tions imposed on the ECB in its bylaws.


· Financial integration and the undervaluation of risk, both glo-
     bal phenomena, are essential to explain the credit boom and the
     problem of over-indebtedness which are the origin of the Euro
     Crisis. The case of the covered bonds is a good example that not
     only were credit risks undervalued, but liquidity risk was likewi-
     se under-assessed.


· The Local Imbalances, the high current account surplus in
     Germany and the deficits in Spain and other countries forced
     the transfer of financial flows and boosted the credit boom and
     over-indebtedness. Countries subjected to financial tension are
     implementing sharp reductions in their current accounts, but
     Germany has hardly reduced its foreign surplus since 2007.


· The institutional problems of the Eurozone became apparent at
     the Great Recession, as a result of the sharp drop in activity and
     the collapse of the financial markets and credit channels which
     have rendered many debts unsustainable and unpayable.


92
The Future of the Euro


  Without such a deep recession, the problems would have taken
  longer to appear.


· The aim of this article was not to discuss solutions, but from the
  analysis of the nature and causes of the Euro crisis, we can con-
  clude that the solution must: i) dispel doubts as to the future via-
  bility of the euro, ii) to do so we must work towards the fiscal
  union and the creation of Eurobonds would be the precedent for
  a future single European treasury, iii) we must change the bylaws
  of the ECB so that it may act as a lender of last resort as the
  Federal Reserve does in the US, iv) we must halt the process of
  financial disintegration and ensure the return of part of the capi-
  tal flows which have exited from peripheral countries, and v) we
  must urgently reactivate growth in Europe. In order to do so, the
  monetary policy must opt for quantitative strategies of debt pur-
  chase, the fiscal policy must be less restrictive and the financial
  institutions and countries with greater solvency problems must
  be recapitalized in order to restore the credit channels as soon as
  possible.




                                                                    93
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


Bibliography

- Bernanke, B. (2005). “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current
Account Deficit”. Federal Reserve Speech 10 March.


-    Bernanke, B. (2007). “The Financial Accelerator and the Credit
Channel”. Federal Reserve Speech 15 June.


-    Caballero, Ricardo J., Farhi, Emmanuel and Gourinchas, Pierre-
Olivier (2008), "An Equilibrium Model of ‘Global Imbalances' and Low
Interest Rates," American Economic Review, vol. 98 (1), pp. 358-93.


- Caballero, Ricardo J. and Krishnamurthy, Arvind (2009), "Global
Imbalances and Financial Fragility," American Economic Review:
Papers & Proceedings, vol. 99 (May), pp. 584-88.


- European Commission (2012) “El Sistema Bancario en la Sombra”.
Libro verde, Marzo.


- De Grauwe, Paul (2009) Economics of Monetary Union 9 ed.
Oxford University Press. Oxford.


- Díez, José Carlos (2012) “Crisis de la Deuda Europea: crisis de emer-
gentes o sumergidos” Papeles de Economía Española 130 January,
pag. 150-166.




94
The Future of the Euro


-   Díez, José Carlos (2012b) “El Sistema Bancario tras la Gran
Recesión” Mediterráneo Económico 20 January, pag. 329-345.


-   Dornbusch, Rudiger. (1976) "Expectations and Exchange Rate
Dynamics." Journal of Political Economy 84: pag. 1161-76.


- Eichengreen, Barry, and Wyplosz, Charles (1998) “The Stability
Pact: Stabilizing or Destabilizing?” Economic Policy 26 April, pag. 65-
113.


- Eichengreen, Barry and O’Rourke, Kevin (2010), A tale of two
depressions: What do the new data tell us? February 2010 update,
VoxEU.org, 8 March.


-   European Commission (1998) “Convergence Report 1998”,
Bruselas.


- European Monetary Institute, Convergence Report, Frankfurt am
Main, March 1998.


-      FSB, Financial Stability Board (2011) Shadow Banking:
Strengthening Oversight and Regulation. October.


-   Friedman, Milton (1953) The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates.
Essays in Positive Economics.




                                                                     95
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis


- Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953, pp. 157-203. Chicago.


- Keynes, John M. (1992) Breve Tratado sobre la Reforma Monetaria.
Fondo de Cultura Económica de España. Madrid.


- Meade, James (1957) The Balance of Payments Problems of a Free
Trade Area.


- Economic Journal, Sept. 67, 379-96.


- Mundell, Robert (1961) A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. The
American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4., pp. 657-665.


- Nurkse, Ragnar (1942). International Currency Experience. Lessons
from the Inter-War period. League of Nations, p. 188. Genova.


- Obstfeld, Maurice (1998) EMU: Ready, or Not? Working Paper.
University of California, Berkeley.


- Rodríguez Prada, Gonzalo (1994) Teoría y estrategias de la integra-
ción económica y monetaria: con aplicaciones a los casos de la UE, el
NAFTA y el MERCOSUR. Universidad de Alcalá. Alcalá de Henares.


- Torrero, A. (2006) Crisis Financieras: Enseñanzas de Cinco Episodios.
Marcial Pons. Madrid.




96
/JUERGEN B. DONGES * /




    The European crisis and the challenge
        of efficient economic governance




1. Introduction; 2. The root cause of the problem: too much economic diver-
gence; 2.1. A suboptimal monetary area; 3. Attempted governance in an
indirect manner; 3.1. Breach of the fiscal rules; 4. Governance as activism
against the crisis; 4.1. Constituent principles, violated; 4.2. Financial assis-
tance, a never-ending story?; 4.3. Political pressure to impose discipline,
insufficient so far; 4.4. Financial markets, with capacity to persuade; 5. New
governance design: own responsibility as the key; 5.1. The euro Plus Pact, it
is not binding on anyone; 5.2. The Fiscal Stability Pact, a test of nine; 5.3.
The Macro-economic Governance Pact, with vague parameters; Conclusion




* Professor emeritus of economics at the Faculty of Economic and Social Sciences of the
University of Cologne (Germany). From 1969 to 1989 he managed several economic
analysis departments at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy, in which he was the
Vice-chairman for the previous six years until he took the chair in 1989 in Cologne. He
is currently a Senior Fellow of the Cologne Institute for Economic Policy. He was the
Chairman of the German Council of Economic Experts (the so-called “Five Wise Men”)
and the German Commission on Economic Deregulation. He is an economic advisor in
several academic institutions and foundations in Germany, Spain and in other coun-
tries. He is also a member of the Supervisory Board of several multinational companies.
He is the author of several books and articles published in academic journals on inter-
national economy and public policies in the field of macro and micro economy.


                                                                             97
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


1. Introduction

The purpose of this article is to focus the current discussion on the
need for economic governance in the European Union (EU) and, in
particular, in the euro area, in the context of the political reality.
This is not such an easy task, as it may seem; in practice the rela-
tions between national governments, on the one hand, and these
and the European Commission and the European Parliament, on
the other, end up being profoundly redefined, with more European
powers and less national sovereignty.


        This topic is not new; it has been on the table at the mee-
tings of the European Council of the Heads of State and
Government since the formation of the European Single Market 25
years ago (1986 Single European Act). We can interpret agreements
leading to a coordination of economic policies, as the initial step
towards “smooth” European economic governance, specifically to
(i) promote employment (1997 European Summit of Luxembourg),
(ii) apply structural reforms conducive to flexibility in the product
and factor markets (1998 Cardiff Summit), and (iii) institutionalise
macro-economic dialogue among the governments, the European
Central Bank (ECB) and social partners (1999 Cologne Summit).
Apart from the above steps we should add (iv) the agreement of the
European Council in 2010 to launch a strategy of structural reforms
that would make the EU at the end of that decade the most dyna-
mic economic area in the world.




98
The Future of the Euro


  These agreements which were then celebrated as a landmark in
the European integration process have not given the desired results.
The reason is very simple: over and above the rhetoric, the govern-
ments were not willing to co-operate if the alleged or true national
interests indicated otherwise. Such governance installed in the
European Council, the Ecofin and in other councils of ministers
involved, lacked any kind of power of management and supervi-
sion of the economic and fiscal policies of the member states.


   At the current debate the great hope is that in the future
national interests will come second, giving way to the “More
Europe”, as the new political logo reads. The aim is to reach gre-
ater and efficient intra-European co-ordination of the economic
policy of the member countries. This aim was raised in 2011-
2012 in three basic agreements: (i) the Euro Plus Pact (to strengt-
hen the competitiveness and growth capacity of the economies),
(ii) The Fiscal Stability Pact (Fiscal Compact to guarantee in all
the countries the sustainability of public finances in the medium
and long term) and (iii) the Macro-economic Governance Pact
(Economic Governance Six Pack, to ensure economic and fiscal
policies compatible with the internal and external balance in the
economies). Now, the declarations of intent are one thing, put-
ting them into practice and applying the appropriate economic
policies, is quite another. Why should what politicians promise
today be believable, if in the past (and today, as many of them
are still around) did not fulfil their commitments?




                                                                   99
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


      I will now analyse governance in its past and present dimen-
sions. The following section emphasises the significant fact that
the euro area is not an optimal monetary area. In the third and
fourth sections the forms of governance relied on until now are
analysed. The fifth section deals with the new approach for
European governance. The last section concludes the analysis in a
tone of moderate hope.




2. The root cause of the problem: too much economic
divergence

      The crisis of the sovereign debt in Europe has shown a serious
fault in the formation of the single currency: trusting that the
governments of the member countries would apply quality econo-
mic policies in accordance with the common interest of all the
partners, as set forth in the EU Treaty (articles 2 and 121), was
naive. In Germany, I together with many other economists noticed
this fault then, but political leaders took no notice or it was labe-
lled as “academic” and, therefore, irrelevant to take great historical
decisions. The leaders simply invoked the criterion of the so-called
supremacy of politics over economics, as they do today when they
run from one summit to the next to rescue certain countries from
bankruptcy and try to stabilise the euro area.




100
The Future of the Euro


2.1. A suboptimal monetary area


  The architects of the euro area, from the 1989 Delors Report,
knew that a monetary union would not be feasible in the long run
without a fiscal union, not to mention political union. The history
of the different monetary unions in Europe in the 19th Century
had left an unequivocal message: all of them failed because of
incompatibilities among the budgetary policies of the member
countries. However, during the negotiations of what would become
the Maastricht Treaty (of 1992) the prerogative of national budge-
tary policy was sealed. The then two main characters of the
European project, the German Chancellor Helmut Kohl and the
French President François Mitterrand, fascinated their counterparts
with their vision of the euro as a pacemaker to accelerate and to go
into greater integration. More than one will remember the famous
statement of the French Finance Minister, Jacques Rueff, ‘Europe
shall be made through the currency, or it shall not be made’ (1950),
and they took it literally. The French statesman could never have
imagined such a deteriorated environment of public finances as we
have today in many European countries.


  It was also clear that the five convergence criteria set forth in the
Maastricht Treaty, even if they could be fulfilled (something that
not all countries have done), did not guarantee an optimal mone-
tary area (in terms of the theory of Robert Mundell and others). In
Europe, it would have been essential for the countries to be quite
homogeneous in terms of economic development and functioning


                                                                    101
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


of the institutions or the prices and salaries in the various countries
should have been flexible enough (especially downwards in coun-
tries with weak growth and great structural unemployment), or for
European mobility of labour to be high (from backward regions
with high unemployment rates to dynamic regions with shortage
of workers). These conditions for an optimal monetary area did not
happen twenty years ago and do not happen today. The difference
between Europe and the United States in this is significant.


      Only a group of countries in the euro area (in central and nort-
hern Europe) at least met then and meets now the condition of
homogeneity. The countries in the southern periphery were not,
strictu sensu, ready for their accession in 1999 to the monetary
union and, therefore, to waive a monetary and exchange rate
policy as adjustment facilities of internal imbalances (inflation)
and external imbalances (current account deficit) and to under-
take tax regulations that would restrict government deficit and
the level of government debt. It is not a coincidence that these
countries have had for the past two years a risk of insolvency (not
to have the capacity to re-finance the debt in the capital market
under affordable conditions), as only sovereign countries have, if
the State may not resort to the Central Bank to secure financing
and must get it by issuing bonds in a foreign currency. Greece
may be the most illustrative example of having done what the
German Council of Economic Experts has classified as an “origi-
nal sin”, in other words, having rushed into accessing the mone-
tary union in 2001, forced even through deceit (hiding the truth


102
The Future of the Euro


of their fiscal statistics): the country is now at the mercy of the
international financial markets (rating agencies), after having
revealed the serious structural deficiencies in the economy and
the public institutions, which has led to a low growth potential
and low levels of productivity and competitiveness clearly insuf-
ficient at this time (globalisation of competition).




3. Attempted governance in an indirect manner

   It was conceptually logical that with the creation of the single
currency the powers on monetary policy would be transferred
from the National Central Banks to the new ECB. However, as the
budgetary policy would carry on being a national responsibility,
two principles constituting the euro area were established in
order to guarantee the sustainability of the public finances in the
member countries and to ensure that the monetary union would
work as a price stability union.


• The two principles proclaimed in the Maastrich Treaty are the
   prohibition to bail out insolvent partners, on the one hand,
   and the prohibition imposed on the ECB to finance govern-
   ment deficits (no monetisation), on the other hand. These
   clauses are contained in the most recent version of the Treaty
   on the European Union (the Treaty of Lisbon of 2007) in arti-
   cles 125 and 123, respectively.




                                                                 103
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


       • The two provisions were supplemented with the Stability and
             Growth Pact (SGP) approved in 1997 at the European Summit
             in Amsterdam; in it a ceiling for national budget deficits (3%
             of GDP) and government debt (60% of GDP) were established
             under the assumption that the growth rate of the nominal
             GDP in the euro area would be 5% in the medium term.1


             With all this, indirect governance elements were created, in
        other words, formally maintaining national powers in budgetary
        policy, but controlling the use of the powers that could destroy
        the feasibility of the euro area.


             The monetary union was not designed to pay debts jointly and
        generate financial transfers from certain States to others, as many
        today think that that is the case, appealing to solidarity among
        peoples. There was already solidarity, and there still is, in the
        good sense of the concept: the more developed countries of the
        EU must help the least developed for these to advance in real
        convergence; the various European Structural Funds are for this.
        But it is not compatible with the concept of solidarity; it rather
        constitutes a “perversion” (Issing) of it, having to rescue a society
        that underestimates saving, tends to consume ostentatiously,
        tolerates waste by the public authorities, does not fulfil tax obli-


1 For a profound analysis see A. Brunila, M. Buti and D. Franco (ed.), The Stability and
Growth Pact: The architecture of fiscal policy in EMU. Houndsmills/Basingstoke (United
Kingdom): Palgrave, 2001 – Círculo de Empresarios (ed.), Pacto de Estabilidad y
Crecimiento: alternativas e implicaciones. Libro Marrón 2002. Madrid (December).


       104
The Future of the Euro


gations and claims social benefits beyond the means of the
country, given its own resources.


3.1. Breach of the fiscal rules


The architecture of indirect governance crumbled when it had to
pass the first real test, in 2002/03. In those days, Germany
(Schröder) and France (Chirac) violated the the fiscal rules of the
game. In Germany, government deficit had reached 3.7% of GDP
in 2002 and 3.8% in 2003; in France, it was 3.2% and 4.1% respec-
tively. In both cases, most part of the deficit was structural. The
European Commission had activated, according to the SGP, the
supervisory mechanism for ‘excessive government deficit’ against
these two countries. The German Chancellor explicitly rejected the
intervention from Brussels, the same as the French President. They
both imposed their criterion at the European Council in November
2003, which suspended the process (against the votes of Austria,
Spain, Finland and Holland). The then President of the European
Commission, Romano Prodi, had described the SGP in an inter-
view (on 18/10/02) as “stupido”, which is highly surprising coming
from the custodian of the European Treaties.


   At the European Summit held in March 2005, the SGP was
amended, watering it down a great deal: with new exceptions for
breaking the rules, an assessment of the budgetary situation on a
case-by-case basis, considering the special circumstances of each
country, relaxing the periods to take the necessary adjustment


                                                                 105
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


       measures, the differentiation among countries as regards the goal
       of budgetary consolidation in the medium-term and some com-
       plex and non-transparent supervisory mechanisms.2 We must
       remember this in order to understand the reason for the current
       proposals to depoliticise (“automate”) the decisions on sanctions
       in case of an infringement of the fiscal regulations.


             With the erosion of the SGP, the factors that determined the cri-
       sis of the current sovereign debt, put down roots, a crisis which
       would have happened anyway, if the 2007-09 global financial and
       economic crisis had not have appeared. If the governments of the
       two main countries of the euro area are skipping the Treaty of
       Europe and the SGP, why wouldn’t the rest do the same if this is
       what is best for them and open the tap of non-productive public
       expenditure? Structural government deficits increased conside-
       rably and with this the volume of the government debt. With this
       precedent, the supervision of national budgetary policies by the
       European Commission was reduced to merely a rhetorical exercise
       that did not scare the rulers much. Economic governance in an
       indirect manner had failed. The ECB, however, fulfilled its role and
       its first president, Wim Duisenberg, did not allow political leaders
       to tie his hands, despite their attempts.




2 For this purpose, the European Commission adapted the original regulations No
1466/97 and 1467/97 of 7/7/1997; see COM (2005) 154 and COM (2005) 155 of
20/4/2005.


      106
The Future of the Euro


4. Governance as activism against the crisis

   The threat of Greece’s suspension of payments two years ago
showed lack of efficient European economic governance. Instead,
a rare and disconcerting political activism appeared. The nume-
rous measures taken since May 2010 in Europe seem more like an
exercise of muddling through than implementation of a consis-
tent and long-term strategy.


4.1. Constituent principles, violated


   It all started in the worst possible manner: the Governments eli-
minated in one fell swoop the two principles establishing the euro
area mentioned above.


   The lifting of the non-rescue clause created the problem of
moral hazard for Governments with a tendency to excessive public
expenditure and for reckless banks when it comes to buying
government bonds. The Governments could pass the cost of exces-
sive indebtedness to taxpayers from other countries (who had no
right to speak or vote when the budgets of the State in question
were drafted). The banks started a tremendous communication
campaign to warn of the danger of the euro area (systemic risks) if
indebted countries were not rescued, efficiently concealing to the
public opinion that their true intention was to protect their share-
holders.




                                                                  107
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


      Under the presidency of Trichet, the ECB was under pressure to
undertake a new role: the role of being a “repair shop” for the
faults in the fiscal and growth policies. It acquired in the Securities
Markets Programme, big sums of Treasury bonds from countries in
trouble which nobody wants. Here lies the difference with other
relevant central banks (the Federal Reserve, the Bank of England,
the Bank of Japan), they also buy government securities in the con-
text of their non-conventional monetary policies, but these are
assets with considerable profitability. Furthermore, the ECB
currently grants unlimited liquidity to banks for three years, at a
symbolic interest rate (1%) and it accepts low quality securities as
guarantee. But it is not in its hand to lead banks to proper granting
of credit to companies or households in the country under affor-
dable conditions; the ECB must resign itself to banks choosing
more profitable business in the short-term, as purchasing the debt
of the State; therefore, there is not much change in the scenario of
credit restriction in the private sector in several countries, like in
Spain. The European monetary entity is not only “a last resort len-
der” anymore, which in situations of financial emergency is justi-
fiable, but it has also become “a public debt buyer of last resort”,
which is more questionable, because it delays the fiscal adjust-
ments of the Governments (and it caused in 2011 the resignation
of two German senior members of the monetary authority bodies,
first the resignation of Axel Weber, President of the Bundesbank
and ex officio member of the ECB Governing Council and, subse-
quently, the resignation of Jürgen Stark, member of the Board of
the ECB and its chief economist). The role that the ECB is playing,


108
The Future of the Euro


for the moment also under its new president (Draghi), may dama-
ge its reputation as an institution independent of political powers
and commited to price stability, which is what it has been entrus-
ted with in the European Treaty.


   An additional problem is that the same standards of asset qua-
lity, which are used as collateral in the re-financing of commercial
banks by the National Central Bank itself (and, as such, part of the
Eurosystem), do not govern in the whole of the euro area anymo-
re. In several countries in trouble, especially with persistent current
account deficits which (already) do not finance in a conventional
manner import of capital or through financial assistance from
abroad, the respective National Central Banks, with permission
from the ECB, accept low quality securities as guarantee of loans,
more than what is allowed for emergency liquidity assistance. It is
as if they were using the money printing press. This somewhat
undermines the monopoly of the ECB to create money. What is
questionable from an economic perspective is hidden behind the
enormous increase in the amount of these operations in the
Eurosystem Target 2 in the past years, which has been vehemently
warned by the Ifo Institute of Munich for the last year.3 The
Bundesbank has become a gigantic creditor of hundreds of millions
of euros for the National Central Banks of the other countries, wit-


3 See H.-W. Sinn and T. Wollmershäuser, “Target Loans, Current Account Balances and
Capital Flows: The ECB’s Rescue Facility”, NBER Working Paper, No 17626 (November).
CESifo, “The European Balance of Payments Crisis”, CESifo Forum, Special Issue, January
2012.


                                                                           109
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


       hout protection and right to any kind of compensation if there is
       any significant bankruptcy of banks and savings banks or if the
       euro area collapses. The Governments of debtor countries have in
       reserve a powerful argument to manage to get from others, espe-
       cially from Germany, concessions in the negotiations over finan-
       cial assistance.


       4.2. Financial assistance, a never-ending story?


             Political leaders believed, and some of them still do, that the
       creation of a common rescue fund is the solution to the problems
       of countries in trouble and it eliminates possible spillover effects.


             The first rescue mechanism was created with the European
       Financial Stability Facility (EFSF).4 This fund is provisional (three
       years, until 2013) and at the beginning had a provision of 440,000
       million euros in loans guaranteed by the euro countries; as the
       Fund wanted to place their issues with the highest ranking ‘AAA’
       to get attractive profitability, the real lending capacity would be
       lower than the allocation, about 250,000 million euros. Ireland
       (87,500 million euros) and Portugal (78,000 million euros) had to
       resort to this Fund. Subsequently, in July 2011, the European
       Council decided to increase the real lending capacity of this rescue
       fund to 440,000 million euros and, in addition, increase their



4 EU Council of Ministers (Ecofin), EFSF Framework Agreement, 9/5/10 and 7/6/10.
Web page: http://www.efsf.europa.eu (Legal documents).


       110
The Future of the Euro


powers and relax the conditions for granting the loans to countries
in trouble. It even received leverage instruments (with a 4 factor)
and the so-called ‘special purpose vehicles’ (off-balance); such ins-
truments, applied by private banks, were exactly the ones that trig-
gered very harmful effects for the global financial crisis to break in
2008.


   In mid-2012, six months in advance to the original schedule, a
new permanent rescue fund will come into force, the ‘European
Stabilisation Mechanism’ (ESM).5 This fund will have a provision
in nominal terms of 700,000 million euros (with capital contribu-
tions from the member countries amounting to 80,000 million
euros); the real lending capacity of this new Fund is 500,000
million euros. Provisionally, the amount of available resources may
amount to about 800,000 million euros, by transferring the unused
EFSF resources. The IMF, the OECD, the United States and China,
among others, recommend a higher firewall (up to 1.5 billion
euros).


   In parallel with these events, a special treatment has been given
to Greece. After the initial financial assistance plan approved in
May 2010 (110,000 million euros, of which 30,000 million euros
came from the IMF), of which politicians said that it would enable


5 European Council, Treaty Establishing the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), 25/3/11.
Internet: http://www.efsf.europa.eu (Legal documents). – European Council, Treaty sig-
ned by the 17 euro area Member States, 2/2/12. Internet:
http://www.european.council.europa.eu.



                                                                            111
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


the country to return to the capital market in 2013, in February
this year a second package was agreed (130,000 million euros,
including a contribution from the IMF, to which a further amount
of 24,400 million euros of the first package pending payment will
be added). The latest thing is that private creditors will undertake
(about 85.8% voluntarily and the rest will be obliged by law) a
deduction of 53.5% and will agree for the rest of their securities an
exchange for new Greek long-term treasury bonds and of the EFSF
Fund at a moderate interest rate (which will reduce the Greek
public debt in about 107,000 million euros of a total of 350,000
million euros). Greece’s main public creditor, the ECB, has escaped
this operation and the asset losses derived from it, by means of a
trick, quickly exchanging their former Hellenic bonds, which
would have undergone a reduction, for new exempt bonds under
the same condition.


      The official aim is to get the public debt to be reduced from the
current 160% of GDP to about 120% of GDP in 2020. The Ecofin
believes that this level is sustainable, which is quite surprising for
three reasons: firstly, this level was what Greece had in 2008/09,
already in the increase and considered unsustainable then;
secondly, the tax authorities must improve a great deal in order to
promote the capacity to collect taxes and stop tax fraud and capi-
tal flight; and thirdly the IMF’s estimates of 2-3% economic growth
per year from 2014 must be fulfilled, which implies that the neces-
sary structural reforms must be quickly implemented and the eco-
nomy must reach considerable gains in international competitive-


112
The Future of the Euro


ness by substantial salary and price reductions (according to the
estimates, about 50%). All of these points are question marks. The
most probable thing is that the announced aim of debt reduction
will not be attained and that the European governments sooner or
later will again have on the negotiating table Greece’s request for
further financial assistance.


4.3. Political pressure to impose discipline, insufficient so far


   The European form of governance since the sovereign crisis star-
ted in Greece has always been “more of the same”: to want to solve
a problem of excessive indebtedness with more debt. The critical
public opinion, as in Germany, was calmed down by saying that no
cash was going to be paid from national budgets and, therefore,
from taxpayers (although there will be in the ESM), but that each
government “only” had to provide guarantees (distributed among
the countries according to the holdings of the national central
banks in the share capital of the ECB). As if guarantees could not be
enforced at the demand of the creditors, in other words, buyers of
the securities issued by the EFSF/ESM! The expectations to calm
down the markets, restore confidence and stabilise the euro area
were not met. The markets had noticed that, in the countries badly
affected by the sovereign debt crisis, progress in fiscal consolidation
and structural reforms that raise the potential of growth and com-
petitiveness, which there are, were too slow and incomplete.




                                                                     113
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


      This was caused from outside. The aided governments have not
forgotten the political messages launched from the beginning of
the crisis from Brussels/Paris/Berlin. The messages that are least for-
gotten and carry on being repeated with slight variations, are the
following: (i) “We will rescue the euro, no matter what it costs”
(Barroso); (ii) “We will not allow anyone to fall into insolvency”
(Sarkozy); (iii) “If the euro fails, Europe fails” (Merkel). There could
be no better invitation for irresponsible governments to blackmail.
That is how a government in trouble is tempted not to consistently
take pure and hard measures, therefore reducing the cost of loss of
political support, which any severe fiscal adjustment plan (with
unnavoidable cuts in salaries and social benefits and necessary rise
of taxes) would imply. In Greece it is already normal for the Troika
(the European Commission, the ECB and the IMF), each time that
it visits Athens to verify if Greece’s government has implemented
its commitments, to confirm that there is lack of forcefulness in the
policies applied, especially in relation to the structural reforms. But
as the President of the euro group, Juncker, and the Ecofin finally
have given the green light for new aid tranches to be given, the
government (after Papandreou, Papademos) could, after long nego-
tiations, according to the demands of his European partners, and
once at home, do half of it. He could even reject the proposals made
by his partners (Germany, the first) to provide administrative advi-
ce in situ, for instance, in order to create an efficient tax agency and
to design and manage infrastructure investment projects.




114
The Future of the Euro


   If with the aid programmes the idea was to buy time to imple-
ment structural reforms in the real economy, as the political leaders
repeatedly emphasised, time was not used productively in all the
countries involved, and Spain was no exception during the last
part of Zapatero’s government, when the crisis was not officially
denied anymore: fiscal and economic consolidation policies arri-
ved late and lacked consistency and force.


4.4. Financial markets, with capacity to persuade


   One way of overcoming the reluctance of the governments to
inexorable political and economic changes in their respective
countries comes from the market, specifically the spreads of the
risk premiums included in the interest rates where the Treasury
may place their issues.


   As mentioned above, the risk premiums of ten-year bonds, with
reference to the German bond, “bund”, reached rocket prices in
Greece in 2011 and also considerably in the other peripheral coun-
tries with debt problems, including Spain, where the interest rates
reached all-time highs of several hundred basis points. The same
happened with the credit default swaps (CDS) premiums. No mat-
ter how much the governments criticised financial agents for this,
not to mention also the three main rating agencies (Fitch, Moody’s,
Standard & Poor’s), we cannot understimate its deterrent effect
when it is intended to go into greater debt. The increase in price of
the debt convinced political leaders in the countries in trouble that


                                                                   115
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


the time of spending happily had gone and that they had to be
prepared for a future characterised by austerity. The new govern-
ment of Spain (Rajoy) is an example of strict action to modify
unsustainable habits in society and restore the economy. In Italy
there was a big change of direction since a government of techno-
crats (Monti) started in November last year. Ireland had already
started in March 2011, after early parliamentary elections and the
formation of the new government (Kenny). Three months after
that, the same happened in Portugal (Passos Coelho).


      Therefore, any decision to artificially reduce the interest rates of
government bonds, as it has already been taken within the context
of rescue packages and as some governments claim, is counterpro-
ductive. Eliminating the mechanisms of the market that act, wit-
hout political interference, in favour of the quality of public finan-
ces, is pointless. Mutualisation of the sovereign debt, no matter
how much it is proclaimed by certain political circles (also Spanish,
irrespective of ideologies), as well as academic (including German,
Keynesian ideas) and financial (especially the most important
banks which are anxious to operate in capital markets with great
liquidity, comparable to the U.S. market) circles, is also pointless.
There is no reason why we should think that issuing eurobonds
would improve the quality of the economic policy in the euro area.
On the contrary, a reduction in the price of credit in the countries
in trouble, which the eurobond would entail, would deteriorate the
estimates of low cost, which all categories of public sector outlays
and any decision by the public authorities on loan finance, would


116
The Future of the Euro


be subjected to; furthermore, it would be impossible to put pressu-
re on a government from outside to control expenditure and opti-
mise tax collection; and, in addition, restructuring processes in the
real economy, which are so important to raise the potential of
growth, would be postponed. It is far better for the financial mar-
kets to deploy their penalising effects and thus complement the
relevant mechanisms planned by the SGP and the coming Fiscal
Stability Pact.




5. New governance design: own responsibility as the key

   It seems that European leaders got it into their heads that the euro
area needs another kind of governance different from what we have
had until now.


   We will have to carry on thinking in the need for official assiss-
tance for certain countries, not only for Greece. As regards Greece,
maybe we must think of two options: one, exiting the euro, in
principle on a provisional basis (until the fundamental problems
have been solved) and continue as a EU member; two, exiting the
Economic and Monetary Union, also for a certain time, but kee-
ping the euro as dual currency circulation with their own currency.


   Politicians now understand better than in the past that, for the
feasibility of the monetary union in the long term, we need robust
and resilient foundations to prevent external shocks of offer and


                                                                    117
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


demand, both from outside and from inside (which in some way or
another will happen again). It is not enough to have a determined
common monetary policy dealt with by a competent European aut-
hority with aims of stability and orderly functioning of inter-bank
market. This is only one of the required conditions. Two further fun-
damental conditions are inexorable for the context of national eco-
nomic policies:
• On the one hand, there must be some rules on behaviour in bud-
      getary and economic policy compatible with the efficiency crite-
      ria in the allocation of production factors and with growth and
      employment aims. The problem of “moral hazard” must be
      totally eliminated.
•     On the other hand, there must be unconditional willingness of
      the governments to observe these rules and act according to
      them. There must be a clear division of work and responsibility
      between the governments and the ECB.


      Indeed, efficient European governance means the transfer of the
national sovereignty to the European Union in budgetary matters
and in areas essential to the real economy. This would entail a qua-
litative leap in the process of integration.


      The three pillars of the new architecture are:
• The Euro Plus Pact (approved at the European Summit of 24-25
    March 2011, with immediate effect);
• The Fiscal Stability Pact (approved at the European Summit on
    1st March 2012, with the exception of the United Kingdom and


118
The Future of the Euro


  the Czech Republic, and estimated to come into force, after rati-
  fication by the national parliaments, on 1st January 2013);
• The Macro-economic Governance Pact (approved by the
  European Parliament in September 2011 and ratified by the
  European Council, which is in force already).


   The three Pacts complement one another. Without quality of
public finances there will be no appropriate economic growth (“dis-
trust effect”), but without economic growth it will be impossible to
have organised public accounts (“tax collection weakness effect”),
and with no macro-economic balance growth will be slower (“effect
of inefficiency in the allocation of production factors”).


5.1. The Euro Plus Pact, it is not binding on anyone


   This Pact is based on right diagnosis: the potention of growth in
southern countries and the capacity to create employment (to a gre-
ater or lesser extent) are low owing to the persistence of negative
national factors: non-qualified labour, insufficient technological
innovation in companies, over-regulation of the labour market and
of various services, inefficient bureaucracy, deplorable tax fraud and
corruption. For this reason, structural reforms in the economy and
the institutions are so necessary.




   The governments of the countries of the euro area have under-
taken to implement it; other six countries of the EU have also


                                                                   119
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


       undertaken this commitment (for this reason the term “Plus” has
       been added to the name of the Pact).6 The scope of action that the
       Pact contemplates affects the labour market, the educational sys-
       tem, the environment for research, the tax system and a long etce-
       tera. All this is praiseworthy.


             But the main problem of the Pact is that it gives full freedom to
       the governments to take the measures that they deem appropriate
       and not to take others that would also be necessary from an objec-
       tive point of view. There is no sanction in case of lack of strictness.
       Therefore, this pillar of economic governance of the euro area does
       not offer security.


       5.2. The Fiscal Stability Pact, a test of nine


             Rightly, the inexorable key is the commitment from the govern-
       ments to maintain orderly and balanced public finances in the
       future.


             This is no dogmatic approach (“neoliberal”, as some call it pejo-
       ratively), but it is the consequence of an economic analysis, sup-
       ported by theory and empirical experience. Government deficit
       must be limited, owing to the “Domar condition”, according to
       which, for reasons of assignative efficiency, long-term interest rates

6 European Council, Conclusions 24/25 March 2011, Annex I: The Euro Plus Pact –
Stronger Economic Policy Coordination for Competitiveness, Bruselas, 25/3/11 (EUCO 10/11,
CO EUR 6, CONCL 3).


       120
The Future of the Euro


must be higher than the economic growth rate. With no ceiling for
government deficit sooner or later we reach a point from which the
financial expenditure of the State (for servicing the debt) increases
substantially, which progressively reduces the room for manoeuv-
re of the government to seek its economic and social aims. The
level   of   public   debt   must   be   limited   because   of   the
“Reinhart/Rogoff rule”, derived from econometric studies, which
establish a critical threshold of 90% of GDP, from which the secu-
lar economic growth rate may diminish at least half a percentage
point per year for three reasons: one, because public debt servicing
reduces the margin for productive investment of the State (infras-
tructures); two, because payment of interest to foreign creditors
reduces available national income and, therefore, the capacity of
consumption of households; and three, because the need to re-
finance sovereign debt makes financing of private companies in
capital markets difficult (“expulsion effect”).


   The Ltmus test is characterised by strictness under which the
governments deepen in budgetary consolidation. Despite the fact
that in different countries of the euro area some measures invol-
ving tax adjustment have been taken already, public finances are
not consolidated at all. According to the European Office of
Statistics (Eurostat), government deficit is excessive (more than
3% of GDP) in most of the countries, also in Spain (2011: 8.5% of
GDP). Germany (1%) and four small countries (Estonia, Finland,
Luxembourg and Malta) are the few exceptions. Most of the
government deficits are structural, in other words, not cyclic but


                                                                   121
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


        permanent, and, therefore, destructive for the good functioning
        of the economy. The level of public debt is also too high (higher
        than 60% of GDP) in almost all the countries, including
        Germany (2011: 81.2%) and France (85.8%) and now also Spain
        (68.5%), for the first time since 2011, Spain (68%). Where public
        debt greatly exceeds all acceptable levels according to the
        “Reinhart/Rogoff rule” is in the three countries that have been
        rescued (Greece, Ireland and Portugal) and in Italy. For the latter
        country, however, there is a differentiating factor in its favour,
        most of the public debt is internal and, thus, its servicing may be
        managed directly with its own instruments (by increasing fiscal
        pressure on its citizens).


             As mentioned above, the rules on sustainability of public finan-
        ces as set forth in the Treaty of the European Union and in the SGP
        have not been efficient to impose budgetary discipline. Its applica-
        tion has been highly politicised. The mechanisms of penalisation
        have never been implemented. The new Fiscal Pact has been arran-
        ged in such a manner that it could put the screws, firstly, on the
        euro countries on which the agreement is binding.7 The most
        important advances as regards the SGP, for the moment only on
        paper, are the following three:
       • Firstly, the seriousness of government deficit is explicitly ack-
             nowledged when it is structural. The explicit ceiling established



7 European Council, Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and
Monetary Union, 2/3/12, artículos 3-8. Internet: http//:eur-lex.europa.eu.


       122
The Future of the Euro


    is 0.5% of GDP, maintaining the threshold of 3% for total defi-
    cit. There is thus a large margin for the operation of “automatic
    stabilisers” in the economic cycle and for discretionary govern-
    mental measures if there is recession.
• Secondly, the aim of limiting the level of public debt at 60% of
    GDP through a procedure which, if the debt exceeds this per-
    centage, may activate the supervisory mechanism for “excessive
    government deficit”, even if the deficit is below 3% of GDP. The
    country in question shall be forced to reduce it at an average
    rate of one twentieth per year as a benchmark (“1/20 clause”).
• Thirdly, the obligation for each member country to define its
    medium-term budgetary objective (MTO), quantifying an indi-
    cator for public expenditure evolution and making sure that the
    estimated expenditure shall be financed by sustainable income
    (“golden rule” of budgetary balance). If a country does not orga-
    nise its budgets in a balanced manner it will be required by the
    European Commission to submit new budgetary plans.


    If the new rules are important, a mechanism to enforce them is
equally important. The most relevant three new elements are the
following:
•   First, continuous supervision of the policies applied in both
    summits of the euro area has been devised (two per year, at
    least, called and chaired by the President of the EU, currently
    Herman Van Rompuy).
•   Second, there is a change in the decision process on financial
    sanctions (of up to 0.2% of GDP) in case of breach and non-ful-


                                                                   123
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


      filment of the specific recommendations to remedy the situa-
      tion in the sense that a proposal of the European Commission is
      considered approved if the Council of the Heads of State and
      Government of the euro area does not vote against it with a qua-
      lified majority (until now such a majority was required for the
      European Council to approve the sanction). Therefore, there will
      be less room for political maneuvre to prevent the fine (as it was
      normal in the past after the Schröder/Chirac precedent mentio-
      ned above). The sanctions are not totally automatic as one
      would like them to be, but they are moving in that direction.
      Furthermore, they have a broader scope than before, because the
      manipulation of fiscal statistics shall also be punished.
•     Third, the obligation for each member country to transpose the
      fiscal stability rule into its national legislation is established and,
      therefore, be explicitly responsible for its fulfilment. The Court
      of Justice of the EU shall ensure its fulfilment.


      For the States to decide the medium-term budgetary stability
(equivalent to the economic cycle), the most credible formula is to
constitutionally estabish a ceiling for structural government deficit.
Germany has already done it (0.35% of GDP for the central govern-
ment, from 2016, and cero deficit for the federal states, from 2020).
Spain is moving in that direction after the reform of article 135 of
the Constitution at the end of the previous term of office and the
recent approval of the Budgetary Stability Law which will require
from 2020 cero structural deficit to the public authorities (which
could be up to 0.4% of GDP in exceptional circumstances). Other


124
The Future of the Euro


countries are moving in that direction. The advantage of a consti-
tutional rule as regards de margin of debt of the government is that,
if a country incurs deficit and constitutional breach, it will need bet-
ter arguments for its society than if it only needs to be explained
before the Community authorities and take there the relevant war-
nings; Brussels is “far” and it is “under suspicion” of meddling in
national affairs.


   The Fiscal Pact will only work if the euro area countries are
willing to do without most of its sovereignty in budgetary matters,
which will be transferred to Community institutions. Obviously,
this affects the main prerogative of national parliaments, which is
to shape the budgets of the State and decide how to finance expen-
diture. This will meet great opposition, in all the countries. It is not
a trivial matter that the Fiscal Pact must be institutionalised
through an inter-governmental agreement, that is to say, a level
lower than the Treaty of the EU, which reform would have requi-
red the unanimous approval of the twenty-seven, which was not
reached. This procedure has opened in the legal field a debate to
decide if the procedure chosen is compatible with Community
Law, specifically in relation to the mechanisms of sanctions for
excessive government deficit as set forth in article 126 of the
Treaty. For European leaders to have lowered the quorum required
for parliamentary approval of the inter-governmental agreement is
not a trivil matter either, to 12 of the 17 States that form part of the
euro area. Could it be that some partners are not reliable? It is true
that it has been decided that the countries that do not ratify the


                                                                     125
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


Pact and transpose to their national legislation the ceiling of
government deficit will be excluded from possible financial bai-
lout. However, is this credible, especially if the stability of the euro
area is at risk? This being so, it would be better not to be too hope-
ful about this Fiscal Pact.


5.3. The Macro-economic Governance Pact, with vague
parameters


      The same caution is advisable with regards to the solemnly
proclaimed Six Pack (so called because its content has been draf-
ted through a Community directive and five regulations).
Nodoby doubts that, for the feasibility of the euro area, macro-
economic stability is a necessary condition (although not enough
if the requirements for an optimal monetary area are not fulfi-
lled). Furthermore, it is true that macro-economic stability goes
beyond budgetary balance, as it has been proven with the recent
experience of different countries (inflationary pressure, property
bubble, excessive private sector debt, competitive weakness of
companies, current account imbalance, etc.). However, the
European Commission, the European Parliament and the
European Council seem to have faith in the capacity of economic
policy to handle crucial factors in the real economy. This is
highly questionable.


      An alert mechanism scoreboard was created for the appearance
of internal and external imbalances in the countries, which will be


126
The Future of the Euro


managed by the European Commission based on ten parameters,
as follows: 8
• Internal imbalance parameters: evolution of unit labour cost,
   unemployment rate, private sector indebtedness, credit to the
   private sector, evolution of property prices and government
   indebtedness.
• External imbalance parameters: surplus and deficit of current
   account balance, net international investment position, change of
   export market shares and change of the real effective exchange
   rates of the euro.


   For these parameters, critical thresholds have been established,
from which the alarm would be triggered, and this would start a
procedure to analyse the causes in order to decide from Europe if
corrective measures need to be taken or not. For instance, for unit
labour costs the threshold is an increase of 9% in three years, for
unemployment rates it is 10% of the workforce as a three-year ave-
rage or for current account balance the threshold established is 3
year backward moving average of the current account balance as a
per cent of GDP, with a threshold of +6% of GDP (surplus) and -4%
of GDP (deficit). If there is excessive imbalance, the European
Commission will make the relevant recommendations for the
government of the country in question to remedy the imbalance; in
case of non-fulfilment, a fine may be imposed (up to 0.1% of GDP).



8 European Commission, EU Economic governance “Six Pack“ enters into force,
MEMO/11/898, 12/12/2011.


                                                                  127
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance


      The thresholds set are not a consequence of a detailed economic
and empirical analysis that may indicate for sure when an imba-
lance is excessive for a country and negatively affects the euro area
as a whole. The numerical values rather represent the perception of
politicians of the recent events; therefore, they are, unavoidably,
arbitrary. But the fundamental question is different: How can a
government act efficiently?


      We must remember that the EU proposes an open market eco-
nomy with free competition (article 119 of the Treaty of the EU). All
euro countries have this concept of economic system, some becau-
se of the Ludwig Erhard tradition (Germany), and others with reser-
vation in favour of the government (France). In a market economy,
the government lacks the instruments to control the variables con-
templated in this Macro-economic Governance Pact. Therefore, the
governments should activate a series of interventionist measures,
with no guarantee of their efficiency and with a high risk of distor-
ting efficiency in the allocation of production factors. In a market
economy, responsibilities are distributed in a different way: for level
of employment, social partners (unions and employers); for export
development, private companies (technology); or for granting
loans, commercial banks (based on the appropriate risk estimate).
The current account balance, among other things, represents the
saving trend rooted in society and objective conditions for fixed
capital investment (as explained by the “macro-economic equa-
tion” and the “Böhm-Bawerk theorem”). Unions will not accept
government interference in the negotiation of collective agree-


128
The Future of the Euro


ments and companies will not stop being creative or innovative in
organisational management and product development for which
elasticity-income of international demand is higher than the unit,
and banks will not neglect their classical business, which is to pro-
vide credit to companies and households.


   This economic governance project has no clear future. In the
best-case scenario, the new Summits of the euro area would have
matters to discuss. The countries in which the economy works well
could be taken as a benchmark for the others to rectify their struc-
tural deficiencies and improve their productive and competitive-
ness levels. In the worst-case scenario, the euro area would be expo-
sed to continuous political conflicts, which would not promote
economic growth with high employment. It is so easy, and espe-
cially politically profitable in countries with domestic problems, to
look for the villain abroad, maybe Germany?


Conclusion

   The sovereign debt crisis has had a healthy effect in convincing
politicians that by providing liquidity to governments and banks
the stability of the euro area will not be attained in the medium
and long term. The quality of the economic policy must improve
in the countries, there must be impeccable follow-up by indepen-
dent institutions to weigh up the economic and fiscal situation and
it must be guaranteed that national accounts and other relevant
statistics are arranged under utmost scientific accuracy at all times.


                                                                   129
The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance




      If in all the euro countries the governments understand that
sound public finances and application of structural reforms is their
responsibility and if they act seriously according to them, no State
will have to rescue another State because of over-indebtedness and
waste, and the ECB may stop indirectly financing States and focus
more on its task, ensuring stability in price levels in the euro area.
The ESM fund would be reserved to emergency situations caused by
external factors beyond the government’s control. The Fiscal Pact
would have fulfilled its mission and the Euro Plus Pact would be
filled with efficient contents. We would not need to resort to mar-
ket interventionism as entailed with the Six Pack.


      If, on the contrary, there is no determination in the member
countries, any attempt of European economic governance would
result more from proactive intentions than harsh reality. The euro
area would have an uncertain future. The alternative of a European
Political Union, in which all necessary economic policies could be
undertaken from a Community Executive under the control of the
European Parliament, with all democratic rights, cannot be seen on
the horizon.




130
/GONZALO GARCÍA ANDRÉS * /




    The turbulent adolescence of the euro
                   and its path to maturity




1. Introduction; 2. Anatomy of the crisis: Greece, the contagion and the per-
verse dynamics of debt; 2.1. Sovereign credit risk within the euro: from zero
to infinity; 2.2. A fiscal problem, not the fiscal problem; 2.3. Contagion: the
fragmentation of the single monetary policy; 2.4 A particular manifestation
of the global financial crisis; 3. The Eurosystem at a crossroads; 3.1. Intra-
system balances as an expression of the fragmentation of monetary policy;
3.2. Quantitative easing for banks only; 4. The definitive solution must
begin in 2012; 5. Conclusion; Bibliography



* Member of the Technical Body of the Spanish Civil Services (Técnico Comercial
Economista del Estado) and Graduate of Economics at Universidad Autónoma de
Madrid. He has spent a large part of his professional career in the current General Office
of Treasury and Financial Policy in the Ministry of the Economy and Competitiveness
of Spain. He held the office of Deputy Director of Financial and Strategic Analysis, res-
ponsible for financial stability and crisis management issues, international financial
policy (EU, G20) and adviser to the Social Security Reserve Fund. In September 2009 he
was appointed Deputy Director of Funding and Debt Management, where within a few
months he was involved in the adaptation of the Treasury funding programme to the
instability generated by the Greek fiscal crisis and its contagion throughout the rest of
the euro region. From September 2010 to January 2012 he has held the office of Director
General for International Finance, which has enabled him to form part of the manage-
ment boards of the European Investment Bank and of CESCE. He has likewise been
Associate Professor in Economic Theory at Universidad Rey Juan Carlos and has publis-
hed several articles on regulatory, financial and monetary matters in Spanish journals.


                                                                              131
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


       1. Introduction

             The Monetary Union is a political construction, the boldest and
       most significant step forward by the European project since the
       Treaty of Rome. Its conception also had an economic basis, that of
       completing the consolidation of the economic integration process
       which was begun in 1985. However, its implementation was a great
       adventure. The countries that use the euro are far from constituting
       an optimal monetary zone. In addition to the evident initial diffe-
       rences in the economic and institutional structure of the countries
       and in their histories of stability, the euro was forced to make room
       for disparate economic philosophies.


             The European leaders elected to create a very light institutional
       structure, with an independent federal monetary authority, an
       apparently severe budgetary discipline (the Stability and Growth
       Pact or SGP) and the rule of no mutual support (in order to rein-
       force the individual fiscal stability of each State).


             During its first ten years the euro appeared to be working relati-
       vely well. Average real growth exceeded 2% and both the level and
       the volatility of inflation improved in comparison to the previous


He is currently an adviser in the General Deputy Office of Financial and Economic
Matters of the European Union and the Eurozone which is part of the General Office of
the Treasury and Financial Policy. The opinions expressed in this article pertain to the
author and under no circumstance may be attributed to the Ministry of the Economy
and Competitiveness.



       132
The Future of the Euro


decade, although the differences in the macro-economic and finan-
cial behaviour of the members were quite considerable. Although
the Stability and Growth Pact was reformed mid-decade, no signi-
ficant alterations were made to the institutional framework and the
number of members gradually grew. The onset of the financial cri-
sis in 2007 initially underlined this perception of the euro as somet-
hing imperfect but solid.


   However, a little after its 11th anniversary, three interconnected
calamities fell upon the euro. Firstly, one of its members plumme-
ted towards insolvency in just three months. Secondly, the politi-
cal pact on which the single currency was built began to shake
when financial assistance within the area became inevitable. And
thirdly, the unity in regard to monetary policy fell apart with the
dislocation of the public debt markets.


   Two years later, and despite having taken decisive steps in natio-
nal policies and in institutional framework reform, the crisis of the
euro has deteriorated to the point of calling its survival into ques-
tion; and a definitive solution is yet to be glimpsed. With the bene-
fit of hindsight, it is worth attempting to interpret was has happe-
ned, taking into account the extreme complexity both of the initial
situations (with accumulated imbalances and structural deficien-
cies in several countries), as well as the outbreak, contagion and
escalation of the crisis. And to do so moreover against the broader
backdrop of the global financial crisis, which has influenced eco-
nomic and financial evolution for five years, in order to identify


                                                                   133
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


which specific aspects of the euro have played a vital role. All the
above with the aim of helping come up with solutions, bringing
together the most urgent ones and those of a longer term basis.




2. Anatomy of the crisis: Greece, contagion and the perverse
dynamics of debt

2.1. Sovereign credit risk within the euro: from zero to infinity


      The natural starting point of the analysis of the crisis is the
behaviour of sovereign debt markets. The creation of the euro gave
way to a number of markets for debt securities issued by sovereign
states but denominated in the same currency. This is an atypical
configuration with few precedents, given that sovereign debt secu-
rities are usually associated with the bond that exists between the
issuer and monetary sovereignty.


      Until 2007 the markets considered that the very creation of the
Monetary Union had reduced sovereign credit risk to a very small
level. For example, the spread between the ten year Greek bond
and the ten year German bund fell within a range between 10 and
30 basis points between 2002 and 2007. In spite of GDP growing
at relatively high rates, the level and performance of the fiscal and
current account imbalances in Greece had justified a much higher
risk premium.




134
The Future of the Euro


   With the outbreak of the global financial crisis, credit risk spre-
ads among Eurozone countries widened. But this trend – common
to all of the world financial markets –, was mainly due to risk aver-
sion and an increase in the demand of assets deemed to be safer
(Barrios et al, 2009). The spreads thus adopted a trend towards
moderation throughout 2009, all amid a context of low absolute
financing costs for the sovereign issuers.


   Towards November 2009, an alteration in the behaviour of sove-
reign debt markets took place, which in hindsight can be conside-
red as a structural change. The almost perfect convergence since
the beginning of the Monetary Union1 therefore gave way to a
cumulative bifurcation, reflecting the binary behaviour of the mar-
kets. This is a dynamic system with two main features:


• Systematic inefficiency. Bond market prices do not reflect the
   fundamental information on credit risk determining factors.
   Until 2009, the spreads had been smaller than would be justified
   by the main variables (debt stock, deficit, international invest-
   ment position, real exchange rate); since autumn 2009, the spre-
   ads have been systematically higher than would be justified by
   the performance of the fundamental variables. This gap betwe-
   en market prices and economic fundamentals has been noted in
   several empirical studies (Aizenman, Hutchison & Jinjarak
   (2011), De Grauwe & Ji (2012)).

1 The average 10 year debt spread in Eurozone countries against Germany was of only
18 basis points between 1999 and mid-2007.


                                                                        135
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


• Tendency towards instability. The euro sovereign debt markets
      have shown themselves to be incapable of adjusting their credit
      risk assessments in a stable manner. Their capacity for discrimi-
      nation has been non-existent for years, with a high demand for
      bonds from countries exposed to vulnerability, which were dee-
      med to be almost perfect replacements for the German bund.
      And in these last two years, the trend has been explosive. In
      micro-economic terms, instability means that given an excess
      supply of bonds, a drop in price does not bring it back to balan-
      ce. But furthermore, we must point out that the explosive natu-
      re of the sovereign debt markets since the beginning of 2010 has
      become more noticeable than that reflected in market prices.
      ECB intervention has lessened the trend towards increases
      which are sharp and not related with new fundamental infor-
      mation on the likelihood of default by various countries in the
      region.


      On the basis of this general outlook of the dynamics of debt
markets, a distinction must be made between the Greek market
and the rest.


2.2 A fiscal problem, not the fiscal problem


      The Greek situation is special. In October 2009, the new Greek
government announced that the public deficit for the year would
be somewhat over double that which had been forecast (12.7% of
GDP versus the expected 6%). This setback of Greek public debt


136
The Future of the Euro


was thus triggered by a fundamental fiscal surprise of considerable
dimensions.


   Greece has systematically managed its public finances poorly
since joining the euro.2 It has taken advantage of the financial
benefits of belonging to the euro to increase expenditure, while
maintaining a pro-cyclical fiscal orientation during a clearly expan-
sive phase. The Hellenic country has thus made real one of the
worst fears of the founders of the euro in regard to the risk of free-
rider fiscal behaviours. The bad news is that neither the market dis-
cipline under the non-mutual guarantee clause nor the Stability
and Growth Pact have managed to correct this situation, which has
worsened further due to continuous problems regarding reliability
of public accounts.


   The Greek public debt market has also followed a pattern of
inefficiency and instability. Gibson, Hall & Tavlas (2011) have
identified a systematic bias between the credit risk spread adjusted
to the main determining variables and the market spread.
Nevertheless, the collapse of the market is not difficult to explain.
The depth of the fiscal crisis and its structural nature, added to the
uncertainty and lack of confidence generated by the handling of
accounts, spread the perception among investors of inevitable
insolvency with a certain risk of loss of principal.




2 In fact, its public deficit has never been below 3% since it joined the monetary union.


                                                                             137
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


      What is hard to explain is why the Greek crisis spread to the rest
of the public debt markets in the area. Firstly, the weight of Greece
in the GDP of the Eurozone (around 2.3%) does not justify that its
fiscal crisis should become a systemic problem. Secondly, no other
Eurozone member country is anywhere near this level of systema-
tic poor management of public funds and continuous breach of
the rules of the Monetary Union.


      There are two factors in the Greek collapse during the first
semester of 2010 which became important for the operation of the
rest of the Monetary Union. To begin with, the fragility of the
domestic debt markets within the Eurozone became clear.
Secondly, the political tension generated by the intra-zone finan-
cial aid revealed a considerable institutional weakness. Discussions
prior to the approval of the loan to Greece brought to light that the
politics of the countries in the zone were about to take on a hard
line of fiscal adjustments and onerous conditions in the financial
aid defended by creditor countries, in stark contrast with the posi-
tion of countries which were beginning to feel the effect of the tur-
bulence in Greece as of January.


      Even so, it seems impossible to explain how the Greek crisis
became a euro crisis in light of only these two factors. Particularly,
following the creation in May 2010 in response to the explosive
market situation, of the European Financial Stability Facility and
the start of the intervention by the Eurosystem via the Securities
Market Programme.


138
The Future of the Euro


2.3 Contagion: the fragmentation of the single monetary policy


    The strategy we have chosen to explain the spread from Greece
throughout all of the Monetary Union is a two-phased approach.
The first phase attempts to define the morphology of the crisis,
which may help, at a second phase, to get to the bottom of its
nature.


    These are the main morphological characteristics of the crisis:
•   Systemic for the entire Eurozone. The crisis is often discussed
    as if it only affects part of the Monetary Union; along the same
    lines, it is argued that this is not a crisis of the euro, on the
    grounds of exchange rate levels or price stability. In fact, since
    the generalised dislocation of the debt markets was sparked off
    towards the end of April 2010, the crisis has indeed become a
    euro crisis. It affects all member countries, albeit in opposite
    way. There has been a flow of capital from the more indebted
    countries to the creditor countries, which has been reflected in
    the yields of public debt and other securities. Thus, the impact
    of the fiscal irresponsibility of one of the members has not
    resulted in a generalised increase in interest rates as was expec-
    ted (Dombret (2012)). It has had an asymmetric impact, punis-
    hing countries with greater financial vulnerability and benefi-
    ting the stronger ones.


• Specific to the Eurozone. The financial bifurcation movement
    has been limited to the member states, despite having some


                                                                   139
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


                effect on the rest of the world.3 There is no sovereign debt glo-
                bal crisis; on the contrary, public debt yields in the main deve-
                loped countries have reached historic minimal levels. Thus, the
                main non Euro indebted countries (United Kingdom, United
                Sates) have seen an increase in the demand of sovereign debt as
                a result of the euro crisis. For instance, at the start of 2010, ten
                year British debt securities traded at levels similar to the Spanish
                ones. The worsening of the crisis in the Eurozone has meant that
                the British debt is just a few basis points away from the German
                debt. The negative contagion has therefore only affected euro
                members, whereas the positive contagion of public debt has
                managed to reach other markets.


          • Its dynamics are financial and autonomous, not defined by
                fundamental economic variables. This statement calls for an
                explanation because… doesn’t Ireland have a serious solvency
                problem in its banking system? Isn’t Portugal undergoing a
                current unsustainable imbalance? Doesn’t Spain have a high
                public deficit and an excess of private debt? How will Italy
                manage to sustain a public debt stock of 120% of the GDP and
                a GDP growth trend below 1%? … and we could move on to
                Belgium and then to France. All the euro countries which have
                suffered the restriction of their external financing terms in the


3 The Euro crisis has become the main factor threatening the recovery of the world eco-
nomy and the consolidation of the progress made in restoring financial stability after
the global crisis. However, at this point only direct spreading via debt markets is dis-
cussed.



          140
The Future of the Euro


  last two years are facing serious problems. But the existence of
  such problems does not make them causes for the dislocation of
  the debt markets and the consequences thereof. In fact, in all
  cases we are dealing with problems with which the markets have
  been well acquainted for years. There are two ways of illustrating
  the secondary role played by economic fundamentals in the cri-
  sis. One is to compare euro countries affected with other non-
  euro countries with similar fundamentals. Aizenman et al (2011)
  have done this by matching Spain with South Africa and con-
  cluding that the greater risk spread in Spain cannot be explained
  by the worse levels in the variables which have determined cre-
  dit quality ratings. The other is to verify whether an improve-
  ment in the fundamentals (including economic policy measures
  required to achieve this) has had a positive impact on the finan-
  cing terms. For example, affected countries have considerably
  reduced their primary deficits adjusted to the cycle, although
  this has not helped to improve the perception of the fiscal situa-
  tion. This does not mean that the fundamentals are not impor-
  tant when determining the vulnerability of a country, or that
  the economic policies adopted in response to the crisis have not
  proven vital in halting or slowing down the impact of the crisis.
  But it is important to stress that the crisis is essentially not a pro-
  blem of fundamental economic variables.


• It has become apparent through the inversion of the capital
  flow pattern within the euro. For years, the economies with
  lower rates of savings (such as Greece or Portugal) or higher


                                                                      141
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


             investment rates (such as Spain) comfortably financed their
             large deficits via private flows of capital from countries with hig-
             her rates of savings and lower investment rates. As of spring
             2010, many of these countries have been forced to face an inte-
             rruption, and in some cases a sudden inversion, of external
             funds, as shown by the performances of their financial accounts
             (see Graph 1 for Spain). Part of that capital has been diverted to
             creditor countries. From this perspective, the crisis can be
             understood as a series of sudden stops (with their pertaining
             sudden goes) in capital flows within the Monetary Union. The
             most acute episodes of the crisis have thus coincided with an
             intensification of the external financial restriction. In short, it is
             about a crisis in the balance of payments within the particular
             framework of the Monetary Union, whose adjustment variable
             is not the amount of reserves but the net funding of the
             Eurosystem.


              By combining these characteristics, the crisis can be defined as
        a cumulative coordination failure, with a positive feedback.4 The
        key mechanism underlying this failure is the effect that the dislo-

4 The concept of coordination failure arises as part of an alternative interpretation of
Keynes’ analysis to that of the Neoclassical Synthesis, which considers there is a deeper
explanation for unemployment and instability problems than salary rigidity. In a first
formulation, it can be associated with the Macroeconomics of imbalance. Subsequently,
within the framework of New Keynesian Economics, this is analysed with different
models which have strategic interdependence and multiple balances in common
(Cooper and John, 1991). In the context of the financial crisis, the coordination failu-
res have played a core role, linked to uncertainty and the effect thereof on expectations.



       142
The Future of the Euro


   Graph 1
   Net Loan and Financial Account balance of Spain




   Source: Bank of Spain



cation of the operation of the public debt market has over the
mechanism of monetary transmission and, in the last resort, on
the financing conditions of the non-financial private sector.


  Indeed, the public debt markets, in addition to procuring state
funding, play a central role in the operation of the monetary and
financial systems. The yield curve of public debt, considered to be
the risk-free asset, serves as the main price reference for the rest of
the credit and securities markets, acting as a floor for financing
costs for all other agents. On the other hand, the implementation
of monetary policy traditionally uses government securities as asset
guarantees. And financial institutions, and credit institutions,
UCITs and pension funds in particular, often keep a considerable
amount of sovereign bonds in their portfolios.


                                                                    143
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


      The dislocation of the public debt markets has had a devastating
effect on the affected economies. The increase in volatility (see
Graph 2 for the Spanish market) and the upturn in the credit risk
spread without any underlying new fundamental information
have restricted funding for the non-financial sector in various
ways. Directly, insofar as market-funded companies must pay more
for issues. And indirectly, and more importantly given the finan-
cial structure of the euro economies, it operates via the banking
system. Bank access to market funding is restricted in terms of
volume and prices, whilst the value of both their public debt hol-
dings and other market shares continues to fall. The result is a res-
triction in funding available to businesses and households.



      Graph 2
      Historical volatility of Spanish debt




      Source: Bloomberg




144
The Future of the Euro


   This situation gives rise a contracting spiral which generates a
perverse dynamics in the sustainability of public debt. The first reac-
tion from countries suffering from a financial restriction mainly of
their debt markets is the acceleration of fiscal adjustment which, in
principle, appears to be a logical and reasonable response. The pro-
blem is that a combination of a strong contractive fiscal approach
and financial restriction weakens the nominal GDP. This leads to
an increase in the nominal fiscal adjustment required to achieve a
deficit target in relation to the GDP. Unemployment rises, disposa-
ble income falls and the creditworthiness of businesses and house-
holds deteriorates. The result is a deterioration of the Debt/GDP
ratio, with a feedback effect.


In summary, the dislocation of public debt markets generated an
endogenous monetary restriction, equal to a drastic toughening up
of monetary policy in the most affected countries. The transmis-
sion mechanism of the policy established by the ECB no longer
works in a fairly uniform manner, upset by the intensity of the pri-
vate funding flows and the effect thereof on expectations. The
result is the breakdown of the single monetary policy.


2.4. A particular manifestation of the global financial crisis


   The symptoms of this disease afflicting the Monetary Union
seem very familiar by now: debt markets which no longer work nor-
mally, spreads with an explosive tendency, asset liquidation at dis-
counted prices (fire sales), banks in the grip of liability restrictions


                                                                     145
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


       and falling asset values, gaps between the financial sector and the
       real economy. In fact the mechanism is identical to that which led
       to the subprime mortgage debacle in the systemic crisis of develo-
       ped economies in 2007-2009. The main difference is that both the
       source and the means of contagion were in that case the private
       debt markets, whereas in the Eurozone the dislocation has mainly
       taken place in public debt markets. But the analogy is valid in
       analytical terms and can prove quite useful when considering the
       regulatory implications which will result from the crisis resolution.


             The effect on monetary policy was similar, although at that time
       the public debt markets carried on as normal and could continue to
       be used to tackle the endogenous restriction in the financing con-
       ditions of the private sector with firm and innovative measures.


             Several studies on the nature of the global financial crisis have
       highlighted the importance of the increase in uncertainty when
       seeking to understand and resolve it. Caballero (2010) considers
       that the financial crisis, which appears similar to a heart attack, is
       the product of a combination of uncertainty as defined by Knight
       and the complexity of the structure of the financial system. These
       two factors amplify the initial shock effect, with forced sales of
       assets and liquidity strangulations which drive a wedge between
       the financial sector and the real economy, preventing the proper
       operation of the economy and the markets.5 The solution requi-

5 This then leads to large scale coordination failure, in the sense mentioned at the end
of the previous note.


       146
The Future of the Euro


res the State to become an insurer of last resort, providing insurance
against uncertainty to persuade the agents that the less likely nega-
tive scenarios will not take place. This enables the coil to snap, thus
coordinating agents at higher comfort levels.


  This financial crisis model can be applied to the Eurozone. The
Greek fiscal surprise and its rapid decline towards insolvency
would be the initial shock, generating confusion among agents and
leading them to reconsider their perception of sovereign risk wit-
hin the euro. The complexity of the financial interrelations within
the area, along with the emergence of political differences, disse-
minates lack of confidence to all other markets. And the rapid dis-
location of the debt markets increases uncertainty, hits the banks
in affected countries and ends up by paralyzing the workings of
their financial system and depressing the real economy. The inten-
sity of self-fulfilling prophecies in the markets increases the uncer-
tainty regarding the outlooks for the countries and for the
Monetary Union as a whole. Investors fear the possibility that the
market dynamics should cause solvent countries to lose access to
new funding.


  Definitive uncertainty appears when the disintegration of the
Monetary Union, which seemed like a bad joke even at the start of
2010, becomes a scenario deemed likely by main investors. In fact,
the persistence of such huge spreads between the public debt of
member countries is an unequivocal indicator that the market is
taking the possibility of disintegration very seriously. Investors


                                                                    147
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


accept negative real returns in the short term and no return in the
medium and long term of the German public debt because they
believe that, given a break-up scenario, these assets are the ones
which will guarantee the security and continuity of the euro.


      It is a fact that certain partial insurance mechanisms to deal
with the effects of the crisis have been implemented in the
Eurozone. On the one hand, the Eurosystem has performed the
role of lender of last resort for the banking system with force, adap-
ting its role to perceived needs. On the other hand, the creation of
a system of financial aid as a component of the institutional fra-
mework of the Monetary Union also constitutes a significant
collective insurance item. But as we pointed out in the introduc-
tion, for the time being these instruments, along with the steps
taken at a national level, have not managed to prevent crisis relap-
ses. The relapse of summer 2011 was particularly serious, as it
underlined its systemic nature and struck both Italy and Spain,
with an ensuing financial strangulation that has led to a new reces-
sion in the region.




3. The Eurosystem at a crossroads

      The ECB and the 17 National Central Banks (NCB) comprise the
most powerful institution in the Monetary Union. Its legal inde-
pendence is greater than that of other central banks in developed
countries and, like them, it has the essential power of unlimited cre-


148
The Future of the Euro


ation of money. In contrast with the rest of Monetary Union bodies,
the Eurosystem is capable of making decisions and of expediently
executing them. Even so, it is not a central bank like all the others.
During its first decade of life, the difficulty entailed in setting a sin-
gle monetary policy to be applied to a group of economies with dif-
ferent fiscal policies and economic and financial cycles became
patently clear. But since the Greek crisis, the task has become extra-
ordinarily complicated: on the one hand, due to mix of the fiscal
origin of the problem and the financial nature of the contagion;
and on the other, as a result of the tension which the solutions con-
sidered has produced between the Bundesbank philosophy and that
of the more pragmatic (and closer to Federal Reserve and Bank of
England standards) monetary policy of the all the others.


   The Eurosystem has been in the eye of the storm for the last two
years and its performance has been the target of criticism from all
angles: there are those who resent it not having acted in a suffi-
ciently forceful way and there are others who believe that the SMP
and the Long-Term Funding Operations are causing it to deviate
from its mandate and endanger price stability.


   With our sights set on the search for a definitive solution to the
crisis, let us attempt to better understand the implications of what
has happened for the single monetary policy and the response
given by the Eurosystem.




                                                                       149
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


3.1. Intra-system balances as an expression of the fragmentation of
monetary policy


      It would have all been simpler if the impact of the Greek fiscal
debacle would have been a generalised increase in public securities
interest rates in all other euro members. The Eurosystem would
have been able to counteract this effect by adjusting the tone of its
monetary policy. However, the contagion has driven a wedge wit-
hin the euro-debt financial markets, where capital is flowing
towards creditor countries and away from debtor countries.


      The dislocation of the debt markets has endowed the net fun-
ding of the private sector in each country with strongly endoge-
nous dynamics, as can be observed in Graph 3. Despite the expan-
sive tone of the monetary policy of the ECB, in Ireland, Portugal,
Greece and Spain, businesses and households have had to face a
drop in the supply of funds, which in recent months has also affec-
ted Italy. In countries such as Finland, the net capital inflow has
magnified the expansive tone of the monetary policy.


      The Eurosystem has thus had to face the most difficult problem
since its foundation, in that it directly questions the unity of the
monetary policy within the area.


      The alteration in the pattern of financial flows within the
region has substantially modified the geographical distribution of
balances within the Eurosystem. As we have already mentioned,


150
The Future of the Euro


within a monetary union a deficit in the domestic balance of pay-
ments is best funded with a greater appeal made by the banking
system of the country to the Eurosystem. If we take a close look at
the evolution of the financial account balance of Spain, excluding
the Bank of Spain and the Net Eurosystem Loan granted to the
Spanish banking system (Graph 1), we can conclude that deficits
in the balance of payments have been offset by an increase in
appeals to funding via monetary policy operations.


  The result of this is that the counterparts of the monetary base
(which can be calculated from the Eurosystem consolidated balan-
ce sheet) are now more concentrated in those countries which




   Graph 3                                            Interannual Growth rate
   Bank Funding of the non-financial private sector   in Feb 2012




   Source: Bank of Spain


                                                                           151
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


       have experienced the dislocation of their debt markets and the res-
       triction of private sector funding.


             The accounting reflection of these financial dynamics can be
       found in the sharp increase of the so-called intra-system balances.
       The monetary policy decided by the Eurosystem is applied in a
       decentralised fashion, in that it is carried out via national central
       banks. The net balance of the operations of a given country with all
       other countries in the area generates a book entry shown as the
       balance variation between each national central bank (NCB) and
       the ECB. These intra-system balances, required to ensure the iden-
       tity between assets and liabilities in the NCBs and an appropriate
       distribution of seigniorage, disappear when the balances are aggre-
       gated in the consolidated balance sheet of the Eurosystem, as the
       sum of positive balances is equal to the sum of the negative ones.


             The component of these intra-system balances which explains its
       sharp increase during the crisis is the one that relates to the varia-
       tions in the net balance of outstanding operations settled via TAR-
       GET2, whose counterpart entity is the ECB.6 These operations can
       be either private inter-bank transactions or monetary policy opera-

6 The other basic component of intra-system balances is that related with the issue of
euro banknotes. Both the ECB and the NCBs issue euro banknotes in accordance with
a key (8% allocated to ECB and an adjusted allocation by the NCBs). Then the NCBs
release them based on demand. The difference between the allocated issue of bankno-
tes and the release thereof into real circulation generates an intra-system balance,
which is required for a fair distribution of seniority associated with banknote issue.
Germany has the highest negative balance under this heading.


       152
The Future of the Euro


tions between a NCB and a private counterparty. To a large extent,
the sign and amount of the balance depend on the relationship bet-
ween the public or private source of the money of commercial
banks in the central bank. When commercial banks increase their
deposits in the central bank as a result of an increase in private fun-
ding received (deposits, loans or security issues), they tend to redu-
ce their appeal to central bank funding (as we assume that they seek
to limit their reserve surplus). The counterpart of this increase in
liabilities and decrease in assets as a result of the net loan is a posi-
tive balance held by the central bank with the Eurosystem, accruing
at the reference interest rate. On the contrary, a drop in private fun-
ding makes the banks increase their appeal to the central bank. In
this case, the counterpart of the increase in assets is a negative
balance in the liabilities with the Eurosystem.


   Germany, which had a very moderate positive balance before
the outbreak of the global financial crisis, has gone on to have over
half a billion euros of positive balance by the end of February 2012
(see Graph 4). The German Banks have reduced their appeals to
the Eurosystem, as they receive funding at very favourable terms
from the market and have furthermore reduced their asset posi-
tions in other euro member countries.


   On the contrary, Greece, Ireland, Portugal and, more recently,
Spain and Italy, have experienced an increase in their negative
balances to very high levels, due to their banks having had to off-
set the loss of private funding.


                                                                      153
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity



           Graph 4
           TARGET2 Balanace




             Source: Whitaker, Central Bank of Ireland, Bank of Spain, Bank of Greece, Bank of
             Portugal, Deutsche Bundesbank


             The growing trend of intra-system balances was interpreted by
       Sinn (2010) as a stealth bailout by Germany of countries with nega-
       tive balances, going as far as proposing correction measures there-
       of. Although it found some support among German academic
       media (see Declaration of Bobenberg, 2011), Sinn’s interpretation
       was subsequently refuted in several articles which have attempted
       to shed light on the nature and significance of intra-system balan-
       ces (Bindseil & König (2011), Jobst (2011), Borhorst & Mody
       (2012)). The debate saw a later resurgence, to a large extent due to
       the concern expressed by the Chairman of the Bundesbank in a let-
       ter addressed to the Chairman of the ECB.7 Sinn (2012) suggests



7 Shortly after this letter was made public, the Chairman of the Bundesbank published
an article in the press which explained the position of his institution in this debate.


       154
The Future of the Euro


the establishment of a system for annual settlement of intra-system
balances with liquid assets with guarantees from each country (on
real estate assets or on future tax income). In his opinion, it would
be a system similar to that which exists in the United States within
the Federal Reserve System.


   In order to adequately interpret the evolution of intra-system
balances it is worth remembering the following points:
• Balances are the result of the normal execution of monetary
  policy. These are therefore flows between the Eurosystem and
  the banking systems (in no case bilateral between central
  banks), of a monetary nature (these are not real flows of cash or
  fiscal transfers) and resulting from the use that the Eurosystem
  counterparts make of monetary policy operations.
• Under present conditions, the greater appeal to the Eurosystem
  Net Loan by the banking system of a country does not reduce
  the funding available to the banking system of another country.
• The risk of loss assumed by the NCB on the assets of the
  Eurosystem balance is in line with its allocation of the ECB capi-
  tal and does not depend on the size of its intra-system balance.
• Proposals to limit the maximum volume of these balances are
  equal to calling into question an essential principle of the opera-
  tion of the Monetary Union, and the adoption thereof would pro-
  bably lead to the disintegration of the area. It is not appropriate to
  use the example of the United States, as the Federal Reserve System
  operates within a fully integrated banking and capital market.




                                                                     155
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


             In summary, the accumulation of intra-system balances is the
        normal result of an asymmetrical crisis in the balance of payments
        within the area. As is pointed out by Pisany-Ferry (2012), the evo-
        lution of the intra-system balances is only a symptom of the dise-
        ase afflicting the Monetary Union: the best expression of the frag-
        mentation of the monetary policy.


             As we discussed earlier, access to Eurosystem funding has acted
        as a security valve to prevent a generalised problem of illiquidity
        eventually leading to situations of default. However, to date, this
        insurance mechanism has proven incapable of correcting coordi-
        nation failure. And on many occasions, the appeal of a country’s
        banking system to the Eurosystem has been interpreted by the
        market as a risk factor, so that it has become an additional compo-
        nent of the self-fulfilling prophecy process. The greater the increase in
        funding via monetary policy, the greater the restriction on funding
        from the market. Bear in mind the aberrant nature of this sequen-
        ce and its lack of sense in an environment other than that of the
        Monetary Union. During the shutdown of the wholesale financial
        markets at the end of 2008 and beginning of 2009 nobody thought
        to judge that a greater appeal to the credit of the Fed or of the Bank
        of England was an act of weakness.8




8 Among other reasons because the names of the institutions that most used these faci-
lities were not known, and because the geographical distribution of the use (in the case
of the districts of the Federal Reserve system) was not significant


       156
The Future of the Euro


   During spring of 2011, it seemed that the combination of the
SMP, the maintenance of the full allocation in monetary policy
operations and start of financial aid programmes in the cases dee-
med to be more vulnerable (Ireland in November 2010 and
Portugal in May 2011) allowed the Eurosystem to take on a less lea-
ding role in the crisis resolution.


   The position of the ECB, as explained by Trichet (2011), was
based on the diagnosis that this was not a crisis of the euro, but rat-
her a problem of poor macro-economic management, linked to an
insufficient budgetary discipline and the persistence of real and
financial imbalance. The solution could only come about from a
combination of fiscal adjustment and structural reforms at a natio-
nal level, and the strengthening of the institutional framework of
the Monetary Union. Much emphasis was placed on the impor-
tance of the full activation of the EFSF and the future European
Stability Mechanism (ESM). As for monetary policy, this supported
the principle of separation between the setting of the interest refe-
rence rate and the maintenance of unconventional measures to
deal with the distortions in the financial markets and the trans-
mission mechanisms. As an unequivocal example of application of
this principle, the Governing Council decided to raise interest rates
on two occasions in response to the inflationist risk associated with
the rising price of fuel and raw materials.


   But the deterioration of the crisis since the end of June 2011
once again placed the ECB at a crossroads. The dislocation of the


                                                                    157
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


Italian public debt market, the second largest in the euro region,
triggered a new and virulent bifurcation dynamics which severely
punished the banking system. Although the negative balance of its
international investment position is moderate, Italy underwent a
sudden restriction of external funding which led to the liquidity
crisis of its banking system. The value of traded stocks of the banks
in the region plummeted and the perception of default risk, reflec-
ted in the credit derivative contract premiums, shot up. During
those weeks of August and September, the euro crisis reached its
most dangerous systemic repercussions since its onset.


      The Eurosystem was forced once again to react in order to con-
tain the spiralling instability which threatened to spread the rest of
the world. It reactivated and expanded the SMP, by purchasing
Italian and Spanish public debt for the first time. The bloodbath
was successfully avoided, but throughout the month of October, in
the debates held prior to the European Council and G20 meetings,
the need for the ECB to adopt a firmer and more efficient strategy
to solve the crisis was the main topic. And the Eurosystem finally
took a new step.


3.2. Quantitative easing for banks only


      The central banks of the main developed economies have had to
revolutionise the implementation of monetary policy in order to
respond to the financial crisis. At a first phase, they modified the
conditions of liquidity provision, both in regard to terms and types


158
The Future of the Euro


of counterparties and guarantees, maintaining a relatively stable
balance. When the crisis became systemic in autumn 2008, it beca-
me clear that the cut in the interest reference rate to its minimum
level (zero or close to zero) would not prove enough to halt the spi-
ralling contraction between the financial conditions and the real
economy.


   Henceforward, the monetary policy of the Fed, the Bank of
England and the ECB was implemented mainly through unconven-
tional measures, which was the start of the stage in which we remain
to date. Despite the sudden departure from the practice of the last
two decades, this was not a totally untraveled path. The Bank of
Japan had spent years trying unconventional measures in an attempt
to overcome the persistent deflation generated by the financial crisis
at the end of the eighties. And the Japanese experience, not very suc-
cessful, brought about a debate on how to implement an efficient
monetary policy in a context of a liquidity trap, distortions in the
transmission mechanism and a banking crisis.


   The Fed paid special attention to the problems of Japan and the
conclusion of its analyses served as the basis for the deflation pre-
vention policy of 2002 and 2003. Bernanke & Reinhart (2004) iden-
tify three categories of these measures: i) the use of communication
to influence agent expectations ii) quantitative easing via the incre-
ase in the size of the balance sheet and iii) the alteration of the com-
position of the balance sheet in order to directly affect the prices of
certain financial assets. Each of the aforementioned central banks


                                                                     159
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


has applied the unconventional approach in its own way, but all
have coincided in having significantly expanded the balance sheet.


      Both the Fed and the Bank of England have carried out a three-
fold increase of the weight of their balance sheet in regard to the
GDP (see Graph 5). And both have done so by the mass acquisition
of financial assets, which traditionally made up the main compo-
nent of the assets in their balance sheets. The US monetary autho-
rity began by concentrating its purchases on mortgage bonds,
having subsequently moved on to Treasury bonds. The Bank of
England has mainly purchased significant volumes of short and
medium term public debt securities (around 14% of GDP and 30%
of the amount of securities in circulation). The objective in both
cases has been to have a direct influence on the nominal expendi-
ture in order to reduce the risk of deflation and help the economy
to reabsorb idle resources.


      Although it is too early to carry out a full evaluation, the evi-
dence suggests that the unconventional strategies of the Fed and
the Bank of England have proven successful. Estimates indicate a
significant positive effect on asset prices, both of those assets
which have been directly purchased and those with higher risk and
greater impact on the funding terms of the non-financial private
sector (See Meaning & Zhu (2011)). The evolution of the nominal
demand has also been positive, although in this case it is harder to
estimate the impact of unconventional measures. We must also
highlight the credibility of the strategy and its contribution to the


160
The Future of the Euro


reduction of uncertainty, given that the forceful and voluminous
interventions and the communication thereof have managed to
modify agent expectation and to coordinate these towards balan-
ces equilibria which are at some distance from more catastrophic
scenarios. It has not been a magical solution for all problems, but
they have managed to stabilize the operation of the financial sys-
tem, to lend strength to the recovery of the economy and to crea-
te conditions so that the correction of the structural problems of
public and private indebtedness is carried out at a moderate cost.


   From the start, the Eurosystem elected to concentrate its uncon-
ventional measures on the provision of funding to the banking sys-
tem, in line with the financial structure of the area, particularly in
terms of full allotprent and the performance of unusually long term
operations. The purchase of assets has been more modest in relative
terms and has now become sterilised. In December 2011 this stra-
tegy was reaffirmed, by deciding to enter into two special financing
operations for a three-year term, along with other credit support
measures designed to favour bank lending and the money markets
in the region.


   The demand for liquidity of both operations was very high, with
a very high participation of entities compared to the average num-
ber of previous long term financing operations. The total amount
granted was 1.018 trillion euros. The distribution of liquidity follo-
wed a concentrated geographical pattern reflecting the effect of
funding restrictions on the banking system. The percentages of


                                                                   161
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


      Graph 5
      Balance fo the Central Banks during the crisis
      (in % of the GDP)




      Source: ECB, BoE, FED


Spanish and Italian banks were much higher than their respective
allocations in the ECB, whereas the banks from creditor countries
were granted much lower percentages, and further increased their
resources in the Deposit Facility.


      Following these two operations, the consolidated balance sheet
of the Eurosystem reached 32% of the GDP for the region, excee-
ding the percentages of the Fed and Bank of England. However, the
impact of the unconventional strategy in the balance sheet of the
central banks has been somewhat lower in the ECB that in the other
two, due to the increase in total weight over the GDP, as well as
having only used assets related to monetary policy, which account
for a lesser percentage of the balance sheet in the European case.


162
The Future of the Euro


   The immediate impact of the three year funding operations was
very positive. The coverage for a three year period of the liquidity
requirements of the banks considerably reduced the uncertainty
which had frozen the workings of the banking system. The percep-
tion of bank credit risk improved with significant drops in the pre-
miums of credit derivatives and increases in the value of capital.
The money markets and bank debt markets underwent a revitalisa-
tion, with new flows of funds and the return of European and
foreign institutional investors. At the same time, the public debt
market spreads also experienced a significant narrowing down,
returning in the case of the Spain and Italy to around 300 basis
points. The disabling of the loop-shaped coordination failure bet-
ween sovereign debt and bank risk also had some effect on the
monetary and credit performance, as well as on the real economy.
Towards the end of the first quarter, both the European
Commission and the ECB stated that the M3 and private sector
loans exhibited positive – albeit very low – expansion rates, where-
as activity stabilised after the drop in the last quarter and first
months of 2012.


   Beyond its short term efficacy as an insurance mechanism in the
face of the systemic deterioration of the crisis, the full effect of the
quantitative easing for banks only in the Eurosystem will only be
assessable over time. Nevertheless, the strategy adopted has some
weak points, among which we highlight the following:
• It emphasises the Eurosystem’s tendency towards geographi-
  cal concentration of net funding. The net amount and the dis-


                                                                     163
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


      persal of the net lending volumes by country and of intra-sys-
      tem balances have increased substantially. The Eurosystem has
      thus decided to carry on its clearing role for private funds move-
      ments, directly avoiding having to deal with the underlying
      causes of such movements in order to modify them. The side-
      effect is the increase in the risk volume of the Eurosystem and
      in its geographical concentration, assumed by member coun-
      tries in proportion to their share of the capital.
• It fails to put an end to the fragility of the public debt markets
      in the face of dislocation, and might even increase it.
      According to BIS figures, Spanish Banks have increased their
      public debt holdings by over 40,000 million between December
      2011 and January 2012, whereas the Italians did so at around
      15,000 million euros. This evolution, which is due to the entities
      taking advantage of the possibility of generating margin by borro-
      wing from the Eurosystem and buying public debt, might end up
      being counter-productive for two reasons. In first place, because
      these are not resources geared towards credit for the non-financial
      private sector (which is the main objective behind it). And
      secondly, because it might even intensify the means of contagion
      towards the banking system if the public debt spreads widen once
      again. A demand has therefore been generated for the more casti-
      gated public debt securities, but nothing can guarantee that the
      market evolution will not suffer further dislocation episodes
      which will increase volatility once again and widen the gap bet-
      ween market prices and prices based on fundamental variables.
• The SMP might be relegated an amortised instrument. It


164
The Future of the Euro


   seems logical that the Programme activity was interrupted
   almost at the time when the positive impact of long term fun-
   ding operations became evident. The problem is that, within the
   Governing Council, the opposition to the reactivation of the
   SMP is likely to increase in the event of a new dislocation of the
   markets, arguing that both the levels of risk in the balance sheet
   and degree of geographical concentration are way too high. This
   eventually would be cause for grave concern, given that the SMP
   was the instrument which had succeeded in preventing a syste-
   mic collapse of the euro region both in May 2010 and in August-
   September 2011.


   There is an alternative, which the Eurosystem has ruled out,
which might prove more effective as a contribution towards a defi-
nitive solution to the crisis. It would involve directly tackling the
source of the problem, which is the instability that the dislocation
of some public debt markets have brought upon the core of the
economy’s funding system. The aim would be to ensure that a limit
is established on the deviation between the market prices and pri-
ces adjusted to fundamental economic variables which must not be
exceeded. Although there are various ways of implementing this
type of measure, they all involve direct intervention in the market
in a plausible way. Only the central bank, with its power to create
unlimited money, will be able to successfully carry out such a task.


   A reasonable option would be to publicly commit to ensuring
that the spread between short term sovereign debt in euro countries


                                                                   165
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


does not surpass a certain value threshold. Given the arbitrage rela-
tionship between the various terms of a country’s public debt yield
curve, the application of this stability limit on the shorter part of the
curve (bills and bonds up to 2 years) would suffice, for this then to
be applied to longer terms. In fact, the epicentre of the dislocation
episodes in the public debt markets can be found in the shorter part
of the curve, where volatility increases and exorbitant probabilities
of default emerge, which in turn adversely affect the repo market,
which is crucial for short term financing of the banking system.


      The stability limits should be defined for each country on the
basis of its vulnerability and adapted as the case may be to take into
account potential default in commitments of fiscal consolidation
and structural reform. By way of illustration, for Spain and Italy the
stability limits might be around 200 basis points: this level would
be clearly above what can be considered a fair value spread. But
what is important is not to compress the spreads as much to ensu-
re the stability thereof to enable the transmission mechanism of the
monetary policy to operate under relative normality.


      The Eurosystem should purchase public debt when the price rea-
ches the stability limit. But if this proposal is viable, the volume of
debt eventually purchased by the Eurosystem is likely to be more limi-
ted than that already in place in the SMP. Moreover, the volume of
purchase of public debt could be sterilised, as is already done now. The
problem is less about amount of money, and more about price struc-
ture and risk, as well as market operation.


166
The Future of the Euro


   This type of initiative would enable to transform the perverse
dynamics of debt into a virtuous circle. The recovery of monetary
and financial stability in the more adversely affected countries
would establish the conditions for fiscal consolidation and structu-
ral reform measures to have the positive impact that they should
have had on the confidence of agents and markets.


   It is not about the Eurosystem taking on a new role as lender of
last resort to the States, which would be entirely inappropriate.9
The idea would be to preserve the good operation of the debt mar-
kets as a key component in the transmission mechanism of mone-
tary policy and funding of the economy. We are speaking of a
public good of great economic value, the protection of which is an
essential (albeit not explicit) task of any central bank. But as we
recalled earlier, the Eurosystem is not a central bank like the rest.


   The rejection by the Governing Council of a plausible intervention
in the public debt markets designed to limit the instability seems to be
related to a number of economic and legal objections. It is argued that
this type of action does not pertain to a central bank and that it carries
inflationist risks in that it would be assuming a quasi-fiscal role,
attempting to solve problems of lack of budgetary discipline and/or




9 De Grauwe (2011), after performing a thorough analysis of the crisis, uses the notion
of lender of last resort for sovereign debt markets. Subsequently, this idea has been used
by others to assimilate a plausible intervention in the debt markets with State funding
via the central bank.


                                                                              167
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


competitiveness by means of creating money. It is also argued that it
may violate section 123 of the Treaty, or at least the spirit thereof.


      Despite having the seal of respectability granted by the
Bundesbank, such arguments are questionable. It is true that the
Eurosystem should not intervene in public debt markets if the
widening of the spreads is due to irresponsible fiscal policies or an
impairment of fundamental variables (a drop in the GDP, an incre-
ase in the external deficit). For this reason it is highly probable that
a mistake was made when in May 2010 the Eurosystem purchased
Greek public debt. But when the market dislocation begins via con-
tagion and, furthermore, is endogenous and subject to feedback, if
the central bank does not act, it is opening the door to monetary
restriction which would endanger price stability not only of the
country but of all the region. As for inflation, this type of uncon-
ventional measure would carry lesser inflationist risk than the
other two long term funding operations unanimously approved by
the Governing Council. The argument to intervene becomes even
stronger when the affected countries have reacted to contagion by
accelerating their fiscal adjustment plans and implementing signi-
ficant structural reforms.


      On the other hand, a more plausible and decisive intervention
in debt markets would not only not violate what is set forth in sec-
tion 123, but would in fact be fully coherent with the spirit there-
of. The text of the section refers to the direct purchase of public
debt securities in the primary market, excluding from the ban the


168
The Future of the Euro


purchase of bonds on the secondary market. The ban on monetary
funding seeks to ensure the independence of monetary policy in
regard to the needs imposed by the fiscal policy. The public indeb-
tedness requirements (arising from treasury deficits, net asset varia-
tion and the refinancing of debt maturities) must be covered by
appealing to the market, without resorting to the expansion of the
monetary base, which ends up generating an inflationist bias.
However, compliance with this healthy principle requires the exis-
tence and proper operation of a liquid and deep public debt mar-
ket. A lack of action in the face of the dislocation of public debt
markets means accepting the gradual destruction of one of the
basic foundation stones of the separation between fiscal policy and
monetary policy.10


   In our opinion, the reason why the Eurosystem has not chosen
this solution, more in line with the practice of other comparable
central banks, is not economic but political. This is difficult to belie-
ve, in that it is a fiercely independent institution managed by qua-
lified professionals. But as was pointed out in the first sentence, the
Monetary Union is a political construction; and the euro crisis
carries, as is natural, a very influential political dimension. The
governments and central bank authorities of Germany and all other


10 Within the monetary union, the loss of access to the market as a result of contagion
does not mean resorting to monetary funding of public debt, but the use of official fun-
ding on a temporary basis. However, this situation quickly leads to some to request to
exit the euro and the recovery of monetary sovereignty as a means of escaping the per-
verse dynamics of debt.



                                                                            169
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


countries benefiting from the positive contagion of the Greek crisis,
have viewed the crisis as a vindication of their economic philosop-
hies and an opportunity to reconsolidate the Monetary Union in
accordance with their principles. And as part of this process, they
understand that market pressure is an efficient discipline that must
not be neutralised. In their opinion, the markets may exaggerate,
but in the end they reflect the fundamental economic problems.


      In summary, the Eurosystem has proven to be essential in con-
taining the crisis at the times of greater systemic danger, but it has
not done what any national central bank would have done to tac-
kle the perverse dynamics of debt which threaten the survival of
the euro. In a way, it cannot be blamed. It has acted in accordance
with its nature.




4. The definitive solution must begin in 2012

      After the bad omens with which 2011 came to an end, the first
few months of 2012 have seen the danger of a systemic collapse of
the euro fade into the distance, and it even seems that certain sig-
nificant steps have been taken towards a definitive solution to the
crisis. The insurance provided by the Eurosystem has brought
about time and tranquillity.


      But the situation is still critical, if we look beyond the financial
tension gauges and we measure the situation of the real economy


170
The Future of the Euro


and political cohesion within the area. The deterioration of the cri-
sis in the second half of 2011 has come at a very high cost in terms
of a fall into recession for Spain and Italy and other member coun-
tries, as well as the worsening outlook for countries with a pro-
gramme. To the rise in unemployment we must add new fiscal
adjustment measures, required to meet the targets in a context of
lesser growth of tax bases and higher cyclical expenditure. At the
same time, the detachment towards the Monetary Union is on the
increase, both in countries punished by financial pressure as well
as in creditor countries.


   Given such conditions, the definitive solution to the crisis, this
being understood as the one allowing recovery of sustained
growth throughout the region and a reduction and stabilisation of
the credit risk spreads, cannot take as long as the refund of the
money by the banks to the ECB. It is urgent and the effect of
Eurosystem long term funding operations should be harnessed in
order to implement it.


   In our opinion, the definitive solution is made up of 4 compo-
nents. Two of them are already well on track. The third is the key:
the one requiring greater effort due to its political and technical
complexity. And the last is fundamental to prevent future crises and
to encourage the stable operation of the Monetary Union; but this
can be taken more slowly, as it is not a pressing need and will even-
tually happen when the time is right.




                                                                   171
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


             A SUITABLE HANDLING OF THE INSOLVENCY PROBLEM IN
       GREECE. Immediately after the approval by the States in the euro
       region of the Loan to Greece which gave rise to the first adjust-
       ment programme carried out jointly with the IMF in April 2010,
       the prevailing opinion in the financial markets was that Greece
       had a solvency problem which required debt restructuring.
       However, among the European authorities, including the ECB, the
       overriding idea was that any measure generating losses for inves-
       tors had to be avoided at all costs. It was believed that this appro-
       ach might exacerbate contagion to other public debt markets.


             But the delay in recognising this problem undoubtedly was very
       onerous. In the Deauville Declaration of October 2010, the leaders
       of France and Germany, guided by the healthy aim of involving
       private investors in the assumption of losses as a result of their
       decisions, extended the potential risk beyond Greece, moreover
       projecting it to the future. And in spring 2011, it became clear that
       the first Greek programme was not in line with the assumption of
       return to the market expected for 2012.11 Finally, the Heads of
       State and Government of the Eurozone countries decided in
       October 2011 that the restructuring of Greek debt had to allow suf-
       ficient reduction of its stock and that this solution was meant
       exclusively for the exceptional case of Greece.




11 The alarm bell was sounded by the IMF, given that the approval of program disbur-
sements requires a reasonable guarantee that the financing needs of the country are



       172
The Future of the Euro


   A year and a half after the outbreak of the crisis, one of the most
decisive conclusions was thus reached: the problem of Greece is
special and requires special handling. And a series of questionable
decisions that had amalgamated, consciously or unconsciously, the
Greek situation with that of other vulnerable countries in the
region, was thus left behind.


   Greece has continued to be a source of uncertainty which has
affected the crisis dynamics. Its economic depression (a 13% drop
in real GDP between 2009 and 2011, a 30% drop in deposits in the
banking system during the same period) and the proof of its insti-
tutional frailty have led to a situation of clear unsustainability of
its public debt,12 calling into question the viability of its perma-
nence in the euro. And the risk of Greece’s departure is a very dis-
turbing scenario, as this is not contemplated in the Treaties and it
is difficult to imagine the consequences it may lead to.


   The Private Sector Involvement (PSI) Operation in the reduction
of debt, a prior condition for the approval of the second program-
me by the Eurogroup and the IMF, was quite successfully executed
throughout the month of March. The operation is a sophisticated

met for the following year; and given the market situation, the IMF considered that
Greece could not be expected to return to the market in 2012 as expected.
12 The deterioration of the sustainability analyses of the Troika since the start of the
programme has been overwhelming. At the start of the program the public debt vs.
GDP was expected to reach its peak in 2012 with 158% of GDP and no reduction. In
autumn 2011, this peak was changed to 186%; finally, the sustainability analysis carried
out after the PSI operation suggests a peak of 164% of the GDP.


                                                                            173
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


        and European version of the Brady Plan,13 which has used bonds
        issued by the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) to soften
        the drop in present value of over 50% in exchange for new ultra
        long term bonds. The credible threat of a disordered bankruptcy
        and the retroactive introduction of Collective Action Clauses in
        the issues subject to Greek legislation managed to achieve a per-
        centage participation in the exchange above 95%. The operation
        has succeeded in reducing the debt load and Greek state’s refinan-
        cing needs very substantially.


              From a liquidity approach and at punitive rates at the start of
        2010, reality has taken over through an operation in which priva-
        te investors rightly take on a part of the cost of bankruptcy pre-
        vention14 and Eurozone countries assume greater risks, for longer
        periods and in exchange for lower interest rates.


              Despite the magnitude of the debt reduction (100,000 million
        euros, which would allow it to reach a ratio over GDP of 116.5% in
        2020, according to the sustainability analysis of the Troika), the


13 Name of the Plan used at the end of the 1980s to solve the foreign debt crisis of deve-
loping countries, mainly Latin American. It consisted in exchanging outstanding bonds
for new bonds with a lower present value and longer terms, guaranteed by US Treasury
issued securities.
14 The policy of loss avoidance for investors led to a perverse dynamics whereby priva-
te investors reduced their exposure, in many cases with substantial gains, thanks to the
ever increasing involvement of official creditors. Taken to the extreme, this logic would
have led to a process whereby private investors would not suffer any losses whereas the
official lenders were left funding the entire Greek debt.



        174
The Future of the Euro


prevailing opinion seems to emphasise the main risks facing the
second Greek programme.15 After the last two years, any glimpse
of a positive assessment in regard to what is going on in Greece
seems completely off the wall. It is true that the sharp drop in the
GDP, the fiscal adjustment and the reforms carried out have not
achieved sufficient reduction in the primary budgetary balance or
in the current deficit (which is still around 10% of GDP). However,
in our opinion, the PSI operation and the approval of the new pro-
gramme, which supports devaluation via the reduction of labour
costs, the gradual continuation of the fiscal adjustment and the
50,000 million euros to ensure the solvency of the banking system,
will be able to restore certain stability to the Greek economy.
Taking into account the reduction in uncertainty, the moderate
deflation of costs and the effort invested in structural reforms,
there is a very clear potential for economic recovery. This stabiliza-
tion would exert a positive impact on expectations, leading in turn
to a virtuous circle. All this depends on the country being able to
maintain a stable political leadership which is committed to com-
pliance with the second programme.


   In any event, the value of the PSI operation and the second pro-
gramme for the definitive solution of the euro crisis arises from the
reduction in uncertainty. Despite the need to continue to adopt
policies which require sacrifices on the part of the citizenship for

15 See for instance the IMF report on the request for a new program, which emphasizes
the risk of new accidents and the importance of Euro members undertaking to continue
to finance Greece in concessional terms whilst the appropriate policies are implemented.



                                                                            175
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


some time, the reduction of the debt and the funding of the long
term needs of the State render the option of staying in the euro
much more attractive than the option of departure (although the
latter will continue to have its supporters both in and outside of
Greece).


      A FISCAL PACT TO STRENGTHEN POLITICAL CONFIDENCE.
The Greek experience clearly justifies a reinforcement of the fiscal
regulations of the euro, so that these are more efficient during the
expansive stages of the cycle, therefore obliging member states to
internalise the external cost of unbalanced public finances.


      The European Union already approved in 2011 a substantial
toughening of the Stability Pact and Growth, as part of the reform
of the macro-economic governance known as Six Pack, which also
broadens the multilateral supervision of macro-economic imbalan-
ces of a non-fiscal nature. The preventive section includes the quan-
titative definition of what is understood to be a substantial deviation
from the Medium Term Objective of structural budgetary balance or
from the path established to achieve it. The corrective section brings
about the Excessive Deficit Procedure due to the non-fulfilment of
the public debt criterion and introduces the reverse qualified majo-
rity rule for decision-making, which will make it harder for member
states to put a stop to a Commission proposal. Minimum require-
ments are also established for the budgetary frameworks of the coun-
tries, in terms of coverage of all administrations, multiannual natu-
re and quality of the public accounting systems.


176
The Future of the Euro


    This exhaustive reform of the fiscal rules culminated with the
signature on 2 March 2012 of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination
and Governance. This new Treaty:
•   Has been signed by 25 of the 27 EU member countries, alt-
    hough it will only be legally binding for euro members.
•   It shall come into force on 1 January 2013, provided it has been
    ratified by 12 euro member states, thus avoiding the uncer-
    tainty associated with the ratification process of a modification
    of EU Treaties. Even so, its content is expected to be added to
    community legislation within five years.
•   It introduces the rule of budget balancing. This will be unders-
    tood to be met when the structural deficit reaches its Medium
    Term Objective (MTO) with a maximum deficit of 0.5% (which
    can reach 1% if the debt is significantly below 60% and the sus-
    tainability risks are low).
•   Any significant deviation from MTO or from the path of adjust-
    ment towards the MTO that is observed will trigger an automa-
    tic correction mechanism, defined in the national legislation
    but inspired by the principles established by the Commission.
    The foregoing shall be of application unless in the event of
    exceptional circumstances.16
•   Both the rule and the correction mechanism must be added to
    the national legislative systems, preferably at a constitutional
    level, within the year subsequent to the entry in force of the



16 This refers to i) An unusual event outside of the control of the country which has a
large impact on the financial position of the public administrations or to ii) periods of


                                                                             177
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


              Treaty. And the transposition shall be subject to verification by
              the EU Court of Justice, which shall be empowered to take dis-
              ciplinary action in the event of infringement.
        •     The euro countries undertake to support Commission propo-
              sals within the framework of the excessive deficit procedure
              concerning any of them, except in the event of a qualified
              majority thereof against it.


              The new Treaty is consistent with the system of fiscal regula-
        tions established in the revised SGP and actually uses its basic com-
        ponents (the MTO, the significant deviation and the exceptional
        circumstances). What it does is to toughen these rules and increa-
        se the legal rank thereof within the internal legal system. The two
        most important items are the rule of budget balance and the auto-
        matic correction mechanism.


              In technical terms, the new framework of fiscal rules for the
        euro is reasonable from a medium to long term perspective, inso-
        far as:


        •     It reinforces the discipline mechanism during the expansive
              phases of the cycle, which will oblige budgets to be kept in
              balance or with surplus.



serious economic contraction as this is defined in the revised Stability and Growth Pact
and, in both cases, provided the temporary deviation does not endanger medium term
fiscal sustainability.



        178
The Future of the Euro


•   It increases control at a European level on the quality of the
    public accounts as a basis for multilateral supervision of the fis-
    cal policies.
•   It increases the credibility of the prevention and sanctioning
    mechanisms, assisting in non-discretional decision-making and
    toughening sanctions.
•   It obliges national legal systems to fully incorporate both the
    fiscal rules and the minimum requirements of quality and coor-
    dination of budgetary frameworks.


    In the medium to long term, the application of such rules, assu-
ming a trend nominal growth of 3% per annum, would lead to a
public debt stock of 17% of GDP (Whelan, 2012). The key for such
rules to generate anti-cyclical fiscal policies is that they are able to
impose tough discipline during the expansive phases, that the
reliability of the fiscal information is assured and that the sanc-
tions are applied in rigorous and equitable way for all.


    The use of a non-observable variable such as the structural
balance in order to assess compliance with the deficit rule makes
sense, but it complicates the practical application thereof due to
uncertainty in regard to the correct estimate of potential GDP. The
case of Spain during the phase prior to the crisis is paradigmatic:
during the period 2005-2007, the Commission estimated the struc-
tural budgetary balance to be very close to the nominal balance,
given that the growth estimate for potential GDP was around 3%.
The subsequent performance of the economy and of the public


                                                                     179
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


income and expenditure has shown that in the years previous to
the crisis, Spain was growing over and above its potential and that
the structural balance was much worse than that indicated by the
nominal surplus.


      In reality, the value of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and
Governance is above all political, as it helps to bring about once
again a new political understanding among the euro member
countries. Several countries have interpreted the financial aid as a
breach, at least in spirit, of the non-mutual guarantee clause in the
Treaty. It was hard for Germany and other countries in the D-mark
area to bring their monetary sovereignty in line with that of coun-
tries with a lesser tradition of stability. And the non-guarantee
clause was one of the essential conditions to do so. Part of the atti-
tude of governments and central bank authorities in these coun-
tries in the last two years could be explained by this feeling that
rules have been broken.


      The new Treaty, with its reflection in the Constitutions of several
countries, is one more step for countries in the north and centre to
believe that the countries which are currently more vulnerable are
adopting a longstanding commitment to fiscal discipline, beyond
the adjustment forced upon them by the markets. And this confi-
dence is essential to the creation of political conditions which will
enable decisions to be taken with a view to solving the crisis. The
Fiscal Pact is therefore a necessary condition, but in no way is it
enough to make 2012 the year of the start of the end of the crisis.


180
The Future of the Euro


   The Treaty will strengthen the policy of firm advancement in fis-
cal consolidation in the most vulnerable countries, which has been
applied for the last two years. But we are already aware that the per-
verse dynamics can make a steadfast programme of fiscal adjustment
which lacks a complement to help restore growth fail in its objecti-
ve of stabilising public debt. Without nominal growth and financial
stability, the efforts made in regard to deficit reduction not only fail
to reduce the debt/GDP ratio, but actually increase it.


   THE GRADUAL AND FLEXIBLE CONSTRUCTION OF A SIN-
GLE PUBLIC DEBT MARKET. The key to doing away with the per-
verse dynamics of debt is to restore the good working order of the
public debt markets, so that the spreads are more in line with eco-
nomic fundamentals and more stable. This is an essential condition
for relaxing financial terms in vulnerable countries and for allowing
growth to benefit from the positive effects of the reforms adopted.


   We have already pointed out that there is no confidence that the
Eurosystem will adopt the strategy required to achieve this objecti-
ve. A second alternative on the table is the EFSF/ESM. In theory, the
EFSF/ESM, with the set of intervention instruments which it
currently contains, has the effective capacity to stabilise the public
debt markets. However, in our opinion, financial aid is not an effi-
cacious solution to the perverse dynamics of debt. Under current
conditions, the preventive funding facilities would soon become
ordinary adjustment programmes; the result would be the exten-
sion of the loss of access to market funding and the escalation of the


                                                                     181
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


political tension arising from the concentration of funding in the
area from only a few contributor countries. On the other hand, the
design of the secondary market intervention instruments has too
many political and operational limitations to even appear plausible.


      In our opinion, the most suitable way is the creation of a new
public debt market with jointly and severally guaranteed securities.
This is a very important and delicate political decision, as it involves
the pooling together of sovereign risk, which is an essential part of
fiscal sovereignty. Countries with higher credit rating have been hit-
herto reluctant to share the issue of debt with those of a lower cre-
dit quality. This attitude is fair and understandable; to ask Finland,
Holland or Germany to pool together all the debt issued with more
indebted and vulnerable countries is politically unrealistic.


      But given the current crossroads of the Monetary Union, this
step must be taken, and the way to do it is to design it in such a
way that it is politically feasible. This design should abide by the
following principles:
•     The construction of a single public debt market in euros must
      be done gradually. The first stone must be solid but of a mode-
      rate size. The next stones shall be placed little by little and on
      the basis of experience.
•     At the first stage, the percentage of public debt pooled together
      must be limited. This requirement should be in line with the
      doctrine of the German Constitutional Court, which requires
      bonds issued by the State to have a clear quantitative limit.


182
The Future of the Euro


•   The pooled debt must be senior to the national debt, in order to
    reduce the risk of the joint and several guarantee.
•   Incentives restricting moral hazard must be introduced, taking
    in account the strengthened governance framework of the
    Monetary Union.


    In the Eurobond debate, several specific formulae have been
considered which are compatible with such principles. The pione-
er was the blue bond/red bond proposal (Delpla & Weizsäcker,
2009), which suggested pooling together up to 60% of the public
debt over the GDP (blue debt), leaving the rest as subordinate
national debt (red debt). The Commission published a Green Paper
containing various different options of Stability Bonds which
aimed at feeding the debate. Lastly, the proposal of a European
Debt Redemption Fund from the Group of German Economic
Experts (2011), which advises the Federal Government, is also of
great interest, in that it considers the pooling together of the sur-
plus of the 60% of debt over GDP in exchange for real guarantees
in order to overcome the crisis. 17


    In our opinion, the most attractive alternative would be the
Eurobills proposal made by Hellwig & Phillippon (2011) which
would consist of:
•   The issue with a joint and several guarantee of all public debt
    securities with initial maturities of up to 1 year (Eurobills).

17 The formula of the surplus over and above the 60% does not seem fair, as it rewards
the more indebted countries.


                                                                           183
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


       •     The participation of each member country would be limited to
             10% of the GDP. The Eurobill market would therefore have a
             maximum size, based on the GDP for 2011, of 1 billion euros.
       •     The Eurobills would be senior to all other longer term debt, as
             the short term debt is already de facto senior to medium and
             long term debt.
       •     The loss of access to the Eurobills could be considered discipli-
             nary action within the framework of multilateral supervision
             of fiscal policies and macro-economic imbalances.


             The Eurobills are a simple formula with many advantages:
       •     Efficacy. As we have already mentioned, the core of the dislo-
             cation in economy funding mechanisms lies with the shorter
             part of the debt markets and its connection to the money mar-
             kets. The Eurobills would manage to directly tackle the failure
             and the effect would be foreseeably transmitted throughout
             the yield curve. They would thus represent an alternative to
             stability limits.
       •     Political feasibility. The high level of political and legal com-
             mitment to fiscal stability brought by the new Treaty should
             allow for the more solvent countries to accept the Eurobills.
             Given their term, the risk is limited; and in terms of cost if
             issue, the loss would be small or non-existent.18
       •     Operating facility. The EFSF/ESM already issues bills, so it could
             easily assumed the issue of Eurobills. A system would have to

18 The bills issued by the EFSF with proportional guarantees from euro member coun-
tries have a small spread compared to German bills. Taking as a reference the issue of



       184
The Future of the Euro


    be established to consolidate the treasury needs for each State,
    as Bills play a certain role as treasury management instruments.
•   Additional benefits. Eurobills could be used to meet Basel III
    liquidity requirements and would attract a strong demand from
    institutional investors in and outside of the region.


    The construction of a single public debt market in euros will be
a long and complicated process, likely to take decades. It is a basic
ingredient in the path of the euro towards institutional maturity,
which shall have to develop alongside advancements made in fis-
cal integration. But it must commence now, as it is the key to over-
come the crisis once and for all.


    THE FEDERALISATION OF BANKING SUPERVISION IN THE
EUROSYSTEM AND THE CREATION OF A EUROPEAN DEPOSIT
GUARANTEE FUND. In hindsight, one of the most serious flaws of
the institutional framework of the first decade of the euro has to do
with banking supervision and crisis management. In order to reach
a definitive solution, this flaw must be corrected.


    Despite having harmonised prudential legislation from the
start, the euro region has worked with banking systems which have
continued to be governed by an essentially national approach. On


March 6 month bills, the spread compared to the German bills is lower than 20 basis
points. The cost of issue of the Eurobills would naturally be lower than that of the EFSF
bills, thanks to the joint and several guarantees, closer to the levels at which bills are
currently issued by Germany and by other countries with a higher credit rating.



                                                                              185
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


the other hand, despite the efforts begun following the Brouwer
Report (2001) to build a crisis management plan within the EU,
when the crisis was broke out weak in deposit guarantee and prac-
tically non-existent in the intervention and liquidation of credit
institutions.


      One of the most illustrative indicators of this persistence of the
national approach in the realm of banking is that the integration
has advanced more between euro countries and non-euro coun-
tries than within the euro region itself. Among the problems asso-
ciated with this situation, we shall highlight two:
      The absence of global overview of the funding structure of
the area and its relation with monetary policy. The creation of
the euro led to a strong expansion of gross and net flows within
the area. In a way, this was the reallocation of capital towards those
countries where it was scarce and could obtain better returns. But
in some countries this process ended up by creating bubbles in the
real estate sector, which reached hitherto unknown peaks partly
due to belonging to the Monetary Union (low interest rates, very
elastic supply of external funds). In light of the high short term
economic benefits in terms of extraction of income, employment,
fiscal activity and collection, the economic policy renders very dif-
ficult, as we have seen, the adoption of domestic measures to burst
the bubble. At the same time, given that monetary policy is exo-
genous to the authorities of a country, the effect thereof is not
internalised in regard to the creating or blowing up a bubble furt-
her. But it is not only about bubbles. The global crisis showed up


186
The Future of the Euro


other weaknesses in the funding structure of the banks in the euro
region, such as its dependence on the liquidity of the US money
markets.


  The possibility that a banking crisis might bring down a
country. National supervision goes hand in hand with the natio-
nal responsibility for covering costs in the event of a crisis. As we
have seen in Ireland, the bank solvency problems can overwhelm
the fiscal capacity of the country. Moreover, and continuing with
the Irish example, the potential effects of contagion within the
Monetary Union limit the capacity of the affected country to solve
the crisis by the assumption of losses by private creditors.


  Since the start of the crisis, considerable progress has been made
in terms of coordination of bank supervision and crisis manage-
ment in Europe. Nevertheless, the maturity of the Monetary Union
still has a way to go. The essential public policies on the banking
system must be common within the euro area, in accordance with
a plan with two main cornerstones:
• Federal banking supervision within the Eurosystem. The time
  has come to make use of a provision of the Treaty on the fede-
  ralization of banking supervision within the euro area. Given
  that only in 5 euro countries the banking supervisor is separate
  from the central bank, and that the ECB is the most powerful
  euro institution, the most natural approach to achieve this is by
  awarding competencies to the Eurosystem. And the competen-
  cies assumed must include micro-prudential regulation, macro-


                                                                   187
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


      prudential regulation and part of the crisis prevention and
      management function.
• A European Deposit Guarantee Fund (EDGF). The crisis has
      proven that the deposit guarantee systems are basic instruments
      in the prevention and management of banking crises. During
      the global crisis, the risk of having systems with insufficient
      coverage (eg. Northern Rock) or the chaos generated by unilate-
      ral decisions on levels of coverage within the euro (movements
      of deposits between countries at the end of 2008) became
      patently clear. With the generalized increase in coverage of
      deposits up to 100,000 euros (which increases the cost of the
      liquidation of the institutions), the guarantee funds, in princi-
      ple, assume a crucial responsibility. However, the models of
      deposit guarantee systems within the area as still quite different
      from one another. For this reason an obligatory adhesion fund
      should be created to assume the guarantee of all deposits in the
      banks of the euro area and their branches in the EU. The fund
      should be made up of the contributions from entities, determi-
      ned on the basis of credit and liquidity risk and have a system
      of governance similar to that of the Spanish guarantee funds,
      presided over by the ECB and with broad representation of the
      private sector in its Board of Governance. The functions of this
      EDGF should include the resolution of banking crises, assisting
      the mandate of the Eurosystem in early intervention and crisis
      resolution at the lowest cost for the public treasury. As an addi-
      tional and exceptional mechanism of funding, a system could
      be established whereby the ESM could lend funds to the EDGF.


188
The Future of the Euro


    The improvement in the operation of the Monetary Union as a
result of the federalisation of banking supervision and crisis mana-
gement would be considerable in the medium and long term. The
following are among the possible positive changes associated with
this reform:
•   The monetary transmission mechanism would become more
    robust against national fiscal evolutions and the fluctuations of
    the financial markets.
•   A boost to cross-border integration and consolidation. The pro-
    tection of domestic industry would become more difficult,
    which would lead to benefits of risk diversification and econo-
    mies of scale. And competition would gradually become more
    intense, which is essential after the re-nationalisation of the
    banking markets and the strong public support provided to cri-
    sis- affected entities.
•   Support for incentives to implement measures to prevent the
    creation of speculative bubbles.
•   The internalisation of external effects and public service provi-
    sion problems associated with financial stability within the
    area. This would allow for the creation of a structure where the
    central bank and the Ministries (Eurogroup) work much more
    efficiently towards preserving financial stability.
•   It would support the introduction of measures to achieve grea-
    ter involvement of the private sector in the solution of future
    crises.




                                                                    189
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


5. Conclusion

      The adolescent crisis of the euro is extremely serious. European
and national authorities have taken courageous and significant
decisions in recent months, in many cases having learned from
previous mistakes. The restructuring of the debt and the new
adjustment programme are an intelligent and well executed res-
ponse to the serious solvency problem in Greece. Ireland and
Portugal are applying their programmes with excellent assessments
made by the troika. And an institutional framework is under way,
which will render the generation of a crisis in the future a lot less
likely.


      Much political and social capital has been spent on implemen-
ting such measures. It is clear that the euro member countries are
willing to make great sacrifices in order to preserve the project. But
the truth is that the crisis has not yet been overcome, because the
root causes of the uncertainty and the instability generated by the
dislocation of the public debt markets have not been attacked.


      The economy within the euro area will foreseeably face a second
recession three years after the sharp blow of 2009. Ireland and
Portugal are watching their expectations of recovery fade as a
result of lower foreign demand and maintenance of financial pres-
sure. And there are questions as to the likelihood of its return to
the markets within the timeframes set and even in regard to the
Greece and no more commitment. Spain and Italy are implementing


190
The Future of the Euro


strong fiscal adjustments and deep structural reforms in an envi-
ronment of recession and financial vulnerability.


   The euro cannot afford to undergo another episode like the one
in August-September 2011. It is imperative that a measure is taken
to protect us against that risk and removes, once and for all, the
devastating coordination failure of the global crisis of 2009. Having
assumed that the stabilisation of the debt markets cannot be pro-
vided by the central bank as in other countries, we have to choose
a new market. Eurobills are an efficient and balanced solution;
2012 should be their birth year. They will help reunify monetary
policy, by first restoring stability and establishing the foundations
for a solid economic recovery. These conditions are essential for the
programmes to work, for the debt to stabilize and for the consoli-
dation and reform policies to be effective and have continuity.
There is no future without stability and growth.


   It is not necessary to search for great constructions or to come
up with solutions for all the problems. The Eurozone shall never be
an optimal monetary region. It does not need to be. For the time
being, we must concentrate on a series of efficient and plausible fis-
cal regulations, a single monetary policy based on debt markets
which are operating fairly and a stable banking system capable of
funding the economy. And to continue to learn and build an incre-
asingly closer union. The countries that are currently suffering will
learn from their mistake; one cannot prosper within the euro with
the same institutional framework that one had out of the euro:


                                                                   191
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


foreign finances continue to be a restriction, the real exchange rate
and the flexibility in real salaries and mark-ups are important, cre-
dit excesses cost dearly… but we must allow some time for the les-
sons learned to be put into practice and produce good results.




192
The Future of the Euro


Bibliography

- Aizenman, J., Hutchison, M. and Jinjarak, Y. (2011) “What is the
risk of European sovereign debt defaults? Fiscal Space, CDS Spreads and
Market pricing of Risk”. NBER Working Paper 17407.


- Barrios, S., Iversen, P., Lewandowska, M. and Setzer, R. (2009)
“Determinants of intra-euro area government bond spreads during the
financial crisis” Economic Papers 388. European Commission.


- Bernanke, B. and Reinhart, V. (2004) “Conducting Monetary Policy
at Very Low Short-Term Interest Rates” American Economic Review,
94(2): 85-90.


- Bernanke, B., Reinhart, V. and Sack, B. (2004) “Monetary Policy
Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical Assessment” Staff Paper.
US Federal Reserve


- Bindseil, U. and König, J. (2011) “The Economics of TARGET2 balan-
ces” SFB 649 Discussion Paper, Universidad Humboldt de Berlín.


- Bornhorst, F. and Mody, A. (2012) “TARGET imbalances: Financing
the capital-account reversal in Europe” VoxEU.org, 7 March.


- Caballero, R. (2010) “Sudden Financial Arrest” Mundell-Fleming
Lecture prepared for the IMF 10th Jacques Polack Annual Research
Conference. IMF Economic Review, July 20, 2010.


                                                                    193
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


- CESifo (2011) “The Bobenberg Declaration: 16 theses on the situation
of European Monetary Union”. December 2011.


- Cooper, R and John, A. (1991) “Coordinating coordination failures in
Keynesian models” in Mankiw, G. and Romer, D. eds “New
Keynesian Economics” The MIT Press.


- Delpla, J. and Weizsacker, J. (2010), “The Blue Bond Proposal”,
Bruegel Policy Brief 420.


- De Grauwe, P. and Ji. Y. (2012) “Mispricing of Sovereign Risk and
Multiple Equilibria in the Eurozone”. Working Paper, mimeo
www.econ.kuleuven.be/ew/academic/intecon/Degrauwe/


- Dombret, A. (2012) “New year, old problems – Europe’s sovereign debt
crisis”, Speech of a member of the Executive Board of the Deutsche
Bundesbank to the International Bankers’ Club in Luxembourg, 6
February 2012.


- Economic and Financial Committee (2001) “Report on Financial
Crisis Management/Brouwer Report” Council of the European Union.


- EU Commission (2011), “Green Paper: Feasibility of Stability Bonds”,
November.


- German    Council     of   Economic        Experts     (2011)     “Assume
Responsibility for Europe” First Chapter of the 2011/2012 Report.


194
The Future of the Euro


- Hellwig, T. and Philippon, T. (2011) “Eurobills, not Eurobonds”,
VoxEU.org, 2 December 2011.


- Jobst, C. (2011) “A balance sheet view on TARGET-and why restric-
tions on TARGET would have hit Germany first” Vox 19 July 2011.


- Joyce, M., Tong, M. and Woods, R. (2011) "The United Kingdom’s
quantitative easing policy: design, operation and impact” Quarterly
Bulletin 2011 Q3. Bank of England.


- Meaning, J. and Zhu, F. (2011) “The impact of recent central bank
asset purchase programmes” BIS Quarterly Review, December 2011.


- Pisani Ferry, J. (2012) “The Euro crisis and the new impossible trinity”
Bruegel Policy Contribution January 2012.


- Pisany-Ferry, J. (2012) “Debate on Target 2: Don´t confuse symptom
and disease!” Blog de Bruegel, 2 de marzo de 2012.


- Sinn, H.W. (2011) “The ECB Stealth Bailout” VoxEU.org, 1 June.


- Sinn, H.W. (2012) “Fed versus ECB: how Target debts can be repaid”
VoxEU.org 10 March 2012.


- Trichet, J.C. (2011) “The monetary policy of the ECB during the finan-
cial crisis” Speech by the President of the ECB, Montreal, 6 June
2011.


                                                                       195
The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity


- Weidmann, J. (2012) “What is the origin and meaning of the Target2
balances?” Carta del Presidente del Bundesbank publicada en el
Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung y el Het Financieele Dagblad el 13
de marzo de 2012.


- Whelan, K. (2011) “Fiscal Rules: Stocks, Flows and All That” The
Irish Economy Blog, December 9th, 2011.


- Whitaker, J. (2011) “Intra-eurosystem debts” Monetary Research,
Lancaster University Management School. 30 March 2011.


- Whitaker, J. (2011) “Eurosystem debts, Greece and the role of bank-
notes”. Monetary Research, Lancaster University Management
School. 14 November 2011.




196
/DANIEL GROS * / CINZIA ALCIDI**/




          Breaking the common fate of banks
                          and governments




1. Introducción; 2. Recent eurozone history: From bad to worse; 2.1. Recalling
the building blocks of the EMU construction; 3. A false solution to the crisis: the
fiscal compact; 4. Fiscal indiscipline versus financial regulation inconsistency;
5. A proposal for a new regulatory treatment of sovereign debt securities in the
euro area; 6. Conclusions; Bibliography




* Dr. Daniel Gros is the Director of the Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) since
2000. Among other current activities, he serves as adviser to the European Parliament
and is a member of the Advisory Scientific Committee of the European Systemic Risk
Board (ESRB), the Bank Stakeholder Group (BSG) of the European Banking Authority
(EBA) and the Euro 50 Group of eminent economists. He also acts as editor of Economie
Internationale and International Finance. In the past, Daniel Gros worked at the IMF
(1984-86), at the European Commission (1989-91), has been a member of high-level
advisory bodies and provided strategic advice to numerous governments and central
banks. Gros holds a PhD. in economics from the University of Chicago, has taught at
prestigious universities throughout Europe and is the author of several books and nume-
rous contributions to scientific journals and newspapers. Since 2005, he has been Vice-
President of Eurizon Capital Asset Management.
** Dr. Cinzia Alcidi holds a Ph.D. degree in International Economics from the Graduate
Institute of International and Development Studies, Geneva (Switzerland). She is



                                                                            197
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


        1. Introduction

              Since 2010 the news about Europe has gone from bad to worse.
        In early 2012, it still cannot be claimed that the eurozone crisis is
        solved, thought markets within the euro area seems to return
        (maybe only temporarily) to more normal conditions.


              Interestingly enough, the average of the fundamentals of the
        euro area looks actually relatively good: compared to the US, the
        eurozone as whole has a much lower fiscal deficit (4% of GDP in
        2011 against almost 10% for the US) and unlike the US, it has no
        external deficit. Its current account is close to balance, which
        means that enough savings exist within the monetary union to
        finance the public deficits of all its member states. This implies, in
        turn, that potentially enough, domestic, euro zone’s resources exist
        to solve the debt problem, without recurring to external lenders.
        Whether these resources will be invested to finance eurozone
        governments is a different question.




currently LUISS Research Fellow at Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) in
Brussels where she is part of the Economic Policy Unit dealing mainly with issues rela-
ted to monetary and fiscal policy in the European Union. Before joining CEPS in early
2009, she taught undergraduate courses at University of Perugia (Italy) and worked at
International Labour Office in Geneva. Her research interest focuses on international
economics and economic policy. Since her arrival at CEPS, she has worked extensively
with Daniel Gros on the macroeconomic and financial aspects of crisis in Europe and
at global level, as well on the policy response to it. She has published several articles on
the topic and participates regularly in international conferences.


        198
The Future of the Euro


   In spite of this relative strength, eurozone policy-makers seem
incapable to solve the debt crisis. Meeting after meeting, heads of
state and Government or finance ministers have failed to convince
markets of the validity of their strategy, which has focused almost
exclusively on fiscal discipline and has repeatedly advocated the
need of financial help from outside investors, e.g. IMF and Asian
investors, regardless of whether resources exist within the eurozo-
ne. This approach has been both misguided and unconvincing.


   Against this background, the paper emphasizes that while the
political agenda is almost obsessively focused on fiscal issues, the
euro zone crisis does not have a mere fiscal nature neither a simple
fiscal solution. It involves different dimensions running from
current account and external debt problems to the weak state of the
banking sector, which is still largely undercapitalized. This paper
will focus on the last element, the state of the banking system and
attempts at highlighting how features of the existing financial mar-
ket regulation framework which are inconsistent with main buil-
ding blocks of the monetary union have affected the course of the
crisis. We will argue that this inconsistency has crucially contribu-
ted to eurozone crisis and still remains unaddressed. The paper also
expresses concern about the misleading, prevailing view that the
just signed fiscal compact will work as crucial ingredient in the reci-
pe to overcome the eurozone crisis, while the banking sector
remains highly leveraged and exposed to the fortune and misfortu-
ne of sovereign governments. On this ground, the paper puts for-
ward some ideas about how to break the tight linkage between


                                                                    199
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


governments and banks. This is at the root of their common fate
and represents a decisive obstacle to overcome the eurozone crisis.




2. Recent eurozone history: From bad to worse

      To understand why the euro crisis has gone from bad to worse,
one needs to develop a better understanding of the inconsistencies
in the setup of European Monetary Union (EMU) that caused the
problem in the first place. The official reading is that this is not a
crisis of the euro, but of the public debt of some profligate euro
area member countries. Therefore, tackling the causes of this crisis
and averting future ones requires only a new, tighter framework for
fiscal policy – which will be delivered by the new ‘fiscal compact’.


      Yet, financial markets do not seem much impressed by a further
strengthening of fiscal rules: Portugal and other countries still have
to pay high risk premia while Greece has defaulted on its debt and
still teeters on the brink of a total collapse. This suggests that the
official approach captures only part of the problem and still misses
the full picture.


      It is not only fiscal indiscipline in the periphery which turned
the public debt problems of a small country like Greece into a cri-
sis of the entire euro area banking system. The euro zone crisis is
the result of a constellation of vulnerabilities within the eurozone.
They include balance of payments problems, foreign debt, sudden-


200
The Future of the Euro


stops of crosser-border financing running from North to South
combined with a generalized undercapitalization of the banking
system.


   This financial fragility has been the result of inconsistencies in
the setup of the EMU as well as a fundamental inconsistency in
financial market regulation that has yet to be addressed.


2.1. Recalling the building blocks of the EMU construction


   The original design of EMU, as established by the Maastricht
Treaty in 1992, contained three key elements:


i) An independent central bank, the ECB, devoted only to price
   stability.
ii) Limits on fiscal deficits enforced via the excessive deficit pro-
   cedure (Treaty based) and the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP,
   essentially an intergovernmental agreement, although still
   within the EU’s legal framework).
iii) The ‘no bail-out’, or rather ‘no co-responsibility’ clause (art.
   125 of the TFEU).


   The treaty also contained other elements of economic gover-
nance,1 but this remained mostly declamatory as in reality

1 For instance, Article 121 of the TFEU contains the provision that member states
should regard economic policies as a matter of common concern and shall coordinate
them within the Council.


                                                                       201
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


       Member States did not see any need to coordinate economic poli-
       cies; at least, not before the crisis.


             The first key element of the Maastricht Treaty, i.e. the very
       strong independence of the ECB, was based on a large consensus
       among both economists and policy makers that the task of a cen-
       tral bank should mainly be to maintain price stability. The con-
       sensus was based on a common reading of the experience of the
       previous decades that higher inflation did not buy more growth
       and independent central banks (with the Bundesbank as the most
       prominent example) are best placed to achieve and maintain price
       stability.2


             Some academic economists and some observers at international
       financial institutions worried already in the 1990s about financial
       instability and advocate a clear role of the EBC in safeguarding
       financial stability.3 Some also emphasized that a common currency
       area also requires a common system of supervision of financial
       markets.4 But the issue of financial stability did not attract the
       attention of policy makers mainly for two main reasons. The first
       one is theoretical: most prominent economic models before 2007
       suggested that price stability delivers financial stability as by-pro-


2 A prominent paper of the period when plans for EMU were taking shape encapsula-
ted this insight in the title ‘The advantage of tying one’s hands’ (see Giavazzi and
Pagano (1988).
3 See for instance Garber (1992).
4 Among others Tommaso Padoa Schioppa (1994).



       202
The Future of the Euro


duct, with no need to add another tool to achieve it. The second
one is much less sophisticated and relates to the fact that the two
key member states driving EMU, France and Germany, had not
experienced a systemic financial crisis for decades.


  The second element of the Maastricht Treaty, namely the limits
on fiscal policy, did not enjoy the same consensus in the academic
profession (nor among policy makers) as central bank indepen-
dence. During the 1990s a wide ranging debate took place about
the sense or non-sense of the Maastricht ‘reference’ values of 3% of
GDP for the deficit and 60% for the debt level. Apparently the
advantage of tying one’s hands was much less recognized in the field
of fiscal policy. However, this debate did not need to be resolved as
long as benign financial market conditions prevailed and even the
core countries conspired to weaken the limits on deficits set by the
SGP in 2003.


  The third element was only in the background and remained
untested until recently. Contrary to a widespread misconception,
Article 125 of the TFEU does not prohibit bail outs. It merely
asserts that the EU does not guarantee the debt of its member sta-
tes and that member states do not guarantee each other’s obliga-
tions. Germany had insisted on the no bail-out clause when the
Maastricht Treaty was negotiated about 20 years ago. Today, it is
clear that this clause does not provide the kind of protection that
was sought and widespread financial market turbulences threaten
to engulf Germany to agree to huge bail-out packages which would


                                                                  203
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


have been unthinkable only recently. However, instead of working
on averting the repeat of this situation in the future, German
policy makers are focusing exclusively on the need to ensure lower
fiscal deficits. This is the purpose of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination
and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union also called the
‘fiscal compact’ under which euro area member countries agree to
adopt strict rules, ‘at the constitutional or equivalent level’, limi-
ting the cyclically adjusted deficit of the government to less than
0.5% of GDP. Will this fiscal compact work where the Stability Pact
failed?


      The ‘original’ SGP already contained the engagement by mem-
ber states to balance their budget over the cycle. If implemented
since the onset of the monetary union, the rule would have led to
a continuous reduction of the debt-to-GDP ratio towards the 60%
target. But this did not happen. The promise or rather exhortation
contained in the SGP to balance budgets over the cycle was widely
ignored, given that the rule was not binding and financial markets
remained in a ‘permissive’ mood. All of the larger euro area mem-
bers ran budget deficits in excess of 3% of GDP threshold for the
first 4-5 years of the euro’s existence. Even Germany ran deficits
above 3% of GDP from 2001 to 2005. In 2003 a proposal put for-
ward by the Commission to ratchet up the excessive deficit proce-
dure to the point where fines might have been imposed on France
and Germany was defeated in the Council (of finance ministers,
ECOFIN). In the crucial vote the large countries (most of which
had excessive deficits, except Spain) colluded to water down the


204
The Future of the Euro


proposal and won the opposition of the smaller countries. The
’band of three large sinners’ (Germany, France and Italy) even
managed to put together a qualified majority to ‘hold the proce-
dure in abeyance’.5


   This narrative is interesting in the light of the new ‘fiscal com-
pact’ which is supposed to radically strengthen the enforcement of
the fiscal rules by the application of the ‘reverse qualified majo-
rity’. Under this principle, an excessive deficit procedure launched
by the Commission is taken to be approved unless it is opposed by
a qualified majority. As past experience shows, despite the new sys-
tem makes the opposition harder, it does not ensure enforcement.


   In 2005, following the 2003 episode, the SGP was changed. The
official justification was the need to improve its economic rational
and thus ownership,6 but it clear that it was necessary to avoid the
repeat of the embarrassing situation in which a literal application
of the rules would have led to sanctions for Germany and France
among others. The reaction in academia and among policy makers
was mixed: the SGP was ‘softened’ according to some, but ‘impro-
ved’ according to others. The very fact that professional opinion
on the merits of ’binding rules for fiscal policy’ was divided from
the start certainly facilitated the change in the SGP when it beca-
me politically opportune.

5 See Gros et al. (2004). 3 See for instance Garber (1992).
6 Annex to the 2005 Council conclusions
(http://register.consilium.europa.eu/pdf/en/05/st07/st07619-re01.en05.pdf).



                                                                          205
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


      As matter of facts, shortly after the SGP was made less stringent,
the upturn of the business cycle allowed most governments to
reduce their deficits to below 3% seemingly vindicating the official
position that the ‘improved’ Stability Pact had led to a more res-
ponsible fiscal policy. But structural deficits (i.e. adjusted for the
cycle) actually improved very little even at time the boom reached
the peak in 2006-7 and, when the crisis hit, any remaining caution
was thrown overboard as deficits were allowed to increase again.


      The euro area countries thus never lived up to the rules they gave
themselves. But even so, on average they remained relatively con-
servative in fiscal terms. In 2009, the average deficit peaked at 6.5%
of GDP, its highest level, whereas both the UK and the US went
above 11% during that year. Moreover, while the eurozone deficit
has brought back to 4% of GDP in 2011, it has remained at double
digits levels in both the UK and the US. In this limited sense, one
could argue that the Maastricht provisions against ‘excessive’ defi-
cits did have some influence after all, at least on average.


      While the average deficits for the euro area appear today
‘modest’ by the standard of other large developed countries, one
euro area country, Greece, clearly violated all rules for years. But
mounting evidence that the Greek fiscal numbers did not add up
was never acted upon until it was too late. As long as financial mar-
kets provided financing at favorable rates any action was politically
inconvenient and was avoided.




206
The Future of the Euro


   When the euro debt crisis started in early 2010 following the
discovery that Greece was running a deficit of 15% of GDP (and
that previous deficits had been misreported), some policymakers,
German in particular, started to call for tighter fiscal rules as essen-
tial to the survival of the euro.Despite Greece was an extreme case,
the case of Italy is widely seen as providing another justification
for tighter fiscal rules. However, the country seems to stand for
complacency rather than fiscal profligacy. Over the last ten years
the deficits of Italy have on average been lower than those for
France and even today its deficit is below the euro area average
(and declining rapidly).Yet, the incapacity of the country to redu-
ce its very high debt-to-GDP ratio has made it vulnerable to a loss
of investor’s confidence.




3. A false solution to the crisis: the fiscal compact

  The new Treaty that was agreed upon in March 2012 has a long
title, Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic
and Monetary Union, but upon closer examination it is long on
good intentions and rather short on substance in terms of binding
provisions.


  The core of the new ‘fiscal compact’ is an obligation to enshrine in
national constitutions the commitment not to allow cyclically adjus-
ted deficits to exceed about ½ of 1% of GDP, which is roughly equi-
valent to balancing the budget over the cycle as in the original SGP.


                                                                     207
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


      This should be done ‘preferable at the constitutional level’. The
European Court of Justice (of the EU) can be asked to pass a judg-
ment on these national rules, but the maximum fine that could be
assessed is capped at 0.1% of GDP – hardly a strong deterrent by
itself. This Treaty concerns only the framework for fiscal policy, i.e.
the rules setting up national ‘debt brakes’, not their implementa-
tion. This Treaty thus does not give any new powers to the Court
of Justice (neither to the Commission) to interfere with the actual
conduct of national fiscal policy. None of the provisions on eco-
nomic policy coordination are binding. Essentially they reiterate
the already often repeated statements of good intentions on struc-
tural reforms.


      Among the provisions, the specification on governance institu-
tes regular meetings, at least twice a year, of the heads of state and
government of the euro area. However, since these meetings will
remain informal, in truth, there was no need for an international
treaty to establish them.


      As far as the non-euro EU member states who signed the Treaty
are concerned, there is no obligation for them to do anything, but
the signature constitutes a political statement which gives them a
partial ‘seat at the table’ of the eurozone meetings, allowing them
to participate in most of the euro area summits.


      From a purely legal point of view, this Treaty contains an inhe-
rent contradiction: it implies that its signatory countries agree on


208
The Future of the Euro


binding constraints for their constitutional order via an ordinary
international treaty. In most countries the national constitution is
of a higher in legal hierarchy than international treaties. This
means that even the provisions on the ‘fiscal compact’ constitute
essentially a political statement, unless the treaty is ratified with a
constitutional majority, as will be done in Germany.


  The main value of this political statement coming from all euro
area member states is of course that it provides political cover for
the German government in its efforts to sell the euro rescue ope-
rations to a sceptical domestic audience. However, it is doubtful
that the ‘fiscal compact’ was really needed for this purpose. Data
on German support of the euro show that public opinion remains
much more constructive on the euro than widely assumed (see
Gros and Roth, 2011). Moreover even before the fiscal compact
existed, all votes in the Bundestag have resulted in very large majo-
rities in favour of the euro area rescue operations, even when they
contained large fiscal risks for Germany.


  In judging the value of this Treaty one should also keep in mind
that, of the four large euro area countries, three have already natio-
nal debt brakes at the constitutional level: in Germany it is already
operational, in Spain has been adopted recently and in Italy is in
course of adoption. In the fourth country, France, it is already clear
that the Treaty will be implemented, if at all given the negative
attitude of the current opposition, via a so-called ‘loi organique’ and
that the French constitution will not be changed.


                                                                    209
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


      All in all, the fiscal compact is probably useful in the long run
and may contribute to avert a future crisis. It forces Member States
to adopt stronger national fiscal frameworks at home. Some, per-
haps most, would have done so anyway under the pressure of the
markets, but it is unlikely that the new Treaty will make a signifi-
cant difference. The main danger is that that it has been oversold.


      It is likely that the ratification process (e.g. the referendum in
Ireland) and then the implementation process in some difficult
countries (e.g. France) will receive a lot of attention and create a
distorted impression of the importance of the Fiscal Compact.


      However, the initial excitement will be over once the national
fiscal rules have been put into place and this Treaty will quietly be
forgotten. Its only remaining impact will consist in the meetings of
the euro area heads of state which are likely to produce the regular
conclusions that ‘Member States commit’ to everything desirable
(structural reforms, etc.). Conclusions which become irrelevant
once the heads of state return to their capitals and their domestic
political realities.


      The experience with the SGP suggests that how this new ‘fiscal
compact’ will be applied in future will depend on the degree of con-
sensus on the need to balance the budget over the cycle. If anything,
political will to follow this balanced budget rule will be even more
important for the new ‘fiscal compact’ since it will take the form of
an intergovernmental Treaty outside the legal framework of the EU.


210
The Future of the Euro


  Today the consensus that only balancing budgets can solve this
crisis and allow the euro to survive seems strong and the position
of the German government seems particularly tough. This is cer-
tainly desirable to prevent future public debt problems but it
neglects the crucial role financial market fragility has played in this
crisis. The case of Greece is emblematic in this sense: despite
Greece accounts for less than 3% of the euro area’s GDP, the pros-
pect of the Greek government becoming bankrupt caused Europe’s
financial markets to go into a tailspin. The reason behind it was
the fragility of banks due to their undercapitalization and their
large holdings of government debt.


  In this perspective, while for a creditor country like Germany it
might be important that other member states are forced to copy its
balanced budget rules, it should be even more important to ensu-
re that financial regulation helps to provide additional incentives
for good fiscal policy and that financial markets become more
robust and able to withstand a sovereign insolvency. This is what
would reduce the need for future bail outs by the German govern-
ment. German savers have over the last decade of current account
surpluses accumulated about one trillion euro worth of claims on
other euro area countries. Safeguarding the value of these claims
(which amount to about 50% of GDP) and ensuring the future
German savings surpluses are invested with minimal risk should
thus be a key policy goal for German policy makers.




                                                                    211
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


       4. Fiscal indiscipline versus financial regulation inconsistency

             The key insight that has been overlooked in the official circles
       dominating EU policy making today is that today’s crisis is largely
       due to an inconsistency in the original design of EMU, not in the
       area of fiscal policy, but in the area of financial market regulation.
       Even after the start of the EMU, financial regulation in general, and
       banking regulation in particular, continued to be based on the
       assumption that in the euro area all government debt is riskless.
       This was from the start logically incompatible with the no-bail out
       clause in the Maastricht Treaty, which implies that a euro area
       member country can become insolvent, and the institution of an
       independent central bank which cannot monetize government
       debt. But it was adopted anyway, maybe because of the perception,
       expressed recently in a spectacularly mis-timed paper from the IMF,
       which proclaimed: “Default in Today's Advanced Economies:
       Unnecessary, Undesirable, and Unlikely”.7


             In the much more forgiving environment of the turn of the cen-
       tury, it was quite natural for policy makers to ignore the logical
       inconsistency between the no bail-out clause and maintaining the
       assumption that government was really risk less. Yet this contra-
       diction had two important consequences. First, banks did not (and
       still do not) have to hold any capital against their sovereign expo-



7 Cottarelli, C., L. Forni, J. Gottschalk, and P. Mauro (2010) Staff Position Note No.
2010/12.


       212
The Future of the Euro


sure. Second, it was also deemed unnecessary to impose any con-
centration limit on the claims any bank can hold on any one sove-
reign. This lack of a concentration limit for sovereign debt is in
clear contrast to the general rule that banks must keep their expo-
sure to any single name below 25% of their capital. This exception
would make sense only if government debt is really totally riskless.


   The main result of this special treatment reserved to govern-
ment debt securities on banks’ balance sheets has been that about
one third of all public debt of the eurozone is held by eurozone
financial institutions, which also tend to privilege the financing of
their own government. The fate of governments and banks is thus
tightly linked.


   To the inconsistency of financial market regulation it must be
added that the ECB failed to apply differentiated haircuts to
government debt it accepted as collateral. Debt securities issued by
euro area governments ware accepted in indiscriminate fashion
provided that the country was rated at investment grade. This was
the case for all euro area member countries, of Greece as Germany.
When the Stability Pact was weakened by Germany and France in
2005, the ECB took member countries to court, but it did not
change its collateral policy. By doing so it would have given a con-
crete signal that it was worried about the long run sustainability of
fiscal policy and its consequences for the future of the single
currency. Alas, it did not do so, not even during the crisis, after it
was clear that it was changing its policy stance. Only now, the ECB


                                                                    213
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


applies a sliding scale of graduated haircuts which makes it less
attractive for banks to hold lower rated government debt.


      The idea that governments provide the only safe assets even in
a monetary union where a no bail-out clause exists was also the
main reason for another omission: a common euro area (or EU)
deposit insurance scheme was never seriously considered. At EU
level, deposit insurance is regulated by the 1994 Directive on depo-
sit guarantee schemes, but the minimum harmonization approach
adopted at that time has proven largely insufficient and the ulti-
mate back up for all national schemes remains the national govern-
ment. A common European deposit insurance modeled on the US
approach of a fund financed ex-ante by risk based contributions
from banks like the Federal Deposit Insurance Company – FDIC-
would have had obvious advantages in terms of risk diversification.
But the preference for national solutions (based on the fear that a
European equivalent to the FDIC would lead to large transfers
across countries) and the bureaucratic interests of the existing
national deposit guarantee schemes ensured that such ideas do not
get a hearing even today.


      The experience with Greece should have served to rest the idea
that government debt in the euro area is riskless. But so far no cri-
sis summit has drawn the conclusion from this experience for ban-
king regulation. Of course, it is true that once the crisis has hit it is
no longer possible to tighten the rules on government debt becau-
se this is pro-cyclical as the mayhem which followed the only


214
The Future of the Euro


attempt to shore up the banking system in the context of the
recent EBA stress tests on government debt has shown.


   However in order to illustrate the importance of thinking about
the larger benefits from a different kind of banking regulation it is
still worthwhile speculating what would have been different if
banking regulation had been ‘Maastricht’ conform, i.e. if it had
recognized that belonging to the European Monetary Union
implies that national government debt is no longer riskless.


   One could thus consider how the crisis would have played out
if the following rules had applied since 1999:
i) Forcing banks to have capital against their holdings of euro area
   government debt.
ii) Applying the normal concentration limits also to government
   exposure.
iii) A different collateral policy of the ECB, for example with a sli-
   ding scale of increasing haircuts on government debt in func-
   tion of the country’s deficit and debt and its position in the
   excessive deficit procedure.


   One can only speculate what would have been different if this
kind of regulation had been in place during the boom years. But a
few conclusions seem certain.




                                                                   215
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


      Greece would certainly have encountered much more difficul-
ties selling its bonds to banks which would have had to hold capi-
tal against it would be less able to use them to access ECB funds.
The same applies to Italy, whose rating went already in 2006 below
the threshold at which under normal banking rules higher capital
requirements kick in. Both these countries would thus have seen
gradually increasing market signals, which would have most pro-
bably led to a more prudent fiscal policy.


      Moreover, their problems would today have been much easier
to deal with because banks would have more capital and the con-
centration limit would have prevented Greek banks to accumulate
Greek government debt worth several times their capital. The
resources necessary to prevent the collapse of the Greek banking
system has increased considerably (by about 40 to 50 billion euro)
the size of the financial support Greece needed so far.


      The negative feedback loop between the drop in the value of
banks and in the yields on government bonds which destabilized the
entire European banking system so much during the summer and fall
of 2011 would also have been very much mitigated if the concentra-
tion limit had been observed. Italian banks would have accumulated
less Italian debt and would have been able to offset some of the mark
to market losses on the Italian debt with their gains on German debt
holdings which they would have had to hold as well.




216
The Future of the Euro


   Common euro area wide deposit insurance would have contri-
buted in several ways to deal with the financial crisis from the
beginning. First of all, in 2008 it would have obviated the percei-
ved need for the competitive rush to provide national guarantees
for bank deposits. The Irish government would thus probably not
have had felt the need to provide the blanket guarantee for all lia-
bilities of its local banks which proved fatal once the extent of the
losses was revealed.


   Ireland would still have suffered from a massive real estate bust
with all the consequences in terms of unemployment, but the Irish
government would not have been bankrupted by its own banks.
Paul Krugman has drawn attention to the parallels in terms of eco-
nomic fundamentals between Nevada and Ireland8 arguing that
explicit fiscal transfers and higher labour mobility within the US
constitute the main differences. However, Ireland has actually
experienced a degree of labour mobility which is quite similar to
that among US states like Nevada. During the boom it had immi-
gration running at over 1% of its population, which after the bust
turned into emigration of a similar order of magnitude. The wides-
pread held opinion that the euro could never work because there is
not enough labour mobility in Europe is not entirely correct.


   In the case of Ireland the key issue was not one of a lack of labor
mobility, but of the absence of a common safety net for banks. A


8 See http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/12/29/ireland-nevada/.



                                                                       217
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


European deposit insurance would have provided stability to the
deposit base. It is also likely that the European Deposit insurance
would have been less complacent and less beholden to the inte-
rests of Irish banks and would thus have started to increase its risk
premium when the signs of a local real estate bubble were clear to
almost everybody outside the country.


      Greece, where the national deposit guarantee scheme is now
practically worthless because it is backed up only by the Greek
government, which has just defaulted on its debt, provides anot-
her example of the potential importance of stabilizing the banking
system. With a European deposit guarantee scheme there would
have been no deposit flight, which has amounted so far to about
50 billion, or over 25% of GDP. There would have thus been much
less need for the ECB to refinance the Greek banking system, lowe-
ring again the cost of the Greek bail out.


      The next crisis will be different from the current crisis, but it is
clear that different rules for the banking system could bring two
advantages: they would provide graduated market based signals
against excessive deficits and debts. Moreover, a better capitalized
banking system with less concentrated risks would be much better
able to absorb a sovereign insolvency, thus reducing the need for
future bail outs. Acting on this front seems a much more promi-
sing route to reduce the likelihood for future crises and minimize
the cost should they occur anyway.




218
The Future of the Euro


   Perceptions matter. Europe’s policy makers seem to be driven by
the perception that this crisis was caused by excessively lax fiscal
policy in some countries. In reality, however, the public debt pro-
blems of some countries have become a systemic, area wide, finan-
cial crisis because of the fragility of the European banking system.
The ‘euro’ crisis is likely to fester until this fundamental problem
has been tackled decisively.




5. A proposal for a new regulatory treatment of sovereign
debt securities in the euro area

   The purpose of this section is to sketch a simple proposal for a
new regulatory treatment of sovereign debt securities in the euro
area which follows the arguments illustrated in the previous sec-
tions.
1. Any risk weights to be introduced after the crisis might better be
   based on ‘objective’ criteria, rather than ratings.
2. Diversification of banks’ exposure; this is even more important
   than risk weighting for sovereign exposure.


   A simple way to attach a risk weight on government debt secu-
rities of a given country would be to make the weight function of
objective factors like the debt and deficit of the country. For exam-
ple, one could imagine that the risk weight could remain at zero if
both government debt and fiscal deficit relative to GDP remain
below 60% and 3% respectively. If the deficit and/or the debt ratio


                                                                   219
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


exceed the ‘reference’ values of the Treaty, the risk weight would
increase by certain percentage points in a proportional or progres-
sive fashion. In addition the risk weights should be linked to the
stages of the excessive deficit procedure (EDP). When the procedu-
re is launched, the risk weight is increased and at each additional
stage of the EDP the risk weighting would be increased further. This
would provide the EDP with real incentives even without the need
to impose fines.


      Introducing positive risk weights for government debt will not
be enough to prevent crisis because of the ‘lumpiness’ of sovereign
risk. Experience has shown that sovereign defaults are rare events;
but the losses are typically very large (above 50%) when default
does materialize. Even with a risk weight of 100% banks would
have capital only to cover losses of 8%. Risk weights would thus
have to become extremely high before they could protect banks
against realistic loss given default scenarios. This suggests that the
more important aspect is diversification.


      All regulated investors, i.e. banks, insurance companies, invest-
ment funds, pension funds, have rules which limit their exposure
vis-à-vis a given counterpart to a fraction of their total investment
or capital (for banks). However, this limit does not apply to sove-
reign debt, especially within the eurozone for banks. The result of
this lack of exposure limits has been that, in the periphery, banks
have too much debt of their own government on their balance
sheet which has led to the deadly feedback loop between sovereign


220
The Future of the Euro


and banks. In Northern Europe, investors, such as investment
funds and life insurance companies, which typically cannot avoid
government debt have also concentrated their holdings nationally.
This has led to a significant fall and in some cases even to negati-
ve value of government bond yields, not only in Germany but
throughout Northern Europe. From the point of view of core
Europe investors, today this might appear as being a prudent stra-
tegy, but this concentration increases the vulnerability of the sys-
tem to any reversal of fortunes. Moreover, if Northern investors
were required to diversify their holdings there would be a natural
demand for Southern European bonds, which would bring some
oxygen to those governments which have experienced a dramatic
surge in their borrowing cost.


   Introducing exposure limits during a crisis period would be
much less pro-cyclical than introducing capital requirements. In
practical terms, the simplest approach would be to grandfather the
existing stocks, but apply exposure limits to new investments.




6. Conclusions

   This paper has emphasized that while the political agenda has
been obsessively focusing on fiscal issues since the early onset of
the euro zone crisis; this crisis has neither a mere fiscal nature nor
an exclusively fiscal solution. Despite the Greek episode seemed to
point only to fiscal indiscipline, the reasons why the crisis did not


                                                                   221
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


confined itself to Greece but spread out to the entire euro area assu-
ming a systemic nature should be sought in the state of the euro
area banking sector. European banks were, and still are, largely
undercapitalized and too tightly linked to the fortune and the mis-
fortune of governments.


      The paper spots three contradictory building blocks of the EMU
construction: the no bail-out rule in the Stability and Growth Pact,
the independence of the European central bank and the provision
in the financial market regulation framework that government
bonds are considered as risk free assets. The combination of the no-
bail clause with the institution of an independent central bank
implies that fiscally undisciplined countries may have to face
default as no other country, nor the EU can take on its debt and the
central bank cannot monetize it. This definitely collides with the
principle that banks are not required to hold any capital against
government debt securities as it assumed that they do not carry
any default risk. In fact, Greece has proved this assumption wrong.


      This contradiction was completely overlooked during the good
years in the turn of the new century and the politically more con-
venient approach suggested by financial regulation became the
dominant. The ‘risk free treatment’ of public debt securities has clearly
worked as incentive for banks to finance profitable government
spending and accumulate large amounts of government bonds.




222
The Future of the Euro


   This is at the root of the common fate of euro area banks and
governments. Alas, the crisis has made that fate an evil one.


   Though these contradictory elements have now emerged clearly,
the issue has not been addressed and the regulator treatment of the
government bonds has not changed yet.


   On this ground, the paper puts forward some concrete ideas
about how to break the tight linkage between governments and
banks, which represents a decisive obstacle to overcome of the
euro zone crisis.


   We argue that positive risk weights for government debt securi-
ties must be introduced in the banks’ balance sheet, but alone this
measure will not be enough to prevent a new crisis. A clear pres-
cription to reduce concentration of the risk and impose diversifi-
cation is at least equally important and complementary to the risk
weighting.


   While developing the arguments for the regulatory changes, the
paper expresses skepticism about the official, widespread view that
the just signed fiscal compact will have a crucial role in overco-
ming the eurozone crisis. As far as the banking sector remains weak
and highly exposed to governments, and the common fate of
government and banks is not broken, the crisis will be hard to die.




                                                                 223
Breaking the common fate of banks and governments


Bibliography

- Cottarelli C., L. Forni, J. Gottschalk and P. Mauro (2010), “Default
in Today's Advanced Economies: Unnecessary, Undesirable, and
Unlikely”, IMF Staff Position Note No. 2010/12.


- Graber M. And D. Folkerts-Landa (1992) The European Central
Bank: A bank of a Monetary Policy Rule, NBER Working Paper
N.4016.


- Giavazzi, F. and M. Pagano (1988), “The advantage of tying one's
hands: EMS discipline and Central Bank credibility”, European
Economic     Review,     Vol.   32,   No.   5,   June,   pp    1055-1075
(http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0014292188900657).


- Gros, D., T. Mayer and A. Ubide (2004), The Nine Lives of the
Stability Pact, Special Report of the CEPS Macroeconomic Policy
Group, CEPS, Brussels, February (http://www.ceps.eu/book/nine-
lives-stability-pact).


- Gros D. and F. Roth (2011) Do Germans support the euro? CEPS
Working Paper Document No. 359, December 2011.


- Gros D. (2012), The misdiagnosed debt crisis, Current History,
Vol.111, Issue 773 p.83.




224
The Future of the Euro


- Gros D. (2012), The Treaty on Stability, Coordination and
Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union (aka Fiscal
Compact), CEPS Commentary, March 2012.


- Padoa Schipppa T. (1994), The Road to the Monetary Union: The
Emperor, the King and Genies, Clarendon Press. Place of
Publication: Oxford.




                                                              225
226
/RICARDO MARTÍNEZ RICO * /




       The fiscal institution in the Economic
                        and Monetary Union:
                    the contribution of Spain




1. Introduction; 2. Evolution of the fiscal policies in Europe and Spain;
3. Analysis of the relationship between fiscal rigour, macroeconomic sta-
bility and growth; 4. Next steps in the Fiscal Institution of the Economic
and Monetary Union: the necessary contribution of Spain; 5. Conclusion




1. Introduction

    The current financial crisis in the European Union (EU) has
highlighted the importance of establishing a common framework



* Public Sector economist, on leave, and Founding Partner, President and CEO of Equipo
Económico, S.L. He has held office as Deputy Finance Minister Working inside the team
of the Deputy Prime Minister, Rodrigo Rato, and Finance Minister, Cristóbal Montoro.
Graduate cum laude in Business Administration at the University of Zaragoza, he stu-
dies in the Deutsche Schule of Bilbao and Valencia. He has attended postgraduate cour-
ses at the London School of Economics, Kennedy School at Harvard University and
Wharton Business School.


                                                                          227
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                        the contribution of Spain

which enables the economic agents to act in a macroeconomic sce-
nario of stability and confidence in the coming years.


      In this crisis situation, once again the discussion has sparked
the debate in Europe of whether the necessary fiscal stability,
which will demand the rationalisation of public spending in the
member states, will be achieved at the expense of prolonging the
crisis and limiting economic growth possibilities. However, there
should be no dilemma between sustainability of public accounts
and medium term economic growth. The crisis of the European
sovereign debt is a consequence of overspending and debt which
the markets are not prepared to fund. In this regard, the only
recourse is a fiscal policy designed to mitigate the harsh effects of
the crisis and boost economic growth within the framework of
macroeconomic stability, continuous supervision over the sustai-
nability of public sector accounts and economic reforms.


      Spain must cease to be a burden for Europe and once again
become a driver of growth. Compliance with a route of plausible
cuts in public spending in all Public Administrations is a necessary
condition to do so, though not the only. As previously shown, in
the case of the Spanish economy, stability and reforms make up the
formula required to revitalize investment, consumption and job
creation. Thus, economic reforms and budgetary discipline are
equally important.




228
The Future of the Euro


   The Spanish case is a clear example of a solid and plausible bud-
getary institution, where the principle of subsidiarity enables each
government with sound finances to tackle its internal decisions in
accordance with its economic and social reality (not only because
of its significance from a regulatory perspective but also because of
the parallels between the European scenario relative to the coun-
tries and the Spanish scenario relative to the Autonomous
Communities). At the same time, those who are forced to ask for
help must abide by the ensuing conditionality.


   In Europe, likewise, the need for greater economic and mone-
tary integration must take us along the path of clear fiscal rules. But
it must also do so to encouraging income transmission mechanisms
between countries and regions, availability of financial resources
and support by way of providing the necessary liquidity to face
emergency situations and the pooling of risks, always in exchange
for strong sets of conditions to prevent moral hazard. Moreover,
within the monetary and economic union the imbalances must be
addressed, not only of highly indebted countries, but also those
with surplus balances. In some way, it must be recovered an incen-
tive system to ensure political commitment and compliance with
goals set. Nowadays, the fiscal institution1 is a basic component of
European and Spanish economic policy.

1 González Páramo defines it as "the rules which govern the preparation of the budgets, their
debate and approval in parliament, execution and subsequent control”. "Costs and benefits of fis-
cal discipline: the Law of Fiscal Stability in perspective” (Costes y beneficios de la disciplina fis-
cal: la Ley de Estabilidad presupuestaria en perspectiva), J.M. González-Páramo, 2001.



                                                                                        229
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

      Throughout this work we shall examine, in first place, how the
sustainability of the public finances requires a solid fiscal institu-
tion and a firm political commitment by the different European
governments. Only on the basis of the conviction of the benefits of
this statement can one contribute towards the construction of a
stronger Europe.


      Then we shall go on to examine the close relationship between
fiscal rigour, macroeconomic stability and growth, arriving at the
conclusion that the establishment of simple, transparent, automati-
cally applied rules with preventive control mechanisms for all
Public Administrations is essential for this ‘positive’ interrelation.
All these components are basic for the design of a fiscal policy
which helps to recover the credibility that Europe needs in its path
towards greater integration to face the sovereign debt crisis.


      In the last chapter we shall examine the measures taken in Europe
and in Spain since the start of the sovereign debt crisis, and we shall
reflect on the following steps to be taken in support of the budgetary
institution. Then close with the appropriate conclusions.




2. Evolution of fiscal policy in Europe and Spain

  The European political integration project came about in the
post World War years, as an extension of the economic integration
process. This was envisaged by one of the founding fathers of the


230
The Future of the Euro


current Union, Jean Monnet. In 1950, he proposed the creation of
a space of peace and prosperity for Europe, via the formation of the
European Coal and Steel Community, which became a reality a
year later. His way of conceiving the European construction as a
project made up of very specific steps – beginning with the eco-
nomy – is the way to understand many of the milestones that
Europe has achieved in the last sixty years. Examples of this have
been the creation of the European Economic Communities, the
launch of the European Monetary System, the creation of the sin-
gle European market and the firm commitment that has led to the
Economic and Monetary Union (EMU).


  During the first decades of the European unification project,
Spain was but a mere observer, although fully embraced the inte-
gration process along the same lines and endorsed the way of tra-
velling the path towards a united Europe. Thus, in the mid-1980s,
Spain understood that the current EU offered a chance to take a
decisive step in its integration into an international market which
would bring gains in efficiency, reinforce macroeconomic stability
and contribute to the increase of wealth and per capita income.
That would lead to the development and modernisation of the
country. And, indeed, this was the case in the first years, where eco-
nomic growth rate of Spain was positive over that of the EU, by a
maximum of 3pp in 1987 (see Chart 1). However, as of this time,
macroeconomic instability driven by an expansive fiscal policy,
became a burden for economic growth and job creation, and gene-
rated a fast and continuous rise in public debt. The importance of


                                                                   231
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                              the contribution of Spain

having a solid fiscal institution in the economic development of
the Spanish economy became patently clear.



      Chart 1
      Year-on-year growth in real GDP in Spain and in the European Union




      Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with data from the International Monetary
      Fund



  After the repeated failures of the European Monetary System star-
ted up in 1979, and the progress of the approval of the Single
European Act (1986) in favour of an internal market, the EU mem-
ber states took an additional step in Maastricht. EU member states
support, via the adoption of the Treaty on the European Union
(TEU) (1992), the creation of an Economic and Monetary Union,
whose third phase would entail the launch of the single currency,
the Euro. Title VIII of the Maastricht Treaty set three main axes
around which the design of the EMU should be built around: sin-


232
The Future of the Euro


gle monetary policy, fiscal policies subject to common rules and
coordination mechanisms for the remaining economic policies. A
clear view of establishing nominal convergence mechanisms based
on the fiscal institution was already existent at that stage, founded
on the following common rules: absolute ban on monetary funding
of public deficits, no liability held by the EU or by any other State
in regard to debts acquired by another member state, and the set-
ting of limits on deficit (3%) and public debt (60%). As of 1997, the
Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) introduce stricter rules with a defi-
cit target of balance or surplus, supported by an early alert system
and a disciplinary penalty structure designed to correct deviations.


  For Spain the commitment to meet the convergence criteria esta-
blished in the TEU for eligibility for the third phase of the EMU
demanded a radical change to be made in our fiscal policy. Europe
then began to act as an anchor in Spanish budgetary policy.
However, even when the worst of the recession was over for Spain,
governments continued to face enormous difficulties in balancing
the budget in the pursuit of macroeconomic stability.


  It would not be until the political change of 1996, and with the
reference and encouragement arising from the creation of the sin-
gle currency, when the necessary fiscal consolidation was finally
tackled, that macroeconomic stability was achieved and the bases
for a new economic growth phase were put in place. The starting
point was poor, in 1995 with a deficit around 7% of the GDP and a
growing public indebtedness which reached 67% in 1996.


                                                                   233
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                               the contribution of Spain

Although the level of indebtedness was lower than the average for
the EU, in the case of Spain the combination of the primary defi-
cit, the high cost of financing of the debt and the recession had
rendered unsustainable the growing public debt. As of that time
there was a change in fiscal policy, which took on a markedly coun-
ter-cyclical approach. As shown in chart 2, an ambitious fiscal con-
solidation programme was implemented which allowed the annual
budgets to close with primary surpluses from 1996 until the end of
the period and to slow down the growth trend in public debt
which, after peaking in 1996, dropped by more than 20pp of GDP
until 2004.


      Chart 2
      Evolution of income and expenditure of Public Administrations and of their budget
      balances




      Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with data from the Ministry of Finance and
      Public Administrations



234
The Future of the Euro


   During the period, the fiscal consolidation drive contributed
towards a strong growth in GDP (average rate of 3.6 between 1996
and 2004), which helped reducing debt stock via the positive spre-
ad between the economic growth rates and interest rates. The suc-
cess in the change of direction in fiscal policy was due to a firm
political commitment, a well-designed fiscal consolidation pro-
gramme and a substantial reform of the fiscal institution.2


   For countries that, like Spain, managed to take part in its foun-
dation and for others which joined subsequently – such as the case
of Greece which, with the support of Germany and despite not
meeting at the time the requirements established by the Maastricht
Treaty, became part of the Eurozone two years later – the incorpo-
ration to the euro meant the relinquishment of monetary policy in
favour of the European Central Bank (ECB). And this total integra-
tion in the establishment of monetary policy has fostered greater
price stability during these years. On the other hand, this relin-
quishment made budgetary policy, along with economic liberalisa-
tion policies, into the main economic policy instruments in each of
the Eurozone member countries.


   We must highlight that, once the objective of forming part of
the euro was met in full, Spain took an additional step beyond what
was required in Maastricht. And, in line with the principles agreed

2 “The Spanish fiscal institution: from the Stability Pact to the rules of fiscal stability” (La
institución presupuestaria española: del Pacto de Estabilidad a las reglas de estabilidad
pre¬supuestaria), R. Martínez Rico (2005).


                                                                                   235
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                       the contribution of Spain

in the SGP, it rounded off the fiscal consolidation effort with a deep
reform of the fiscal institution. As a result thereof, the approval of
the fiscal stability laws (the General Law on Fiscal Stability and the
Organic Law additional thereto) brought about a change in the
budgeting process. This mainly consisted of: the definition of a fis-
cal stability target (fiscal balance) in the medium term for all Public
Administrations; for the State, a non-financial expenditure limit,
the so-called expenditure ceiling, was applied following parliamen-
tary approval during the first half of the year; as a novelty, the
Contingency Fund was added into the State budget, as a flexibility
component during the life of the budget which removes the need
for making fiscal adjustments, equal to 2% of the non-financial
expenditure ceiling approved by Parliament. The approval of the
Fiscal Stability Laws was further completed with a new General
Fiscal Law and a new General Subsidies Law. Specifically, the
General Fiscal Law aimed at achieving greater rationalisation of the
fiscal process, whereas the General Subsidies Law, on its part, aimed
at transferring the governing principles of Fiscal Stability Laws (effi-
ciency, transparency and multi-annual framework) to the expendi-
ture on subsidies (which would mean 20% of expenditure budget).


      However, in 2005, the European process of integration and
reform came to a halt. The solution provided to the reiterated vio-
lations of the 3% limit on public deficit established at Maastricht –
and following the pressure exerted by Germany and France in this
regard, backed by the European Commission – was none other
than the SGP, introducing greater discretionary power and taking a


236
The Future of the Euro


step back in the capacity of the fiscal institution to contribute to
growth.


   Along the same lines, with a comfortable fiscal position and
with the same philosophy as that of the reform of the SGP, Spain in
2006 approved a reform to render the fiscal and Territorial
Administration funding processes more flexible, which is the sour-
ce of our current fiscal crisis. The relaxation of fiscal stability led to
a loss of transparency in its application as a result of the flexible
new rules.


  With the outbreak of the international financial crisis as of 2008,
the primary surplus of the first years of the period quickly ran out.
Discretionary expenditure decisions, the impact of automatic sta-
bilisers and the major errors in revenue estimates led to a deficit
balance, which worsened over two years (from 2007 to 2009) by
13pp of GDP. This deterioration, which had also taken place in the
rest of EU members, was more notable in Spain due to its speed and
magnitude (see Chart 3), with few comparable examples within the
scope of the OECD (except for the cases of Iceland or Ireland). The
deficit fiscal position generated a fast increase in public debt, lea-
ding to doubts about sustainability thereof, and translating into
significant rises in the risk premium of the country.


   At the start of 2010, given the lack of confidence displayed by
international markets, and in light of the fast deterioration of
public finances, the previous Government was forced to implement


                                                                       237
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                              the contribution of Spain

      Chart 3
      Budget balance in 2006 and change in budget balance in 2007-2009




      Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with OECD data



a radical change in its fiscal policy and announce a fiscal consoli-
dation programme.


      The sovereign debt crisis, which especially affects several of the
“peripheral” member states of the Eurozone (but which has also
affect countries such as France and Austria), has highlighted the
need to reinforce the budgetary coordination mechanisms within
the EMU. In the face of the problems arising from the sovereign


238
The Future of the Euro


debt crisis and as a result of the fluctuations in the risk premiums
of the Eurozone member states, a double reinforcement movement
of the budgetary crisis has taken place from Brussels since the onset
of the crisis. On the one hand, that implemented by the European
Commission, the result of which is, for instance, the legislative pac-
kage comprising five regulations and one directive designed to rein-
force the preventive part and the disciplinary part of EC mecha-
nisms. On the other, that of the member states which, via the
European Council, have brought about agreements such as the
Fiscal Pact, which seeks to guarantee that all countries will commit
to fiscal stability under the highest level of regulation. The reform
enacted last year of the Spanish Constitution must be understood
within the framework of this new drive from Europe in support of
the fiscal institution. The reform, as we shall discuss further in this
paper, guarantees the principle of fiscal stability via the highest ran-
king law.


   Despite efforts invested, and despite the positive effect of the
liquidity injections made by the ECB, the current economic scena-
rio in Europe continues to be marked by the risk premiums of EU
peripheral countries, which continue to be too high. The questions
as to the capacity of such countries to meet their debt commit-
ments have burdened economic European Union results over the
last two years. This has led the Commission to forecast a drop in
GDP for all of the EU of -0.5% for this year, which sets it back in
terms of the growth of the world economy. Although it must be
said, that all countries are not behaving in the same way. Germany,


                                                                     239
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

for instance, closed last year with 3% growth, expecting to do so
this year at 0.6%, whereas Italy will experience a drop of around -
1.3% of GDP. From a growth perspective, there is an important dif-
ference between northern and southern European countries arising
from the financial crisis. However, it is worth remembering the
strong interdependence between all member states, including
Germany (second country in the world in terms of export volume,
of which 60% are directed to the EU).


      On its part, the Spanish economy is clearly included in the “slo-
wer” group, at an extremely difficult time. In recent months, the
return to recession, which accumulates after four years of crisis, the
adverse effect on employment and on businesses, has led to a 24%
unemployment rate. At the same time, there is high external debt,
exceeding 160% of the GDP, with a high accumulation of public and
private debt maturities this year. All these factors have led to a risk
premium of around 340 basis points in the last few months and, more
recently, well above 450 basis points, and to be closely watched by the
markets, that is to say, our creditors. Given this scenario, in 2012, the
Spanish economy faces challenges associated with its macroeconomic
imbalances yet to be corrected, as well as the potential problems ari-
sing from a new challenge from international financial markets. In
this framework, we expect a drop in GDP during the first quarters,
and although its performance will improve towards the end of the
year, it will result in an overall drop in GDP of around -1.5% this year.
Meanwhile, the reality experienced by the rest of the world is diffe-
rent, with a world economy growth rate of around 3.5% of GDP.


240
The Future of the Euro


  Undoubtedly, the unemployment rate is our main negative dif-
ferentiating factor compared to all other EU members and the main
concern for Spanish society. As a result of the economic crisis, no
country in the OECD has experienced a downturn in the jobless
rate as negative as ours. Our rate of unemployment has gone from
8.3% of active population in 2007 to almost 24% at the end of
2011. The crisis has highlighted the problem with our employment
model, as our economy is adjusted by means of redundancies ins-
tead of by adding greater flexibility to employment conditions.


   Despite the gradual correction of the external imbalance (the
current account deficit has been reduced from 10% of GDP recor-
ded for 2007 to less than 4% in 2011), Spain continues to be signi-
ficantly reliant on foreign funding (around 40,000M€ per annum).
The need for funds shown by the current account deficit, cannot in
fact be met by attracting foreign investment to our country.
Indeed, the opposite is the case, with recent years witnessing a
divestment process, particularly of portfolio assets. The forecast
drop in the GDP combined with the high level of debt, puts the
sustainability of our funding at risk. Given such conditions, the cri-
sis is requiring a must faster deleveraging process than that initially
expected.


   Since the common denominator of the European sovereign debt
crisis is insufficient GDP growth, only by articulating the reforms
in Europe and in Spain in an expedient and firm manner can the
current increasing loss of confidence by financial markets be sta-


                                                                    241
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                          the contribution of Spain

lled. In the case of the Spanish economy, this is a path which we
travelled successfully in the second half of the nineties, when
Spain took part in the foundation of the euro and then went on to
lead the fiscal consolidation process in Europe. The new govern-
ment seems to have understood this, having begun reforms in
three main areas: sustainability of the public finances and moder-
nisation of the public sector, the restructuring and reorganization
of the financial sector and the reform of the labour market. In the
coming years, political commitment to fiscal rigour, macroecono-
mic stability and growth must go hand in hand in Spain and
Europe, and happen in parallel.




3. Analysis of the relationship between fiscal rigour, macroe-
conomic stability and growth

      In the context described in the previous section, fiscal consolida-
tion within the EMU is a fundamental tool for recovering macroeco-
nomic stability, the confidence of economic players and the path to
growth, leading in turn to job creation.


      Moreover, the balance in public finances provides the econo-
mies participating in the monetary union, which therefore cannot
resort to instruments such as currency rates, with greater leeway to
deal with external shocks, enabling the implementation of anti-
cyclical policies and of automatic stabilisers.




242
The Future of the Euro


   At the same time, as has been amply studied in the literature,3
fiscal balance fosters a macroeconomic stability scenario which pro-
vides a more efficient framework for the development of economic
activity. The reduction in the deficit increases the confidence of
savers and investors. This translates into a stimulus for investment
and job creation, as well as allowing households and businesses to
plan the purchase of durable goods in the long term, thus leading to
sustained consumption, which is a key factor of economic growth.


   One of the most relevant aspects is the stronger credibility of the
economic policy and the improvement in the funding terms of the
economies in the international markets, thanks to the reduction of
the risk premium, which in turn leads to a drop in financial costs,
as shown in Chart 4 in the case of Spain as of 1996. The subjection
of European monetary and fiscal policies to certain rules, and the
assumption thereof by Spain as a participant in the foundation of
the Euro, helped to provide additional credibility to the govern-
ment’s fiscal consolidation strategy. This strategy was strengthened
by the regulatory reforms introduced by said government as we dis-
cussed in the previous section. This positive impact4 on the expec-
tations and on the confidence of economic agents explains the
sharp drop in long term interest rates, compared to the 10 year
German bond. The spread in the Spanish risk premium was actually
zeroed as of 2003.

3 “Fiscal policy and long-run growth”, V. Tanzi and H. Zee, 1997.
4 “The Spanish economic model 1996-2004” (El modelo económico español 1996-2004), L.
Bernaldo de Quirós and R. Martínez Rico, 2005.



                                                                              243
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                                  the contribution of Spain

             However, since 2008, with the arrival of the international finan-
       cial crisis, the macroeconomic imbalances accumulated by the
       Spanish economy led to the opposite effect. Furthermore, as a
       result of the degradation of Spanish public finances between 2003
       and 2009, as shown in the aforementioned graph 3, and the doubts
       in regard to the sustainability of the Spanish public debt, the risk
       premium increased once again in a significant way as of 2010, now
       reaching the 450 base point mark.


             The significance of fiscal consolidation as a tool for the recovery
       of stability and long term growth has also been proven in practice
       in many successful fiscal adjustment processes implemented in the
       last decades in certain European countries, such as Spain (1996-
       2004), Ireland (1982-1989) or Sweden and Finland (1993-2000),
       some of which have been studied in depth in the literature.5


             The most successful process was the one implemented in
       Finland between 1993 and 2000, which managed to reduce pri-
       mary expenditure by 14pp of GDP. This was mainly based on per-
       sonnel cost containment, reduction in transfers from the Central
       Administration to Local Corporations and the pursuit of efficiency
       in social expenditure, particularly in health services, education and
       pensions. Moreover, the fiscal institution underwent a reform with
       the introduction of expenditure ceilings, which proved to be a key



5 "Fiscal expansions and adjustments in OECD countries", A. Alesina y R. Perotti, 1995. “An
Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Adjustments", C. McDermott & R. Wescott, 1996.



       244
The Future of the Euro


tool for cost containment. At the same time, the pension system,
the labour market and the financial system underwent a structural
reform. The only expenditure programme that was deliberately
maintained, thus keeping its 1% share of the GDP, was that of
Research and Development.


   The Swedish experience between 1993 and 2000 obtained similar
results in terms of a reduction in primary expenditure (14% GDP),
which led to the attainment of fiscal balance in 1997, having closed
financial year 1993 with a deficit of 12.9%. In contrast with Finland,



   Chart 4
   Evolution of risk premium




   Source: Financial Times




                                                                   245
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

in Sweden the fiscal consolidation took place due to both the cut in
expenditure and the increase in revenue through a tax rise, while
also implementing simultaneous structural reforms such as the pri-
vatisation of public corporations and the liberalisation of the labour
market. Public spending was reduced by 16pp of GDP over a seven
year period, mainly through a reduction of the expenses in transfers
and benefits (including unemployment benefits) and a reduction in
personnel and current costs of all public administrations. The intro-
duction of three-year expenditure ceilings and annual productivity
targets must be added to such measures.


      The starting point of all the above was the strict cut in primary
expenditure, as the basis for the adjustment process, mainly cen-
tred     on   personnel    costs,    transfers     and     health     services.
Undoubtedly, a key factor in all such measures is that they were
done hand in hand with important structural reforms, particularly
those implemented in the labour market, the fiscal system and the
privatisations. Those allowed the adjustment process consolidation
and the increase in potential growth, on the basis of a firm politi-
cal commitment. Furthermore, it helped proved that fiscal consoli-
dation strategies based on spending cuts are more enduring and
promote a better economic performance than those based on reve-
nue increase.


      Experience has likewise proven that fiscal consolidation cannot
be maintained in the medium term without a proper fiscal institu-
tion articulation. As shown in the previous section, from the start,


246
The Future of the Euro


the construction of Europe has been evolving towards a greater
relinquishment of national policies in favour of European ones. It
is a slow and complicated process in which political divergences
often prevail over the overall view of what this process means. This
relinquishment has meant the need for greater autonomy in the
establishment of rules and objectives, as has been the case, for ins-
tance, with monetary policy. Aside from the current supervision
problems, it is clear that the role of the ECB in regard to price con-
trol has been a success. This example should be transferred to the
fiscal policy as a source of inspiration to maintain the necessary
political commitment and thus achieve effective fiscal coordina-
tion in the Eurozone.


   We live in an open economy, where freedom of movement of
persons, goods, capital, information and technology are necessary
conditions for improvement of competitiveness and economic
development. A globalised market, with a high level of competi-
tion, but also great opportunities, requires a disciplined, foreseea-
ble and transparent behaviour by the countries, designed to gene-
rate confidence among economic agents. The EMU was born out of
this perspective although there have been mechanisms, or even
relevant design components, which have failed.


   In general, The European construction has been preceded by the
establishment of rules seeking to limit the risks of integration. The
problem has arisen from the lack of rigour in compliance with such
rules, probably as result of the insufficient clarity of the rules and


                                                                    247
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                                 the contribution of Spain

       of political leadership committed to integration. When this hap-
       pens, it is easier to interpret the situation in one’s own favour, par-
       ticularly when high political power is held. Therefore, it is impor-
       tant to have clear and simple rules, in order to reduce the possibili-
       ties of interpretation and to help control subsequent compliance.


          At the same time, the establishment of preventing rules to ena-
       ble the anticipation of sharp increases in public deficit, should be
       articulated via a greater participation by the EU in the preparation
       of national budgets, in line with the latest legislative proposals of
       the European Commission on the matter. Preliminary control is a
       guarantee of compliance and greater co-responsibility with Brussels,
       which should in turn lead to better access to European funding.


          According to economic literature,6 those countries exerting con-
       siderable effort to achieve fiscal consolidation amid a context of
       economic uncertainty, should design and announce the establish-
       ment of a fiscal rule within a reasonable period of time designed to
       improve credibility. In the case of Spain, this step has been taken by
       way of the reform of section 135 of the Constitution, a historical
       event of special political relevance.


          In our case, constitutional reform has managed to raise to the
       level of fundamental Law – a relevant issue in our highly decentra-
       lised State – the commitment of all the Administrations to fiscal


6 “Fiscal Rules – anchoring expectations for sustainable public finances”, FMI, 2009.


       248
The Future of the Euro


sustainability. The approval of this reform has meant the recogni-
tion of the benefits of fiscal discipline, having assumed the flaws in
the relaxation of the Stability Laws in 2006 as well as the need to
provide a new common legal framework for all of the public sector.
Except for force majeure cases (natural disasters or emergency
situations), compliance with the limits on public debt and fiscal
balance set by the EU are guaranteed. Likewise, priority is given to
servicing the debt in the budget, a condition which helps build the
necessary confidence in lenders, and is an appropriate antidote for
preventing the loss of confidence in Eurozone countries.


   The reform also established the need for articulation in a new
organic Law, designed, on the one hand, to regulate the distribu-
tion   of   deficit   and    debt   limits    between     the   various
Administrations, the exceptional cases of surpluses therein, and
the means and terms for correction of any deviations in one or the
other that might take place. On the other hand, it had to establish
the methodology and procedure for calculation of structural defi-
cit. It is important that the calculation methodology respects the
procedure used in the EU, to provide discipline and transparency
to the fiscal process and help in the statement of accounts. The cal-
culation rule must be clear, and serve to consolidate fiscal discipli-
ne, as a permanent long term commitment. Lastly, it must esta-
blish the responsibility of the Administrations in the event of fai-
lure to achieve fiscal stability targets. In this regard, the credibility
of the reform will depend on the existence of efficient systems
which encourage the Administrations to meet the fiscal targets. As


                                                                      249
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                          the contribution of Spain

we shall mention in the next section, such principles have been
included in the Law on Fiscal Stability and Financial Sustainability
of Public Administrations.




4. Next steps in the Fiscal Institution of the Economic and
Monetary Union: the necessary contribution of Spain

      The European debate on sustainability of public finances and
the future of the Euro is set at a time in which, following the con-
version of the international crisis into the crisis of the sovereign
debt of several Eurozone countries, we have witnessed myriad
European summits, each of which seeming to be the last chance to
tackle the doubts of the markets in relation to the viability of the
debt, in the first place, of Greece, Portugal and Ireland, and more
recently, of Italy and Spain.


      It is true that the crisis is far from being resolved. The EU has not
always shown a capacity to react with the speed required by econo-
mic relations nowadays – until the tensions reached non peripheral
economies such as Austria or France, the pace in reaching consen-
sus had been much slower than necessary. Moreover, during the cri-
sis, it has become obvious that the institutional design of the
Monetary Union was incomplete and, above all, as we have men-
tioned in this paper, that there has been insufficient political com-
mitment to the application of the existing mechanisms of fiscal
coordination. But it is also true that in the last four years, a consi-


250
The Future of the Euro


derable path has been travelled towards European construction,
towards an improvement in economic governance, so that in addi-
tion to a single monetary policy, Europe is also able to benefit from
greater integration of fiscal policies.


   As such, it is worth highlighting the agreements reached, either
via the community procedure or via inter-governmental agree-
ments, in terms of strengthening coordination, supervision and
policing mechanisms of fiscal and macroeconomic policies.


   In the first place, the European Semester establishes a new sche-
dule whereby, on the basis of the macroeconomic situation of each
member state and its growth forecast, the budgets and economic
policies required to meet the commitments undertaken in the Euro
Plus Pact and the 2020 Growth Strategy are discussed during the
first six months of the year in a coordinated fashion and in accor-
dance with common rules.


   In the second place, the adoption of the so-called Six-pack (one
directive and five regulations) constitutes the greatest reform of the
SGP and of economic Governance since the Maastricht Treaty
which created the EMU. As of the adoption of the new legislation,
the European Commission may establish automatic penalties (of
up 0.2% of GDP) for those countries with excessive deficits which
do not follow the recommendations for correction. At the same
time, the public debt control mechanism and the required reduc-
tion are reinforced in the event of exceeding the 60% GDP level


                                                                   251
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                                    the contribution of Spain

        assumed. It also introduces a mechanism designed to prevent
        excessive imbalances such as unsustainable current account defi-
        cits, loss of competitiveness and other macroeconomic imbalances.


              Lastly, the signature of the new Treaty on Stability,
        Coordination and Growth (by all member states of the EU except
        for the United Kingdom and the Czech Republic) brings changes at
        the highest legislative level to fiscal stability regulation. This must
        be translated in each country in that the structural deficit of the
        public sector may not exceed 0.5 GDP per annum, subject to auto-
        matic penalties.


              These steps will be followed in the months to come by impro-
        vements seeking to fine-tune the mechanisms of economic con-
        vergence, via two legislative proposals7 of the European
        Commission, by establishing a clearer and more demanding sche-
        dule for fiscal coordination in Europe and implementing fiscal
        control and monitoring mechanisms in countries facing serious
        difficulties in regard to their financial stability within the
        Eurozone.


              All these measures help towards the consolidation of economic
        governance, and establish the bases to enable progress to be made


7 "Proposal for a regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on common
provi¬sions for monitoring and assessing draft budgetary plans and ensuring the correction of
exces¬sive deficit of the Member States in the euro area" and "Proposal for a regulation of the
European Parliament and of the Council on the strengthening of economic and budgetary sur-



        252
The Future of the Euro


via other instruments, in order to provide funding and liquidity to
handle emergency situations, to the extent of including euro-
bonds, if necessary, as well as helping the ECB to have greater lee-
way when acting in the markets in pursuit of economic stability.
Without doubt, greater fiscal coordination broadens the funding
margin of these countries. But we must be clear that access to fun-
ding requires preliminary fiscal control, and not the reverse.
Conditionality in all these mechanisms is an essential requirement
when seeking to limit risk. Any funding requires certain minimum
guarantees of repayment of the loan, and this translates into
adjustments and reforms. This is nothing new, but something that
has cropped up on many occasions in IMF interventions.
Eurobonds might get to play a key role, but cannot be the only
item to support the fiscal union, which will drive the Eurozone
towards optimum monetary union, and for which to date there is
no more than a highly experimental road map.


   Within this working programme so badly needed in Europe, and
supported by conditionality, greater mechanisms for EU income
transmission should be created to help countries facing serious pro-
blems – such as that of the sovereign debt crisis – in order to imple-
ment the structural reforms required by their economies, with the
support of Europe in driving growth. This can be done via the
encouragement of youth employment and entrepreneur program-



veillance of Member States experiencing or threatened with serious difficulties with respect to
their finan¬cial stability in the euro area", European Commission, November 2011


                                                                                  253
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

mes, the reinforcement of resources available, among other uses,
for structural funds or for the activity of the European Investment
Bank.


      On their part, the Eurozone member states can and must con-
tribute to guarantee the future of the single currency, and to the
generation of the economic growth required to clear any doubts as
to the sustainability of sovereign debt, either via their contribu-
tions towards the establishment of common rules so that the EMU
becomes an optimum monetary zone, or via the reforms on a
national scale which constitute an example for all the others.


      There is also a high degree of parallelism between the rules
required and which must be institutionalized in the Monetary
Union at a European level, and the process which must be follo-
wed in Spain in regard to responsibility, conditionality and subsi-
diarity of regional and local Public Administrations. In both cases,
the need for a political will capable of applying clear and straight-
forward rules, with prevention mechanisms, supported by coordi-
nation, monitoring and automatic sanction systems for those who
fail to comply with the targets undertaken, has become clearly evi-
dent. In this sense, the fact that the new fiscal pact at a European
level and the recent legislative changes in Spain seem to be going
in the same direction is a positive factor.


      The case of Spain, where we have a very high degree of decentra-
lisation and where the Autonomous Communities and Local


254
The Future of the Euro


Corporations manage approximately 50% of the public expenditure,
is a clear example of the need for coordination of fiscal policies to
ensure that the right signals are sent to markets and investors in
regard to the orientation of the fiscal policy. The consolidation efforts
made by some countries and regions are useless if there are others
which do not honour their commitments and destabilise the zone,
region or country. Europe and, of course, Spain have their own iden-
tity, and this applies to act as a unique body in order to establish the
aims. The scope of action of each government to achieve fiscal targets
undertaken, via the instruments deemed appropriate, is a different
thing altogether. The principle of subsidiarity must be respected pro-
vided that the principle of fiscal balance is observed. Each country
must have autonomy to define and design its fiscal structure so
long as the limits set for deficit, debt and growth in expenditure are
respected. Fiscal competition allows for improvement in revenue
collection efficiency and greater rigour in expenditure control, and
thus the greater fiscal coordination in Europe must not be envisaged
as a single fiscal policy. However, one of the main instruments at the
disposal of the governments when coordinating fiscal policies is con-
ditionality. In any regional funding system there are income transmis-
sion mechanisms and penalties aiming to fulfil the set fiscal targets.
Therefore, in the event that fiscal stability criteria are not met, be it at
a national level within the Eurozone or at a regional level within
Spain, the aid provided, as the case may be via special liquidity facili-
ties and even, if necessary, by way of eurobonds or hispanobonds, or
by way of larger revenue transmissions at a European level, cannot
take place without the acceptance of the conditionality it carries.


                                                                        255
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

      Spain has understood the need to contribute to the stability in
Europe and is leading, for the second time, a solid process of
reforms towards fiscal balance. Following the general elections of
November 2011, the new government and a reinforced political
capital constitute the main assets to bring about the necessary
reforms. The proof thereof is evident in the fiscal reforms: the
Royal Decree of non-availability, the reform of the Law on
Stability, the new system for payment to suppliers, the new bill on
Transparency or the bill of General State Budgets for 2012 (which
establishes an adjustment of 27,300 million euros to be made bet-
ween cost control and revenue increase).


      The modification of section 135 of the Spanish Constitution
assumed its inclusion in a subsequent organic Law (the Law of
Budgetary Stability and Financial Sustainability of the Public
Administrations, recently presented), which specifies changes in
the preparation, execution and control of the Spanish fiscal insti-
tution. The recent approval of this bill means a return to the com-
mitment to the control of public finances and, more importantly,
it adds all of the Public Administrations to its scope of application,
which the previous Stability Law failed to do.


      The three main objectives of this bill are to guarantee the fiscal
sustainability of all Public Administrations, to strengthen econo-
mic confidence and to reinforce the commits of Spain with the
European Union.




256
The Future of the Euro


   All Public Administrations must present a balance or a surplus
calculated according to EAS terms and none may incur in structural
deficit. However, there are two exceptions in the case of structural
reforms with long term fiscal effects (a structural deficit of 0.4% of
the GDP may be achieved) and in the event of natural disasters, eco-
nomic recession and extraordinary economic emergency.


   In establishing the objectives of stability and public debt, the
recommendations of the EU in regard to the Stability Programme
must be taken into account, and all Public Administrations must
approve an expenditure ceiling in line with the stability target and
the expenditure rule. One of the most important aspects, in accor-
dance with European regulations, restricts the growth in expendi-
ture by the Public Administrations, as this may not exceed the GDP
growth rate.


   Failure to comply with the targets shall require the presenta-
tion of an economic and financial plan to allow the correction of
the deviation for a period of one year. This plan must explain the
causes underlying the deviation and the measures which will
bring it back within the limit. In the event of non-compliance
with the plan, the responsible Administration must automatically
approve the non-availability of loans to guarantee compliance
with the set target and the meeting of the targets shall be taken
into account when authorising debt issues, granting subsidies and
signing agreements.




                                                                   257
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                         the contribution of Spain

      The Law, on the other hand, strengthens the preventive and
monitoring systems of stability and debt objectives. Therefore, a
debt threshold of a preventive nature is established, beyond which
the only debt operations allowed will be cash transactions.


      In order to render all Public Administrations jointly responsible,
the penalties imposed in Spain in matters of stability shall be assu-
med by the responsible administration. In the event of failure to
produce an economic-financial plan, the administration in breach
must put of a deposit of 0.2% of its nominal GDP, which after six
months may be converted into a penalty in the event that the vio-
lations should continue. After nine months, the Ministry of
Finance and Public Administrations may send a delegation to
assess the economic and budgetary situation of the delinquent
Administration.


      In order to strengthen the principle of transparency, each
Public Administration must establish the equivalence between
the budget and the national accounts. Prior to approval, each
Public Administration must provide information on its main
budget guidelines, in order to comply with European regulatory
requirements.


      As was set forth in the new draft of section 135 of the
Constitution, the Law establishes a temporary period until 2020
for gradual compliance, until public debt is 60% of GDP. In order
to ensure compliance with this scenario, public debt must be redu-


258
The Future of the Euro


ced whenever the economy experiences positive real growth. Upon
reaching a growth rate of 2% or net yearly employment is genera-
ted, the debt ratio shall be reduced each year at least by two GDP
points. On its part, the global structural deficit must be reduced by
0.8% of the annual average GDP.


   Beyond the institutional importance of the reform, it is worth
considering the political capital that is allowing the deficit problem
to be addressed in an integral way and with long term vision. Doubts
as to possible deficit deviations in the current and following finan-
cial years should not lead us to lose perspective of the importance of
the reform. This reform set a trend designed to transform public bud-
gets into a reliable institution, with a simple structure, with no room
for interpretation, equal for all and with an automatic application
which allows it to be protected from temptations from other govern-
ments. In this regard, we also view the provisions included in the Bill
for the Transparency Law, which, undoubtedly, shall contribute
towards generating better knowledge of public finances.


   The fiscal systems being approved in Spain matched with the
European model. There is a strong parallelism between the two,
and the construction errors of the European design and of the fis-
cal institution in Spain must be corrected by means of a coordina-
tion of fiscal policies in which the principles of regulatory equity,
subsidiarity, conditionality and sustainability should prevail above
all others.




                                                                    259
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                        the contribution of Spain

      Without doubt, the future of the euro requires more Europe.
The construction of Europe needs rules, adjustments and reforms.
Without growth the European model is doomed for failure. The
current crisis is but a result of the structural deficiencies of our eco-
nomy, of our excess indebtedness, of our lack of flexibility and our
lack of competitiveness in some aspects.


      Once again, Spain, on its part, must become a role model of the
fiscal institution in Europe, and of the benefits which macroeco-
nomic stability brings to the economies, in terms of higher growth,
more wealth and greater employment. This is unquestionably the
best way to redistribute income. This is the only way we will mana-
ge to get Europe and Spain out of the sovereign debt crisis they
face, ensuring a solid future for the process of European construc-
tion, which is the greatest milestone in the search for peace and
prosperity in Europe.




5. Conclusion

      Following the same pattern set since the inception of the
European integration project after the World War, the EMU came
about in 1999 as a result of the political aspiration of increasing
integration and as a European response to the globalisation pro-
cess. In reality, the integration via the monetary union which
makes up the Eurozone was not an objective in and of itself, but
rather a means to improve competitiveness and efficiency among


260
The Future of the Euro


member countries. The ultimate goal, therefore, was growth, job
creation and the improvement of social welfare, while at the same
time making inroads in terms of political integration.


   At that time the countries were aware of the need to set fiscal dis-
cipline targets as stability factors for Europe. However, those impor-
tant advances in the European construction process became diluted
over the years with the introduction of components carrying greater
flexibility and discretionality in the fiscal institution. The best exam-
ple is that the solution provided in 2005 to the violation of the SGP
by Germany and France was none other than the reform thereof
which included greater ambiguity in the search for fiscal stability, for
which they gained the support of the European Commission. The
diminishing political commitment with the fiscal institution and its
fragility in the face of the vicissitudes of the different governments
and ideologies became clear at that time. Therefore, with an institu-
tional design which was incomplete, and gradually declining over
the years, the EMU was far from representing an optimal monetary
area, and therefore the imbalances of the Eurozone economies incre-
ased, instead of decreasing, placing Europe in a difficult situation in
the face of the global financial crisis.


   In this context, the current European debt crisis has highlighted
the urgent need for better coordination of the fiscal policies in
Europe. At the same time and particularly during the crisis, the
experience since the foundation of the euro has shown the impor-
tance of political commitment with the fiscal institution and the


                                                                      261
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                        the contribution of Spain

need for preventive rules instead of penalties which are difficult to
apply. It is essential to ensure that the accumulation of excessive
deficits does not lead to unsustainable situations which call into
question traditional European security and seriously complicate
the capacity for funding growth and job creation. Rules are a
necessary condition to ensure compliance with fiscal targets. But
these rules must be of straightforward and automatic application.


      Despite the difficulties, the present economic time obliges
Europe and Spain to make fast and efficient decisions in order to
straighten out the situation. It is important to take advantage of
current circumstances to tackle ambitious reforms designed to
correct some of the structural flaws of the Eurozone and of our eco-
nomy. It is important to face the current problems from a long
term outlook and to establish the rules of a fiscal institution which
ensure the viability of the European project.


      The future and survival of the euro rests on all member states
being able to implement domestic reforms seriously, thus genera-
ting a sign of confidence for international investors and which
shall also serve, again in our case, as a calling card for our busines-
ses abroad. In Spain, one of the countries which has sustained the
most damage from the sharp budgetary deviations of recent years,
regional configuration shows evident parallelisms with Europe,
both in terms of the need to establish common objectives, and in
terms of the control systems or the transmission and penalty
mechanisms.


262
The Future of the Euro


   Spain, as a country which has already proven its ability to take
on this role at the end of the 1990s in the foundation of the Euro,
once again has an important role to play. In this regard, it is worth
mentioning that, thanks to the latest reforms implemented in sup-
port of the fiscal institution, Spain is once again contributing to
the European debate in pursuit of macroeconomic stability in the
Eurozone and its recovery. The challenge to be addressed, by means
of a change in the economic policy, is to recover confidence and
credibility of our economy, to enable businesses and consumers to
concentrate efforts in business, labour or consumer decisions, and
that macroeconomic issues, such as the risk premium, cease to be
cause for concern. Only in this way may Spain avoid lagging
behind like a second rate club, to which we have already said no a
few years back.


   In order to move forward in building a fiscal union in Europe,
which succeeds in turning the EMU into an optimal monetary area
and ensures the good health of the euro and of the European eco-
nomy, the necessary mechanisms of income transmission, ensure
the availability of financial resources and required liquidity, to the
extent, if necessary, of creating risk pooling instruments, such as
eurobonds and, in parallel, the hispanobonds in the case of Spain.
These require, however, the establishment of prerequisites, that is,
economic adjustments and reforms to be implemented by the
countries facing the most difficulties. The rules are very important,
but without reforms it is impossible to grow, and without growth,
budgets become unsustainable. A different issue is, provided agre-


                                                                   263
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union:
                                                        the contribution of Spain

ed commitments are met, the respect for the autonomy of each
country to decide on its income and expenditure structure.
Subsidiarity must govern in Europe for those who are taking the
necessary steps, as is being done in Spain, in order to adapt the
budgets to the economic and social reality of each country.


      The European construction has taken important steps since the
start of the crisis, but it needs to continue to progress via an incen-
tive system to ensure the political commitment with the fiscal ins-
titution in the medium and long term. The objectives of peace and
prosperity established by the founding fathers of the European
construction, on a long term horizon, once again depend on our
capacity to recover the growth and competitiveness of the eco-
nomy, and hence employment and the European welfare model.




264
/JAIME REQUEIJO * /




                   The European Monetary Union:
                          the Never-Ending Crisis




1. Introduction; 2. The Euro: a Badly Constructed Building; 3. The fiscal
Spillover; 4. The Consequences of the Doubtful Debt; 5. Contributing
Factors; 6. Main Measures Adopted to Solve the Monetary Union Crisis; 7.
Outcome of the Measures Adopted so far; 8. Consequences of the Breakup
of the Euro; 9. The Missing Link




* Ph.D in Economics, BA in Law, Former Civil Servant attached to the Ministry of
Commerce, Emeritus Professor of Applied Economics (UNED and IEB).Former positions
include : General Director for Imports and Tariff Policy at the Ministry of Commerce,
Chief Executive Officer of Caja Postal de Ahorros, Member of the Board of Banco
Zaragozano, Director of the School of Financial Studies (UCM) and Member of the
Board of Banco de España.
His fields of research focus on monetary and financial matters, international economics
and the Spanish economy. He has written seven books and published more then
seventy papers in Spanish economic reviews..


                                                                           265
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


1. Introduction

      The constant financial trepidation afflicting different countries
of the Eurozone, and which threatens the survival of the single
currency, is not the result of random events. In our view, they can
be put down to four fundamental reasons. First, the Monetary
Union is a badly constructed building as political urgency prevai-
led over economic prudence. Second, there is the fiscal irresponsi-
bility of many member state governments, an irresponsibility that
has materialized as hefty public debts. Thirdly, the doubts being
generated among the debt holders, mainly institutional investors
and banks, and which has led to significant fluctuations in the
interest rates of those assets and, in general, to a cost hike for the
issuers. Four, what we could call the contributing aspects: the spi-
llover and contagion effects that batter the financial markets,
effects linked to the opinions of the rating agencies and, on occa-
sions, to the worst-case scenarios of the International Monetary
Fund regarding the medium-term performance of the European
Union economies and, particularly important, those of the
Monetary Union.


      Faced with that panorama, and given the absence of clear solu-
tions, there are three questions raised by many observers of the cri-
sis. The first question is what the measures are that have been
adopted so far to try and avoid the recurring disruption. The
second question is whether those measures, or further ones
currently under debate, will be sufficient to solve the problem or,


266
The Future of the Euro


on the other hand, will the fate of the Monetary Union be to totally
or partially break up? The third question is if the Monetary Union
proves to be totally unviable and the national currencies have to be
re-introduced, what will the consequences be of the failure of the
euro?


   This paper seeks to provide a reasoned explanation of the cau-
ses underpinning the current major upheaval and it also aims to
answer the aforementioned three questions regarding the measu-
res, their outcome and impact of a possible breakup of the euro.
The paper ends with a short section considering the solution that
should be adopted to keep the Monetary Union in place.




2. The Euro: a Badly Constructed Building

   Even though the dream of the single currency had been always
present since the Treaty of Rome, the definitive decision, contained
in the Maastricht Treaty, is the outcome of the political desires of
France and Germany. Of France as French governments believed
that having a single European currency would avoid the constant
pressures on the franc, pressures that usually led to the devaluation
of its currency. Of Germany as accepting the single currency meant
highlighting the European vocation of the most important
European economy after reunification in 1990, a process that ope-
ned up many raw wounds – particularly in France. Driven by those
dual interests, the currency unification project prospered, not wit-


                                                                   267
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


       hout significant frictions, until it became reality in 1999, the year
       when eleven countries, including Spain, ceded their monetary
       autonomy to the European System of Central Banks; Greece would
       join in 2001, followed by other countries until it reached the
       current seventeen members.1


             Joining the Eurozone required the countries to meet the so-
       called Maastricht convergence criteria, those rules aimed at ensu-
       ring that the different economies had a certain nominal similarity.
       During the year prior to the Compatibility Test, the inflation rate
       could not be more than 1.5 points over the average of the three
       most stable candidate countries; as the end of that year, the public
       sector deficit could not exceed 3% of the Gross Domestic Product
       or the debt be greater than 60% of that figure; the candidate
       country had to have been part of the European Monetary System
       during the two years prior to the test and without its currency
       having experienced significant fluctuations; and, during the pre-
       vious year, the long-term nominal interest rate had not exceeded
       the average of the three most stable countries by more than 2
       points.2 After the failure of the European Monetary System in
       1993, only the other three criteria were required to determine
       which countries could join the euro, and those criteria have conti-


1 Note that the countries that initially joined the Monetary Union were Germany,
Austria, Belgium, Spain, Finland, France, the Netherlands, Italy, Luxembourg and
Portugal. Greece joined later and, successively, followed by Slovenia, Cyprus, Malta,
Slovakia and Estonia.
2 Article 121 of the 1992 Maastricht Treaty.


       268
The Future of the Euro


nued to be applied to accept the application for entry of the suc-
cessive candidates.


   Please note that those criteria were only required at the time of joi-
ning. The subsequent restrictions were laid down by the 1997
Stability and Growth Pact, aimed at maintaining budgetary stability
within the Union. Thus, the country could not exceed the annual
limit of the deficit and the debt: 3% and 60% of the GDP respectively.
Exceeding those limits meant that the European Commission would
implement the excessive deficit procedure, which would result in the
country in question having to face certain penalties. Subsequently, in
2005, the rules were reformed so that the deficits tested were not the
nominal but rather the structural ones. Therefore, not only the
current deficit, but also the sustainability of the long-term public debt
was taken into account in the supervision and monitoring process
entrusted to the European Commission.3 In short, and right from the
outset, the nominal similarities that a series of economies with clear
real differences had to offer were what seemed to matter to European
leaders. And, proof of that difference could be seen when, in 2002 –
Greece had already joined – the typical deviation of labour producti-
vity per hour worked, calculated as CWA was 29.46;4 which clearly
showed the different competitive capacity of the different countries,
right from the start. Those differences were a hint of the future sym-


3 See “The Stability and Growth Pact: Public Finances in the Euro Zone” of the Sub-
Directorate General for Financial and Economic Affairs of the European Union, SCI
Economic Gazette No. 2906, 16-28 October 2007.
4 Prepared using the Eurostat data for the twelve member countries.


                                                                          269
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


       metric upheavals to come in the zone, and that group of countries,
       for different reasons, did not constitute – or constitutes – an optimum
       monetary zone. And thus, the European Monetary Union was built
       on quicksand, quicksand that would begin to overwhelm it as soon
       as the fiscal irresponsibility of some of the governments made a sig-
       nificant dent in the building overall.




       3. The Fiscal Spillover

             Can governments of countries with weak currencies issue debt in
       their currency and ensure that attracts foreign investors? The like-
       lihood is minimum as the potential investor will think that, at some
       point, the currency will depreciate substantially, leading to a loss.


             Can countries with a strong currency do so? They can because
       the investors will not fear the losses following on from devalua-
       tion. And proof of this is that institutional or private investors, resi-
       dent in a wide variety of countries, have traditionally kept debts in
       dollars, marks, Swiss francs or yens in their portfolios.


             The euro sought to be a strong currency right from the outset.
       This strength was based on the monetary policy of the European
       Central Bank, whose primary objective would be to keep prices sta-
       ble.5 And which, furthermore, represented a series of important

5 Art. 2 of the Statues of the European System of Central Banks and the European
Central Banks.


       270
The Future of the Euro


economies, with Germany at the head. Moreover, the exchange
rate risk disappeared for member countries and it therefore facilita-
ted the setting up of a large financial market in euro.


   The appearance of the euro, therefore, meant the disappearance
of the original sin experienced by countries with weak currencies:
the difficultly of leverage in other currencies, which meant that
they were at huge risk of financial fragility.6 The way was therefore
left clear for governments of euro countries that had found it diffi-
cult to finance themselves in other currencies prior to joining the
single currency, to easily raise leverage in the powerful financial
market of the euro. The only thing missing was the imperative need
to do so.


   And that imperative need arrived with the economic crisis,
which began in 2007, and with the general downturn in the rates
of growth, a fall that is reflected in the following table.


   It should be noted that even through the downturn in growth
was widespread, the countries with the sharpest recession were
Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain within the initial group of twelve
countries.


   When the growth rate shrank, which was greatest in those cases
with the sharpest change in cycle, the budgetary revenue fell and

6 See Eichengreen, B. & Haussmann, R. “Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility”, NBER
WP 7418, 1999.


                                                                         271
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


      Table No. 1. Average Growth of the Eurozone (17 countries)

                                           Average                    Average
       Country
                                          2004-2006                  2 0 0 7 -2 0 1 1
       Germany                               1.87                         1.20
       Austria                               2.90                         1.30
       Belgium                               2.57                         1.12
       Cyprus                                4.07                         1.68
       Slovenia                              4.73                         0.74
       Slovakia                              6.70                         3.80
       Spain                                 3.67                         0.26
       Estonia                               8.43                        -0.14
       Finland                               3.70                         0.80
       France                                2.20                         0.52
       Greece                                4.07                        -1.90
       The Netherlands                       2.53                         1.14
       Ireland                               5.03                        -0.82
       Italy                                 1.27                         0.52
       Luxembourg                            4.93                         1.28
       Malta                                 2.33                         2.20
       Portugal                              1.27                        -0.20
      Source: Own preparation, using Eurostat data (Europe in figures, 2012)



the deficits appeared or increased and grew even further if the bud-
gets included automatic stabilisers, by virtue of which the fiscal
policy became expansive in periods of recession, and even more
expansive if the governments relied on additional fiscal stimulus to
overcome the economic crisis.


      All of these are reasons have been given to explain the rapid
increase in the public sector debt, as can be seen in Table No. 2.


      Given that panorama of slow growth, or decline, and of growing
public debts, it comes of no surprise that debt holders would soon
have greater misgivings – misgivings that particularly affected those


272
The Future of the Euro


   Table No. 2. Evolution of the public debt of the eurozone (% GDP)

    Country                      2007            2011                  Growth
    Germany                       65.2            81.8                  25%
    Austria                       60.2            72.2                  20%
    Belgium                       84.1            97.2                  16%
    Cyprus                        58.8            64.9                  10%
    Slovenia                      23.1            45.5                  97%
    Slovakia                      29.6            44.5                  50%
    Spain                         36.2            69.6                  92%
    Estonia                        3.7             5.8                  57%
    Finland                       35.2            49.1                  38%
    France                        64.2            85.4                  33%
    Greece                       107.4           162.8                  52%
    The Netherlands               45.3            64.3                  42%
    Ireland                       24.9           108.1                  334%
    Italy                        103.1           120.5                  17%
    Luxembourg                     6.7            19.5                  191%
    Malta                         62.4            69.6                  12%
    Portugal                      68.3           101.6                  49%
    Eurozone                      66.3              88                  33%

   Source: Own preparation, with data from the Statistical Annex of European Economy,
   autumn 2011. The data refer to the gross debt as they are the liabilities that the govern-
   ment must face.



countries where the recession was combined with spiralling debt and
the few prospects for recovery. It was, therefore, foreseeable that any
event that affected the debt of a country would lead to a chain reac-
tion that would challenge the financial stability of the Eurozone.


   That event was Greece going into virtual receivership on 23 April
2010: on that date the Greek government asked the International
Monetary Fund and the European Union for a 45,000 million euro
loan to meet their financial obligations, four months after Fitch, the
rating agency, had downgraded its debt.




                                                                                           273
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


4. The Consequences of the Doubtful Debt

      From then onwards, there were constant indications of concern
in different channels about the sovereign debts with a question
mark over them. First of all, the increase of the risk premiums of
certain securities; secondly, the increase in the cost of the credit
insurance for the same securities; third, the greater occasional cost
of the new issues by the countries under suspicion, the so-called
peripheral countries: Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain.


      The three aforementioned reactions clearly moved in the same
direction. As is known, hikes in risk premiums on the secondary mar-
kets consist of discounts on the value of the securities, discounts that
are equivalent to an increase in the relevant interests and which are
compared to the interests of the benchmark debt, the German one,
for the same market. In its simplest version, credit insurance (Credit
Default Swaps) are contracts by virtue of which, and by means of
paying a premium, the bondholder is guaranteed the collection of
the nominal amount. And in increase of the risk premiums and the
price of the swaps affect, by definition, the cost of the new issues: the
more expensive the premiums and swaps become, the higher the
interest that the new issues should offer and the greater the cost for
the relevant governments. All of which tends to worsen the financial
situation of the governments, a situation that will enter a downward
spiral if the average interest rate of the outstanding debt is greater
than the growth rate of its economy.




274
The Future of the Euro


5. Contributing Factors

   Current financial markets are markets of news and rumour
mills.7


   The first report on how the turbulence develop and reflect veri-
fiable facts: the initial request for help by the Greek government;
the successive austerity measures demanded by the European aut-
horities and the International Monetary Fund for the bailout to be
granted; the social response to the austerity plans in different
countries or the downgrading of the sovereign debts of different
countries of the Eurozone, including France. All of the events show
the constant severity of an ongoing crisis.


   The second are, in general, interpretations, opinions that are
usually transmitted through the different media, whether they are
journals, the daily press, television and radio programmes or news
spread online. Some are reasonably based opinions that are trying
to consider the difficult situation of the Monetary Union and to
offer some type of solution.8 Others are purely and simply seeking
to be alarmist, to the point of suggesting to their readers that they




7 An extensive study into the subject of rumours is by Mark Schindler: “Rumors in
Financial Markets”, Wiley&Sons, UK, 2007.
8 Examples of opinions of this type are “Beware of fallen masonry”, The Economist,
26/11/2011, and those expressed by K. Rogoff in the interview published by Spiegel on
27/2/2012, entitled “Germany Has Been the Winner in the Globalization Process”.


                                                                          275
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


       should stock up on food to survive the chaos that will reign, on the
       world scale, when the euro implodes and triggers a financial tsu-
       nami that will spread over the five continents.9


             Furthermore, there are the constant threats of downgrading the
       sovereign debt by the three major US agencies – Standard & Poors,
       Moody’s and Fitch –, the three who were so optimistic when it came
       to US mortgage junk bonds,10 and the doubts expressed, from time
       to time, by the International Monetary Fund regarding the future of
       the euro zone. There is also the risk that the whole set of views,
       from the most founded to the most alarmist, will awaken many
       fears and the prophecy will become self-fulfilling: the disaster will
       occur because the avalanche of negative opinions will set it in
       motion.


       6. Main Measures Adopted to solve the Monetary Union
       Crisis

             At the time of writing (April 2012), these measures have invol-
       ved setting up general bailout funds, the approval of a Greek Loan

9 Read “Will Greek Sovereign Debt Default on March 23” by Patrik Heller, Coinweck,
22/2/2012 (online).
10 In the opinion of John Kiff, from the International Monetary Fund, the opinion of
the agencies increases the uncertainties on the sovereign debt markets, due to the
importance that the participants on those markets seem to attribute to them. See his
article “Reducing Role of Credit Ratings Would Aid Markets” IMF Survey Magazine,
29/9/2010. Also Arezki et al: “Sovereign Rating News and Financial Markets
Spillovers”, IMF, WP/11/68.


       276
The Future of the Euro


Facility, the interventions of the European Central Bank and the
fine tuning of a new Treaty on Stability, Coordination and
Governance of the Monetary and Economic Union.


   In 2010, the European Financial Stability Fund was set up,
whose aim is to facilitate resources to euro countries in financial
difficulties. It is a company whose headquarters are in Luxembourg
and its loan capacity is to the tune of 440,000 million euros.11 To
grant a loan to a Euro country, the government of the country has
to request it and sign an austerity programme. Part of the loans to
Ireland and Portugal were arranged through that Fund.


   In 2011, the European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism was
created for a similar purpose. It is an institution, supervised by the
European Commission, which obtains its resources from the capi-
tal markets by means of issuing bonds underwritten by the
European Union budget. It may provide aid to members of the
European Union, whether or not they are members of the
Eurozone, is compatible with aid provided by other channels and
also requires the prior approval of an austerity package. Loans
have also been granted through this programme to Ireland and
Portugal.


   The two aforementioned funds would duly be subsumed in the
European Stability Mechanism), agreed by the Eurozone countries

11 All the data referring to the bailout fund and to the Greek Loan Facility are taken
from European Commission official documents.


                                                                           277
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


in February 2012 and which should begin to function in July of
that year. Its aid will not be limited to granting loans, but it will
likewise be able to acquire bonds issued by the member countries,
either on the primary or on the secondary markets, and facilitate
resources aimed at recapitalising financial institutions. In princi-
ple, it would have 80,000 million euros of capital and an initial cre-
dit capacity of 500,000 million euros. In May 2010, the members
of the Eurozone bilaterally decided to lend Greece 80,000 million
euros that, in addition to the 30,000 million from the
International Monetary Fund, meant that the first Greek bailout
totalled 110,000 million euros. At the end of 2011, and 73,000
million euros had been paid out from that fund, a payment that
required an austerity undertaking. On 14 March 2012, a new bai-
lout programme was approved, with substantial write offs for the
creditors and austerity obligations for the Greek Government, to
the tune of 130,000 million euros, an amount which includes the
International Monetary Fund contribution of 28,000 million
euros. The purpose of that financial support, which will last until
2014, is to bring the Greek public deficit under the 117% of its
Gross Domestic Product by 2020. Part of that bailout will be chan-
nelled through the European Financial Stability Fund.


      A crisis intervention of particular importance is by the
European Central Bank, an intervention channelled in two lines.
In a non-recurrent way, the Bank acquires debt on the secondary
market, which reduces the risk premium and means that the issues
of new securities are at a lower cost. On the other hand, it lends


278
The Future of the Euro


resources at a very low interest rate to financial brokers – its basic
rate has remained at 1% for some time – which means that the
banks of the worst hit countries acquire part of the new issues.
They, therefore, facilitate the placement of securities, securities that
are profitable for the financial institutions and less costly for the
issuers.


   On 2 March 2012 and after many debates in the European
Council, the representatives of twenty-five countries of the
European Union – as neither the United Kingdom nor in the
Czech Republic wanted to sign up – signed the Treaty on Stability,
Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary
Union. Even though the new Treaty was signed by members of the
European Union that are not part of the Monetary Union, its fun-
damental proposal is to force the euro countries to ensure that
their public finances are balanced. Further proof of that purpose is
that the Treaty will come into force when it has been ratified by at
least twelve euro countries.


   A key aspect of the agreement is the so-called Budgetary
Agreement that forces those countries to tighten their budgetary
discipline and which introduces the balanced budget rule, a rule
that must be included in national legislation and, preferentially, in
the Constitution. The structural deficit must not exceed a specific
limit and cycle deficits are accepted, resulting from substantial
downturns in the economic activity, provided that they do not
alter the balanced budget rule in the medium term. And, in the


                                                                     279
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


       case that the deficit exceeds the permitted limit, a series of auto-
       matic penalties are envisaged.12




       7. Outcome of the Measures Adopted so far

             Judging by the data that appeared in early April 2012, recovery
       from the downturn has not yet started, in particular, as far as the
       peripheral countries are concerned: volatility remains high both
       on the sovereign debt markets and on the variable income ones –
       in the case of the latter, the downward trend is reflected by the
       drop in share prices of the most exposed banks to the sovereign
       debt of those countries – and the doubts persist regarding the capa-
       city of several of them to meet their obligations. Which is not at
       all strange for several reasons.


             The required restructuring to bring the debt back to more bea-
       rable levels would hinder, in the short term, the growth capacity of
       the five countries, as economic recovery would be further compli-
       cated by the shrink in their tax revenue. And all of this would
       occur in a climate of recession and economic stagnation that appe-
       ars to have taken hold of the European Union, over all, and the
       Monetary Union, in particular.13




12 The full text of the Treaty can be seen at the European Council website.
13 The forecasts can be seen at the European Economic Forecast, Autumn 2011 (online).



       280
The Future of the Euro


   The situation of Greece is at the forefront of all the economic
analysis of the euro zone as very few believe so far that the recently
approved second bailout will result in the country solving pro-
blems and many believe that a third bailout will soon be on the
cards. And those doubts regarding the future of the Greek economy
are spreading to the rest of the peripheral countries and, to a great
extent, to the very future of the Monetary Union.


   Despite the measures approved so far, the decision processes have
dragged on as an agreement needs to be reached by country repre-
sentatives, who are very aware of the opinion of their citizens, and
by representatives of community institutions. Long processes, where
multiple opinions, sometimes discrepancies, are mixed, that increa-
se the uncertainties regarding the future of the euro, even though
the disappearance of the single currency could raise much more
wide-ranging problems than the current ones trying to be solved.




8. Consequences of the Breakup of the Euro

   The breakup of the Monetary Union could occur should one or
more member states decided to leave the single currency and rein-
troduce their own currency. That split could either be due to the
departure of one or more weak-economies or to one or more
strong-economies breaking. In either of the two cases, the Union
would be broken.




                                                                   281
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


             From the legal perspective, such a possibility does not currently
       exist as the Maastricht Treaty does not include any clause that
       opens up the way; only the 200714 Lisbon Treaty                 accepts the
       voluntary withdrawal of a member state from the European Union,
       but says nothing about the Monetary Union. This may be because
       the architects of the common currency always thought that, given
       that the single currency was an extremely important step in the
       political and economic construction of Europe, the decision of
       each country should be irrevocable.


             Yet, leaving the legal aspect on one side, despite its importance,
       the collapse of the Eurozone would lead to a series of disastrous con-
       sequences for the country or countries that had left the euro, for the
       Eurozone overall and for the world economy.


             Let us first consider the departure of a weak economy. The mere
       presumption by its citizens of leaving would result in a large-scale
       transference of deposits from its banks towards other banks located
       outside the country, given that nobody would want to see their euro
       assets converted into balances in the devalued currency; the
       Government in question would be forced to impose, as a preventive
       measure and prior to the decision to abandon the euro, a limit on
       withdrawing deposits and a strict exchange rate control. As it is to be
       supposed that part of the private debt of the country would be held
       by foreign institutions, individuals and companies would find them-
       selves in the worrying situation of having to face such debts with a
14 Art. 50 of the Treaty regarding the voluntary withdrawal for a member country.


       282
The Future of the Euro


national currency of a lower value. With respect to the sovereign
debt, the problem would be the same: the Government would be
compelled to honour it at a higher cost. And the internal economic
adjustments would be of such a magnitude that the main purpose
sought by returning to the national currency – regaining the exchan-
ge rate policy and, thus, making the exportable goods more compe-
titive – would take many years to occur. Without even going into the
social and legal conflicts that would occur, in that country, as a seve-
re recession for an unforeseeable length would occur.


   If the country decided to abandon the euro were a very strong
economy, would there be more advantages than disadvantages? It is
not easy to answer that question, for two reasons. First of all, becau-
se the foreseeable outcome is that its currency would appreciate,
which, even though it would mean an initial advantage, would also
raise problems. For example, and from that moment onwards, its
banks would have deposits in the new currency, but it is to be sup-
posed that part of its assets would be for operations with residents
in the euro zone and, therefore, the financial brokers would have to
face losses through that channel, and would moreover have to face
its fiscal obligations in the new currency. Second, and this is the
more important aspect, the appreciation of its currency would affect
its competitiveness in the remaining euro countries – the main mar-
ket of all the countries of the Monetary Union – which, undoub-
tedly, would hit its growth capacity for many years to come.15

15 On these aspects, see “Euro break-up: the consequences” of UBS Investment
Research, 6/9/2011 (online). Also the opinions of Eric Dior: “Leaving the euro zone: a


                                                                           283
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


             The departure from the Eurozone of any country, or several
        countries, would break up the Monetary Union in both political
        and economic terms. In economic terms, because the growing dis-
        trust of all its citizens would lead to substantial capital flights and,
        probably, to the collapse of different financial systems, which
        would cloud the very limited economic perspectives of the zone
        and would lead to a long recession. In political terms as its inter-
        national clout would be considerably reduced, based on a situa-
        tion, the current one, which is not particularly brilliant: its lack of
        political unity and its indecisiveness, which characterises it as a
        soft power area clearly reduce the international presence of a zone
        that, we should not forget, is, taken overall, the second economy
        and the second market of the world.16 Its breakup and the ensuing
        recession would cloud the international presence of that group of
        countries to unimaginable limits. And without taking into account
        the likely decline of the European Union.


             It is interesting to observe the distancing that many non-
        European analysts show when considering the spasms of the
        Monetary Union. Which is the equivalent, in many cases, to con-
        sidering them as a local problem: the Eurozone is having to bear
        great tensions, arising from the sovereign debt crisis, and there is
        a question mark over its survival. And they go no further. They
        forget that, in a world of fully integrated financial markets, the

user’s guide”. IESEG School of Management (Lille Catholic University), October 2011
(online).
16 With World Bank and World Trade Organisation data for 2010.


       284
The Future of the Euro


Eurozone crisis would have a global impact. For two reasons. First
of all, because a good part of the sovereign debt is in bank port-
folios; secondly, because the credit insurances (CDS) are, pos-
sibly, held by financial institutions around the world.


   In December 2011, 513,000 million euros of public debt of the
five peripheral countries (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain)
appeared in the portfolios of European banks.17 If we take into
account that the financial institutions around the world are linked
by a series of international transactions, it is not difficult to con-
clude that the breakup of the euro would have global repercussions.


   In the March 2011, the CDS linked to European sovereign debt
stood at 145,000 million dollars.18 Neither of these two figures are
high but they are sufficiently important for the upheavals of the euro
zone, following on from the breakup of the currency, to be transferred
to other regions of the world with substantial multiplying effects.


   It therefore can be supposed that the Monetary Union will
manage to overcome this crisis. Yet, from our point of view, the
current firewalls – the bailout funds, however they are called – and
the budgetary obligations, included in the Treaty on Stability,
Coordination and Governance, will not be enough to overcome


17 Jenkins, P. y Stabe, M: “EU banks slash sovereign holdings”. With European Bank
Association data (online).
18 ISDA: “The Impact of Derivative Collateral Policies of European Sovereigns and
Resulting Basel III Capital Issues”, 19/12/2011 (online).


                                                                       285
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis


the current problems and ensure that the Monetary Union is the
threshold to what, when all said and done, has been what they
wanted to achieve through the single currency: a certain degree of
Political Union. An additional link is therefore now needed.




9. The Missing Link

      The endeavours aimed at solving the crisis have so far been along
two paths: creating financial instruments to avoid the bankruptcy of
some governments – the most worrying case is Greece – and strengthe-
ning the obligation of member countries to reach and maintain a rea-
sonable budgetary balance. Important steps, but which have not mana-
ged to eliminate the continuous tension that has been observed in the
financial markets, tension that the interventions of the European
Central Bank have only managed to soften. Soften, not eliminate.


      Note that all the actions undertaken so far – bailout and rules –
do not imply any joint liability. It involves combining financial aid
and remembering that fiscal policy in a single currency arena must
be very similar and very prudent in all member countries. The lia-
bility therefore falls on the Government of each country.


      Yet these measures will not be sufficient if the aim is to shore up
the badly constructed building of the Eurozone. It would be neces-
sary to show that the members of the Monetary Union are capable
of jointly and severally assuming liability of the problems of all its


286
The Future of the Euro


members. And what is necessary, to affirm that joint liability, is to
issue the so-called Eurobonds or Stability Bonds; in other words,
bonds jointly issued that will replace, totally or partly, the current
sovereign debt. That measure, that would be a highly important
step forward in the construction of the common building that is
based on the single currency, would result in three far-reaching
consequences: the sovereign debt crisis of some countries would
be rapidly alleviated; the cost of future issues would be reduce as a
consequence of the overall solvency; and the financial system of
the Eurozone would be more resistant to any future upheaval, and
the overall financial stability would therefore be strengthened.
This decision necessarily implies the setting up of a common trea-
sury and likewise the application of a fiscal policy.


   Clearly, that decision would entail many economic difficulties
and highly complex political problems, as the citizens of the most
prosperous and stable countries of the Union will be not very
willing to accept that type of shared liability which they would see
as the financial problems of others being placed on their shoul-
ders. Yet we should not forget that that possibility has already been
raised by the European Commission itself, precisely to attain those
objectives.19 And we should not forget, above all, that, as I have
attempted to explain in this paper, the end of the Monetary Union
is not a zero-sum game, where there are winners and losers; it is a
negative sum game, where everyone loses.

19 See European Commission: “Green Paper on the feasibility of introducing Stability
Bonds”, 23/11/2011.COM (2011) 818 final (online).


                                                                         287
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis




288
A. JESÚS SÁNCHEZ FUENTES * /SEBASTIAN HAUPTMEIER ** /
                                                         /LUDGER SCHUKNECHT *** /


     Public expenditure policies during the
      EMU period: Lessons for the future?1




1. Introduction; 2. Long-term public expenditure in industrialised coun-
tries; 3. The first decade of EMU period: a missed opportunity?; 3.1. A
disaggregated assessment of past expenditure policies; 3.2. Determinants
of the expenditure stance; 3.3. Implications for public debt; 4. Looking
backward to the past, lessons for the future? an episodes based approach;
5. The need for prudent expenditure rules; 6. Concluding remarks;
Bibliography



*He currently works as Ph. D Assistant professor at Complutense University of Madrid.
Before he worked as external consultant at European Central Bank, as (Ph. D) Assistant
professor at Pablo de Olavide University (Seville, Spain) and as research assistant at
Foundation centrA. He holds a Ph.D in Economics from Pablo de Olavide University
(with distinctions) and a Bachelor in Mathematics from University of Seville. His rese-
arch areas are mainly public economics and computational economics.
** He currently works as an Economist at the German Ministry of Finance. He was also
an Economist in the Fiscal Policies Division of the European Central Bank and worked
as a research assistant at the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW). He holds
a Ph.D. in Economics from Munich University (LMU). His research focuses on empiri-
cal public finance and fiscal policy.
***Is heading the Directorate General Fiscal Policy and International Financial and
Monetary Policy at the German Ministry of Finance. Previously, he worked at the
European Central Bank, the World Trade Organisation and the International Monetary
Fund. His recent research mainly focuses on public expenditure policies and reform and
the analysis of economic boom-bust episodes.



                                                                           289
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


       1. Introduction

          The outlook for public finances in the advanced economies for
       the second decade of the 21st century is extremely challenging, not
       least due to the substantial fiscal expansion that took place in the
       context of the financial and economic crisis. Public deficits in 2010
       averaged around 6% of GDP in the euro area and exceeded 10% of
       GDP in the US and the UK (Chart 1, panels a, and b). At the same
       time, public debt in advanced economies has increased signifi-
       cantly between 2007 and 2010: by some 20pp of GDP to around
       86% in the euro area and so far by 30pp or more in the UK (to 80%)
       and in the US (to over 90% of GDP). When including Japan, public
       debt in the G7 countries already averaged over 100% of GDP in
       2010.


             A closer look suggests that most of the deficit increase since the
       start of the crisis in 2007 was due to an increase in public expendi-
       ture ratios which have reached or approached historical highs. By
       contrast, revenue ratio declines have been rather limited (panels c
       and d). It is, therefore, logical to look at public expenditure when
       striving to correct fiscal imbalances in industrialised countries. This
       approach is in fact pursued already by a number of countries with
       fiscal difficulties. It was also the approach used—successfully—by


1 The views expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the authors’
employers. Correspondence to: A. Jesús Sánchez-Fuentes. Universidad Complutense de
Madrid. Campus de Somosaguas, 28223, Madrid (Spain). Tel: +34 913942542, Fax: +34
913942431. Email: antoniojesus.sanchez@ccee.ucm.es.


       290
The Future of the Euro


 Chart 1. Developments in public finances, 1990-2011
 a) Fiscal balance




b) Public debt




Source: Ameco.


                                                                 291
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



  Chart 1. (cont.) Developments in public finances, 1990-2011
  c) Total public expenditure




      d) Total revenue




      Source: Ameco.


292
The Future of the Euro


many advanced economies in the 1980s to return to sound public
finances and at the same time reinvigorate the economy.


   The case of the euro area is of special relevance for a number of
reasons. While the crisis-related deterioration of public finances in
the euro area as a whole has not been as pronounced as for example
in the US or Japan (see Chart 1), heterogeneity at the Member State
level is substantial. A number of countries, in particular Greece,
Ireland and Portugal, recorded double-digit deficit ratios and expe-
rienced significant increases in government debt as a ratio to GDP.
Unsustainable fiscal positions coupled with structural economic
weaknesses and competitiveness deficiencies, in turn, fuelled market
tensions which - due to strong financial interlinkages – undermine
financial stability in the monetary union as a whole. Therefore, at
the time of writing, there is a particular urgency for euro area coun-
tries to regain market confidence through a swift return to sound
public finances. At the same time, euro area membership tends to
exacerbate adjustment efforts since the exchange rate mechanism is
not available, preventing an external devaluation. Therefore, fiscal
consolidation and the restoration of external competitiveness need
to strongly rely on internal adjustment processes.


   Against the background, this study assesses expected public
expenditure developments of selected euro area countries for the
coming years. Based on the experience with expenditure reform in
the 1980s and 1990s, we argue that ambitious and high quality
expenditure reform as part of comprehensive economic reform pro-


                                                                   293
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


       grammes have the best chance of success. Furthermore, the role of
       a prudent expenditure rule and the relevance of having a suitable
       institutional framework are discussed.


             Section 2 reviews public expenditure trends over the past 30
       years. Section 3 reports on the main findings of earlier studies on
       public expenditure policies during the first decade of EMU. Section
       4 looks backward to the past to extract important conclusions on
       the successful strategy exit of current crisis. Section 5 provides an
       illustration on the preventive role of prudent expenditure rules
       before section 6 concludes and draws some policy lessons.




       2. Long-term public expenditure in industrialised countries

             With a view to assessing recent developments in a broader his-
       toric perspective, it is worth briefly taking stock of trends in public
       expenditure and the size of the state over the past 30 years (Table
       1).2 After a strong increase in the size of government in industria-
       lised countries in the 1960s and 1970s, the average total public
       expenditure ratio across OECD, G7 or euro area was broadly
       unchanged in 2007 -just before the financial crisis- from 2000, 1990
       and 1980. The average spending ratio for the euro area remained
       around 45% of GDP and that of OECD and G7 around 40%.



2 See also Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000) for more details on historic expenditure deve-
lopments.


       294
The Future of the Euro


 Table1. Total expenditure developments

                                                Maximum Change
                                                  value
                    1980                                    maxi-
% of GDP                    1990 2000 2007 2010
                 or nearest                                 mum
                                                Year Ratio to 2010

Austria            50,0     51,5     52,3     48,6     52,5   1995 56,4          -3,9
Belgium            54,9     52,3     49,1     48,3     52,9   1983 62,2          -9,2
Finland            40,1     48,1     48,3     47,2     55,1   1993 64,7          -9,6
France             46,0     49,6     51,7     52,6     56,6   2010 56,7          -0,1
Germany            47,4     44,2     47,6     43,5     48,1   1995 54,8          -6,7
Greece             27,0     45,2     47,1     47,6     50,2   2009 53,8          -3,6
Ireland            50,1     42,8     31,2     36,6     46,8   1982 54,2          -7,3
Italy              40,8     52,9     47,0     47,6     50,3   1993 56,3          -6,0
Luxembourg         48,4     37,7     37,6     36,3     42,5   1981 51,7          -9,2
Netherlands        55,2     54,9     44,8     45,3     51,2   1983 59,1          -7,9
Portugal           32,4     38,5     41,4     44,4     51,3   2010 51,3          0,0
Spain              31,1     42,1     39,3     39,2     45,6   1993 47,1          -1,4
Euro area (15)     4 5 ,4   4 7 ,9   4 6 ,2   4 6 ,0   51,0   1 9 9 5 5 3 ,1     - 2 ,1
Australia          32,5     35,4     35,5     33,4     38,5   1985 38,5          0,0
Canada             41,6     48,8     41,1     39,4     44,1   1992 53,3          -9,2
Denmark            52,7     55,4     53,7     50,8     58,5   1993 60,2          -1,7
Japan              33,0     31,6     39,0     35,9     41,1   1998 42,5          -1,4
Sweden             62,9     61,3     55,1     51,0     52,9   1993 71,7         -18,8
Switzerland        32,8     30,3     35,1     32,3     34,2   2003 36,4          -2,2
United
                   47,6     41,1     36,8     43,9     50,6   2009 51,5          -0,9
Kingdom
United States      34,2     37,2     33,9     36,8     42,5   2010 42,7          -0,2
G7                 3 8 ,3   3 9 ,8   3 8 ,5   3 9 ,9   45,0   2 0 0 9 4 5 ,5     - 0 ,5
OECD               3 9 ,1   4 0 ,2   3 8 ,8   3 9 ,8   44,6   2 0 0 9 4 5 ,2     - 0 ,6

 Source: Ameco, OECD.




                                                                                          295
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


             However, this masks significant differences across countries.
        The countries that undertook ambitious reforms in the 1980s and
        1990s typically had much lower spending ratios in 2007 than in
        1980 or at least than at their peak. A few countries, however, inclu-
        ding many of those that we will refer to in the next sections (US,
        Italy, Spain, Portugal, Greece, Ireland, UK) had significantly incre-
        ased the size of government between 1980 and 2007 or least in the
        2000-2007 period.3 This occurred notwithstanding an extended
        economic boom in most of these when expenditure ratios should
        have gone down.


             With the start of the financial crisis, public expenditure ratios
        went up everywhere by on average 5pp of GDP. This brought the
        total expenditure ratio to about 50% in the euro area and 45% in
        the OECD/G7 in 2010. For the euro area, the increase still consti-
        tutes a decline in overall spending since the previous peak in 1995
        but this was due to a lower interest bill. On the whole and for
        many countries, public expenditure ratios are now at or near his-
        torical peaks. This includes the European crisis countries, Portugal
        and Greece and the UK and US.


             These developments show that the challenge of containing the
        size of the state is more present than ever. And together with deficit
        and debt figures, the close link between rising public spending, defi-



3 See also Hauptmeier et al, 2011 for an assessment of the expenditure stance in euro
area countries since the start of EMU.


       296
The Future of the Euro


cit and debt figures is also obvious. But a number of countries mas-
tered the challenge of very large expenditure ratios with ambitious
reform programmes in the 1980s and 1990s. This experience will be
re-called in the next sections. These countries were typically not the
same that face such challenges now—except Ireland and the UK.




3. The first decade of EMU period: a missed opportunity?

   In this section, we examine expenditure developments and plans
of a number of euro area economies, notably Greece, Ireland and
Portugal (programme countries), Germany, France, Italy and Spain
(large euro area countries) in comparison to the UK and US. The
common feature of most of these countries (except Germany and
Italy) for the period up to 2007 was a drawn out economic boom
characterised by significantly positive output gaps. In principle, this
should have allowed bringing down public expenditure ratios signi-
ficantly, firstly, due to the impact of automatic stabilisers and,
secondly, in some cases also due to lower interest spending thanks
to the euro.


   However, this is not what happened. All countries pursued an
expansionary expenditure stance, of the order of 1-5pp of GDP
except for Germany (Hauptmeier et al, 2011).4 This basically “ate



4 One of analysing the expenditure stance of a country is to compare it with the expen-
diture levels that should have occurred if a country had followed certain fiscal rules.


                                                                           297
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


       up” the interest savings from introducing the euro. As a conse-
       quence, total public expenditure only went down significantly in
       Germany and even increased strongly in the three crisis countries
       and the UK between 1999 and 2007 (Table 2). In the US, total spen-
       ding grew by around 2pp of GDP between 2001 and 2006 but the
       ratio remained well below 40% of GDP. Together with the US,
       Ireland and Spain maintained the lowest spending ratios (below
       40% of GDP), France’s public expenditure was the highest, at 52.4%
       in 2007. The increase in public expenditure becomes even more
       pronounced when looking at primary spending. For the crisis coun-
       tries and the UK this went up by 3 to almost 6% of GDP between
       1999 and 2007. As a result, most of the sample countries still had
       significant deficits in 2007 while the debt ratio had hardly declined
       or even increased between 1999 and 2007 (Schuknecht, 2009).


             Expansionary expenditure policies during good times left most
       of the countries “unprepared” when the crisis hit. As a consequen-
       ce of the output fall and further expansionary programmes, public
       expenditure ratios increased strongly between 2007 and 2009/2010.
       Increases ranged from around 4pp of GDP in Italy and Germany, to
       6-7½ pp in the UK and US to over 10pp in Ireland. The expenditu-
       re increase was particularly strong in the countries where a credit-
       fed real estate and financial sector boom had “artificially” inflated



Such an exercise was conducted by us last year (Hauptmeier et al, 2011). The study
found that most euro area countries had pursued expenditure policies that were more
expansionary than a reasonable expenditure rule would have proposed.


       298
The Future of the Euro


Table 2: Recent total expenditure developments


           % of G DP            1999    2007 2009 2010              Change          Memoradum: deficit

                                                           1999-2007 2007-2010         2007           2010
Programme countries
Greece                          44,8    47,6   53,8 50,2      2,8            2,6       -6,8        -10,8
Ireland                         33,9    36,6   48,9 46,8      2,7            10,2       0,1        -11,3

Portugal                        41,0    44,4   49,9 51,3      3,4            7,0       -3,2           -9,8

Large euro area countries
Germany                         48,2    43,5   48,1 48,1      -4,7           4,5        0,2           -4,1
France                          52,6    52,6   56,7 56,6      0,0            4,0       -2,8           -7,1
Italy                           48,1    47,6   51,6 50,3      -0,5           2,6       -1,6           -4,5
Spain                           39,9    39,2   46,3 45,6      -0,7           6,4        1,9           -9,3

Large non-euro area countries
United States                   34,2    36,8   42,7 42,5      2,7            5,6       -2,8        -10,6
United Kingdom                  38,9    43,9   51,5 50,6      5,0            6,7       -2,7        -10,3


Table 2: Recent expenditure developments for selected countries

           % of GDP              1999          2007        2009         2010                 Change
                                                                                    1999-2007    2007-2010
Programme countries
Greece                           37,3          42,8        48,7         44,4           5,5            1,6
Ireland                          31,5          35,6        46,9         43,7           4,1            8,1
Portugal                         38,1          41,4        47,0         48,3           3,3            7,0

Large euro area countries
Germany                          45,1          40,7        45,4         45,4          -4,4            4,7
France                           49,6          49,9        54,3         54,2           0,3            4,3
Italy                            41,5          42,7        47,1         45,9           1,2            3,2
Spain                            36,4          37,6        44,5         43,7           1,2            6,1
Large non-euro area
countries
United States                    30,4          34,0        40,2         39,8           3,5            5,9

United Kingdom                   36,0          41,7        49,6         47,7           5,6            6,0


Source: Ameco


                                                                                                             299
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


Table 2: Recent cyclically adjusted primary expenditure developments

              % of GDP              1999      2007      2009   2010             Change

                                                                       1999-2007 2007-2010

Programme countries

Greece                              37,3       42,9     48,6   44,4       5,5            1,5
Ireland                             31,7       35,8     46,6   43,5       4,0            7,7
Portugal                            38,2       41,4     46,9   48,3       3,2            6,9

Large euro area countries

Germany                             45,1       40,9     45,0   45,2      -4,1            4,3
France                              49,7       50,1     54,1   54,0       0,4            4,0
Italy                               41,5       42,7     47,0   45,8       1,2            3,1
Spain                               36,5       37,7     44,3   43,4       1,2            5,7

Large non-euro area countries

United States                        0,0       0,0      0,0     0,0       0,0            0,0
United Kingdom                      36,1       41,7     49,5   47,6       5,7            5,9

Source: Ameco



GDP. When this reversed over the crisis, both higher spending and
lower GDP drove up the expenditure ratio. Virtually all of the
expenditure ratio increase was on public consumption and transfers
and subsidies; public investment went up only slightly in a few
countries. Greece, Ireland and Spain also reported higher interest
expenditure as the rapidly rising debt ratio and higher interest rates
started to affect public budgets.


      Where did countries stand in the third year of the crisis, 2010?
None of our sample countries still featured a relatively small public


300
The Future of the Euro


sector of below 40% of GDP (as defined by Tanzi and Schuknecht,
2000). Even the US, at 41.3% of GDP, featured a public sector that
was not much smaller than the euro area average before the crisis.
Greece, Portugal, France, Italy and the UK reported public spending
ratios of around to significantly above 50%.


   It has been argued that the increase in expenditure ratios is not
very relevant as it presumably reflects almost solely the crisis and
should, thus, reverse itself over time as the economy normalises.
This reasoning implicitly assumes that output levels and growth
rates will more or less return to pre-crisis levels. As a large output gap
would be closed, public commitments should decline relative to
GDP. However, if the pre-crisis GDP was artificially inflated by boo-
ming sectors which have to shrink then both GDP level and growth
rates may be significantly lower post-crises. If the 2010 output gap
was only small, 2010 deficits and expenditure ratios would in fact
represent structural features of the examined economies. In any
case, significant fiscal adjustment is needed which in some cases
exceeds 10 pp of GDP in the coming years (IMF, 2011).


3.1. A disaggregated assessment of past expenditure policies


   To assess in more detail what drove expenditure developments
since the start of EMU, this section provides an analysis the public
expenditure stance across the three main expenditure components
that governments can influence in the short term: government
consumption, transfers and subsidies and public investment. We


                                                                       301
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


       apply the same methodology as in Hauptmeier et al (2011): given
       the existing levels at the start of the EMU (1999), actual public
       expenditure developments are assessed against an expenditure
       path that should have been taken if countries had followed a neu-
       tral expenditure stance, i.e. if governments had aligned expenditu-
       re growth to that of potential GDP. The latter is measured on the
       basis of two expenditure rules: (a) nominal potential GDP growth
       (NPG rule) and (b) real potential GDP growth plus the growth rate
       of the GDP deflator capped at the ECB’s price stability objective of
       below but close to 2% (RPECB) based either on real time or ex post
       data. This counter factual analysis provides four measures of the
       expenditure stance.5 Deviations are analysed by looking at margi-
       nal (annual) and/or cumulative (total period) deviations (expressed
       as percentage of GDP). According to this procedure, on the one
       hand, marginal deviations help to identify the year(s) in which
       expansionary/restrictive policies were implemented. On the other
       hand, cumulative deviations measure the degree of expansio-
       nary/restrictive policies in percentage points (pp) of GDP accumu-
       lated over the period (1999-2010).


             Firstly, to provide a general perspective, we focus on cumulati-
       ve effects for the aggregate euro area (Chart 2), comparing actual
       and rule-based expenditure developments (expressed as percentage
       of GDP).



5 The earlier study applied six measures but the two additional ones did not provide
much additional insights.


       302
The Future of the Euro


Chart 2: Euro Area (12). Expenditures ratios as implied by a neutral expenditure
stance, across rules.
Primary expenditures




Public consumption




                                                                                   303
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


      Chart 2: (cont.) Euro Area (12). Expenditures ratios as implied by a neutral expen-
      diture stance, across rules.




      Public investment




304
The Future of the Euro


   Looking at the primary expenditures stance - panel a - suggests
a co-movement with the NPG rules which indicates the absence of
a prudence margin to operate when difficulties appear. Looking at
the disaggregated developments, i.e. the main expenditure compo-
nents, gives a different picture: First, the results for public con-
sumption show an expansionary expenditure stance on this cate-
gory adding up to 0.5-2pp of GDP, depending on the respective
expenditure rule. Second, for the transfers and subsidies compo-
nent, a strong counter-cyclical behaviour is observed, as one would
expect. However, the decreases in economic good times were much
less significant than the increases during the crisis. Finally, the pat-
tern for public investment is clearly pro-cyclical. At the same time,
the adjustments carried out by some countries during 2010 can be
already observed (returning to 2004 levels).


   To complement this general view, we briefly describe the
country pattern for the main expenditure components.6                    As in
Hauptmeier et al. (2011), for primary expenditures, we observe a
restrictive expenditure stance for Germany whereas all other coun-
tries show an expansionary policy stance over the 1999-2010
periods, notably as regards public consumption as well as transfers
and subsidies. However, the degree of expansion is different among
components. On the one hand, in the case of public consumption,
the magnitude of cumulative expansion ranged from near zero for



6 For the sake of brevity, related country-specific results are not included in the main
text. They are available from the authors upon request.


                                                                            305
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


France to up to 5pp of GDP for Ireland. On the other hand, for
transfers and subsidies, Germany is highly restrictive by 2-3 pp,
and the rest is expansionary by 1-7pp depending on the rule and
country.


      Finally, for public investment, the development of the cumula-
tive expenditure stance is quite interesting: restrictive for Germany
and Portugal, neutral for Italy and expansionary for all other coun-
tries with a tendency of neutralisation in 2010. However, overall
magnitudes are small.


      In a second step, we repeat this same exercise component by
component, in order to decompose the cumulative deviation
observed. This analysis provides a view of the respective stance of
each expenditure component. The list of indicators included is in
line with those presented so far; i.e. (i) public consumption, (ii)
transfers and subsidies, (iii) public investment, and (iv) other
expenditures. Moreover, we split our sample period into sub-
periods to show the role of (i)-(iv) before (1999-2007) and during
the crisis (2008 – 2009, 2009-2010).


      First, looking at the expenditures stance, Chart 3 presents the
decomposition of cumulative effects observed for ex-post and real-
time rules. When compared real-time and ex-post rules behaviour
both similarities and differences are found. While on the one hand
the dynamics are very similar, quantitative differences emerge
especially during sub-period (II), i.e. 2007-2009.


306
The Future of the Euro



       Chart 3: Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending ratios
       compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods

       (I) Real-time NPG rule. 1999-2007
%GDP




       (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 1999-2007
%GDP




                                                                                        307
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



        Chart 3. (cont.) Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending
        ratios compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods
        (I) Real-time NPG rule. 2007-2009
 %GDP




        (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 2007-2009
%GDP




308
The Future of the Euro



       Chart 3. (cont.) Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending
       ratios compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods
       (I) Real-time NPG rule. 2009-2010
%GDP




       (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 2009-2010
%GDP




                                                                                         309
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?




      An alternative way to look at these figures is going through the
different sub-periods. First, deviations in the pre-crisis period are
clearly dominated by public consumption. Moreover, if we leave
out Germany as the only restrictive country over this period, two
different country patterns can be observed: major deviations from
trend as regards public consumption in Italy, Spain and Ireland
while Greece and Portugal show strongly expansionary trends in
transfers and subsidies. Second, deviations from trend in transfers
become relatively more important with the start of the financial
and economic crisis.


3.2. Determinants of the expenditure stance


      An empirical analysis of factors that influence countries’ expen-
diture stances can provide further information on the determinants
of expansionary expenditure policies in the past. Hauptmeier et al.
(2011) therefore applied standard fixed-effects panel estimation
techniques on a sample of 12 euro area countries for the 2000-2009
period using the measure for the expenditure stance described
above, i.e. the (marginal) deviations of actual spending growth from
rule-based or neutral spending (under the NPG and the RPECB rule
in ex-post terms), as the dependent variable.


      The aim of this empirical exercise was to explain the govern-
ments’ expenditure stance on the basis of fiscal and macroecono-
mic factors, relevant institutional characteristics as well as political


310
The Future of the Euro


economy variables. The results of the analysis are presented in
Table 3.


   As one would expect, the macroeconomic environment measu-
red by the output gap (in % of potential GDP) constitutes an
important determinant of the expenditure stance. We find robust
support for a positive correlation between the output gap and the
expenditure stance across rules and estimations, suggesting a pro-
cyclical spending behaviour.


   As regards fiscal factors, surprisingly the level of public indeb-
tedness does not seem to significantly affect our measure of the
expenditure stance. We also do not find robust evidence for an
effect of revenue windfalls that arguably could increase spending
profligacy. We capture such windfalls by including the excess reve-
nue growth in a given year relative to previous year’s Autumn fore-
cast by the European Commission. However, while we see the
expected positive sign the effect is not significant.


   We find empirical support for the importance of political eco-
nomy factors. In particular, parliamentary elections at the national
level (Electoral cycle 1) tend to significantly increase the deviation
of actual from rule-based primary spending. The opposite holds true
for a second election-related variable (Electoral cycle 2) which cap-
tures the years left in the current election term. The negative sign on
this variable suggests that the incentives for fiscal discipline can be
expected to be higher at the beginning of the legislative period. We


                                                                    311
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


Table 3: Determinants of expenditure stance
Dependent variable: Deviation of primary spending growth from rule-based growth rate
Panel A: Ex-post Nominal Potential GDP (NPG) rule

                                            (I)        (II)        (III)        (IV)        (V )          (VI)        (VII)
Output gap (based on Potential GDP) 0,525         0,476       0,401        0,463       0,274       0,374         0,476
                                      [3.78]*** [3.01]** [2.50]** [3.04]**             [1.65]      [2.22]*       [3.00]**
Public debt ratio (t-1)               0,054     0,056    0,035 0,071                   0,042       0,033         0,057
                                      [0.96]      [1.04]      [0.62]       [1.20]      [0.83]      [0.67]        [1.03]
Crisis dummy                          3,946       3,649       4,028        3,138       2,241       2,34          3,341
                                      [2.17]*     [1.74]      [1.64]       [1.75]      [1.08]      [1.13]        [1.22]
Strenght of expenditure framework *
Output Gap                                        -0,262                                                         -0,262
                                                  [2.09]*                                                        [2.08]*
Surprises in Revenues growth                                  0,09
                                                              [0.46]
Strenght of expenditure framework *
Surprises in revenues growth                                  -0,08
                                                              [0.86]
Electoral cycle 1                                                          2,204
                                                                           [3.64]***
Electoral cycle 2                                                                      -0,812
                                                                                       [3.66]***
Government Stability                                                                               -2,699
                                                                                                   [3.26]***
EDP                                                                                                              0,308
                                                                                                                 [0.16]
Constant                              -2,941      -2,998      -1,47        -4,148      -0,006      -0,512        -3,079
                                      [0.72]      [0.77]      [0.39]       [0.97]      [0.00]      [0.13]        [0.78]

Observations                          108         108         108          108         90          90            108
Number of countries                   12          12          12           12          10          10            12
R-squared                             0,1         0,11        0,11         0,14        0,13        0,11          0,11
corr u_i and Xb                       -0,76       -0,76       -0,57        -0,79       -0,52       -0,47         -0,77
adjusted R-squared                    0           0,01        -0,01        0,05        0,01        -0,02         0

R-squared overall model               0,02        0,02        0,05         0,03        0,07        0,06          0,02
R-squared within model                0,1         0,11        0,11         0,14        0,13        0,11          0,11
R-squared between model               0,56        0,53        0,58         0,57        0,49        0,38          0,53
standard deviation of epsilon_it      4,52        4,51        4,54         4,42        4,15        4,2           4,53
panel-level standard deviation        2           2,13        1,43         2,55        1,24        1,05          2,17
fraction of variance due to u_i       0,16        0,18        0,09         0,25        0,08        0,06          0,19




312
The Future of the Euro


Table 3. (cont)
Panel B: Ex-Post Real Potential GDP +ECB price stability objective (RPECB) rule

                                             (I)        (II)        (III)        (IV)         (V)        (VI)     (VII)

Output gap (based on Potential GDP)   0,469        0,429       0,299        0,419       0,277       0,377       0,429
                                      [3.92]*** [2.74]** [2.39]** [3.20]*** [1.94]*                 [2.58]**    [2.72]**
Public debt ratio (t-1)               0,057        0,059       0,031        0,071       0,053       0,044       0,058
                                      [1.19]       [1.33]      [0.64]       [1.40]      [1.18]      [0.98]      [1.33]
Crisis dummy                          2,882        2,634       3,267        2,223       1,685       1,793       2,654
                                      [1.56]       [1.26]      [1.26]       [1.22]      [0.74]      [0.78]      [0.90]
Strenght of expenditure framework *
Output Gap                                         -0,219                                                       -0,219
                                                   [1.75]                                                       [1.74]
Surprises in Revenues growth                                   0,172
                                                               [0.91]
Strenght of expenditure framework *
Surprises in revenues growth                                   -0,044
                                                               [0.59]
Electoral cycle 1                                                           1,798
                                                                            [3.40]***
Electoral cycle 2                                                                       -0,798
                                                                                        [4.17]***
Government Stability                                                                                -2,544
                                                                                                    [3.48]***
EDP                                                                                                             -0,02
                                                                                                                [0.01]
Constant                              -2,808       -2,855      -0,747       -3,792      -0,392      -0,879      -2,85
                                      [0.75]       [0.82]      [0.22]       [0.97]      [0.10]      [0.23]      [0.83]

Observations                          108          108         108          108         90          90          108
Number of countries                   12           12          12           12          10          10          12
R-squared                             0,08         0,09        0,09         0,11        0,14        0,11        0,09
corr u_i and Xb                       -0,82        -0,82       -0,55        -0,83       -0,61       -0,58       -0,82
adjusted R-squared                    -0,02        -0,02       -0,02        0,01        0,01        -0,01       -0,03
R-squared overall model               0,01         0,01        0,04         0,01        0,07        0,06        0,01
R-squared within model                0,08         0,09        0,09         0,11        0,14        0,11        0,09
R-squared between model               0,61         0,61        0,58         0,62        0,4         0,37        0,61
standard deviation of epsilon_it      4,34         4,34        4,35         4,28        4,09        4,15        4,36
panel-level standard deviation        2,04         2,16        1,24         2,49        1,36        1,18        2,16
fraction of variance due to u_i       0,18         0,2         0,07         0,25        0,1         0,07        0,2

Notes: Baseline (I), Baseline + Institutional framework (II and III), Baseline + electoral
cycle and government stability , (IV - VI) and Baseline + European Institutions(VII).
Source: Hauptmeier, S., Sánchez-Fuentes, A.J. & Schuknecht, L. (2011)


                                                                                                                     313
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


       also control for government stability as measured by the respective
       index of the World Bank and find that the policy stance on the spen-
       ding side is less expansionary if a government scores a higher value.


             Most interestingly from a policy perspective, our results suggest
       that the country-specific institutional framework exerts a significant
       effect on the expenditure stance. In particular, we control for the
       extent to which national expenditure policy faces domestic institu-
       tional constraints using the expenditure rules index as developed by
       Debrun et al. (2008).7 We interact this index with the output gap to
       analyse to what extent strong institutions reduce spending profli-
       gacy and find that, indeed, the strength of the national institutional
       framework on the expenditure side significantly reduces the pro-
       cyclicality of the expenditure stance. This finding is along the lines
       of Holm-Hadulla et al (2010), Turini (2008) and Wierts (2008). At the
       same time, the EDP dummy which is included to capture whether a
       country is facing an excessive deficit procedure (EDP) due to deficits
       above the 3% of GDP reference value of the Stability and Growth
       Pact, does not turn up significantly in our regressions.


             The results on the impact of fiscal institutions may be put into
       the perspective of the recent efforts to strengthen the European fis-
       cal framework. One of the lessons from past fiscal developments in


7 For a definition and a detailed description of the computation of this index see
European Commission (2006) and Debrun et al. (2008). The index takes into account
the share of public spending covered by the rule and qualitative features such as the
type of enforcement mechanisms and media visibility.



       314
The Future of the Euro


euro area countries is that the implementation of the Stability and
Growth Pact has not been effective in delivering sound and sustai-
nable fiscal positions in Member States. While one has to be care-
ful when interpreting the non-significance of the effect of the EDP
procedure dummy, the result is in line with this perception.
Moreover, the empirical analysis suggests that national budgetary
rules if well-designed can help to effectively reduce spending pro-
fligacy and therefore serve as important tools to promote sound
and sustainable public finances in line with the European fiscal fra-
mework. This reinforces the need for enhancing national fiscal
rules and frameworks as had been proposed by the European
Commission in the autumn of 2010.


3.3. Implications for public debt


   Based on the analysis presented in Section 3.1, it is possible to
compute to what extent deviations of expenditure growth from
trend led to increases in government debt. Chart 4 shows alterna-
tive debt paths for the sample economies and across expenditure
rules. Consistent with the previous results, real time rules typically
lead to higher debt paths than ex-post rules. In the case of France,
for example, following a neutral expenditure path since 2000
would have resulted in a significantly lower debt ratio in 2010, i.e.
between 70% and 75% of GDP. If Italy had followed a neutral spen-
ding path, public debt would now stand roughly between 80% and
100% of GDP in 2010, rather than at around 120% of GDP.




                                                                   315
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


      For a second group of countries (Spain, Greece, Ireland and
Portugal), the difference becomes even more drastic. Neutral spen-
ding policies in Portugal would have led to debt ratios of 40-60% of
GDP in 2010 rather than over 80% of GDP in reality. Spanish debt
would have been at a trough of 10-40% in 2007-08 and would have
remained well below the reference value in 2009 under all rules.
Ireland would have just about eliminated all its debt in good times
and thus created significant room for the subsequent rise. Under all
rules, debt would have remained below 60% of GDP in 2010.
Finally, Greek public debt would have fallen to 60-80% of GDP (rat-
her than remain broadly constant around 100% of GDP until the
start of the crisis) and increased much more slowly in the crisis.


      All in all, public debt positions in the euro area would have
been much sounder at the start of the crisis and in 2010, if euro
area countries had pursued at least a neutral expenditure stance on
average during EMU. Public debt could have been well around or
below the reference value in the euro area in most of its members
by 2010 and nowhere above 100% of GDP.




4. Looking backward to the past, lessons for the future? an
episodes based approach

      In an earlier study, Hauptmeier, Heipertz and Schuknecht
(2007) looked at the experience with public expenditure reform in
the 1980s and 1990s. They found that there were basically two


316
The Future of the Euro



Chart 4: Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based
Euro area (12)




Germany




                                                                317
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



      Chart 4: (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based
      France




      Italy




318
The Future of the Euro



Chart 4. (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based
Spain




Greece




                                                                        319
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



      Chart 4: (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based
      Ireland




      Portugal




320
The Future of the Euro


reform waves in industrialised countries. Moreover, they found
that there were three groups of countries: (i) ambitious, (ii) timid
and (iii) non-reformers. Ambitious reformers were those that
managed to reduce public primary (non interest) expenditure by
more than 5pp of GDP from their peak within 7 years. Timid refor-
mers were those that cut primary spending between 0 and 5pp and
non-reformers never undertook much of a cut at all. These coun-
tries and country groups, the time and size of the maximum expen-
diture ratio and the change in the expenditure ratio within years
(T7) as reported in Hauptmeier et al. (2007) are depicted in Table 4.


   The study argued that conceptually, reforms needed to be ambi-
tious in order to make a significant difference for the resulting
public deficits and adverse debt dynamics. The more ambitious they
were the more they would even allow tax cuts. Already in the 1980s,
Ireland, Belgium, the UK, Luxembourg and the Netherlands had sig-
nificantly reduced their public expenditure ratio. The UK, Ireland
and the Netherlands did so again in the 1990s plus a number of
other countries: Finland, Sweden, Canada and Spain. Four countries
reduced public primary expenditure by more than 10% of GDP.
During this period, 10 countries undertook timid expenditure
reforms (amongst them the US, France, Germany and Italy at which
we will look again later). The three non-reformers included
Australia, which had always maintained a rather small government
sector, and Portugal and Greece.




                                                                   321
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


Table 4: Expenditure reform phases 1980s and 1990s

                                     Max. primary expenditure   Change maximum
                                              in year                to T7
Ambitious' reformers
Finland                                        1993                  -14,0
Sweden                                         1993                  -14,0
Ireland (Phase 1)                              1982                  -12,4
Belgium (Phase 1)                              1983                  -12,3
Canada                                         1992                   -9,5
United Kingdom (Phase 1)                       1981                   -8,2
Netherlands (Phase 2)                          1993                   -7,5
United Kingdom (Phase 2)                       1992                   -7,2
Spain                                          1993                   -6,4
Ireland (Phase 2)                              1992                   -6,2
Luxembourg                                     1981                   -5,7
Netherlands (Phase 1)                          1983                   -5,1

Timid' reformers
Austria                                        1993                  -4,3
Denmark                                        1993                  -3,9
New Zealand                                    1985                  -3,8
United States                                  1992                  -3,4
Italy                                          1993                  -3,0
Japan                                          1998                  -2,7
Belgium (Phase 2)                              1993                  -2,1
Germany                                        1996                  -0,6
France                                         1996                  -0,5
Switzerland                                    1998                  -0,3

Non' reformers
Portugal                                       2004                   0,0
Greece                                         2000                   0,4
Australia                                      1985                   0,4



      It is, however, not just the magnitude of spending and reform
that is important but also the composition. The literature (e.g.,
Alesina and Perotti, 1995 and 1997) argues that reductions in
public consumption/wages and transfers and subsidies are particu-
larly “high quality”. They increase the chance of success of reform
by providing a strong signal of “willingness” and cuts tend to focus
on unproductive expenditure.


322
The Future of the Euro




  Table 5 illustrates that much of the expenditure cuts of
ambitious reformers came from transfers and subsidies and also
from government consumption. About two-thirds of the reduc-
tion in the total expenditure ratio and over 80 per cent of the
decline in the primary expenditure ratio occurred in these two
categories. Nine out of 11 reform episodes reported a decline in
public consumption by more than 2 per cent of GDP and eight
out of 11 featured a fall in transfers and subsidies by over 3 per
cent of GDP. At the same time, in most cases, government
investment and public education expenditure did not decline
disproportionately or in some cases even increased as a share of
GDP. Timid reformers did not report much of a decrease in
public transfers and subsidies and focussed on public invest-
ment in some cases and on public consumption including edu-
cation in others.


  The study by Hauptmeier et al. (2007) also argued that public
expenditure reform needed to be part of a comprehensive overall
structural reform strategy. It was argued on the basis of the litera-
ture that this would allow the improvement in public finances not
only via less spending but also via better growth prospects. An
overview of the reforms undertaken by ambitious countries is
reported in Table 6. Most of the ambitious reformers undertook
major reforms that were complementary to expenditure retrench-
ment. Most countries strengthened their national fiscal institu-
tions. This not only facilitated fiscal retrenchment but also tended


                                                                   323
324
      Table 5: Composition of expenditure reform


                                                                                                    Transfers
                                    Total       Interest     Primary     Government    Government
      Change T0-T7                                                                                     and      Health   Education   Pensions
                                 expenditure   Spending    expenditure   consumption   investment
                                                                                                    Subsidies

      Ambitious'
      reformers
      Finland                       -15,7        -1,6         -14,0         -3,8          -0,3        -9,4       -1,3      -1,8        -1,5

      Sweden                        -15,7        -1,8         -14,0         -2,8          -0,9        -8,0       -0,4       0,2        -1,7

      Ireland (Phase 1)             -13,3        -1,0         -12,4         -5,2          -3,2        -2,2       -1,7      -0,9        -0,7

      Belgium (Phase 1)             -10,9        -4,8         -6,2          -3,9          1,0         -4,7       -0,5      -0,9        -1,6

      Canada                        -11,4        -1,7         -9,5          -5,3          -0,5        -3,3       -1,1      -1,9        -0,2

      United Kingdom (Phase 1)      -10,5        -2,3         -8,2          -2,5          -0,3        -2,0       -0,3      -0,8        -0,5

      Netherlands (Phase 2)         -9,8         -2,3         -7,5          -1,9          0,1         -6,5       -0,8      -0,4        -1,2

      United Kingdom (Phase 2)      -7,1         0,1          -7,2          -2,7          -1,1        -2,6       -0,1      -0,8        -0,4

      Spain                         -8,2         -1,8         -6,4          -1,5          -1,0        -4,1       -0,4       0,0        0,2

      Ireland (Phase 2)             -10,9        -4,8         -6,2          -3,9          1,0         -4,7       -0,5      -0,9        -1,6

      Luxembourg                    -5,9         -0,4         -5,7          -1,4          -2,1         0,0       0,1       -1,6        -0,8

      Netherlands (Phase 1)         -5,0         0,2          -5,1          -2,0          -0,2        -2,2       -0,1      -1,1        0,4
                                                                                                                                                Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?
The Future of the Euro


to make future budgetary control and thus the avoidance of fiscal
problems more likely.8                  A number of countries devalued their
currencies. All ambitious reformers initiated significant labour
market reforms that improved work incentives. All but one
country reformed the tax system. And most countries reduced the




Table 6: Summary findings for ambitious reform episodes


                   Expenditure reform                                           Structural reform

                                           Institutional Other macroeco- Labour
                   Public
                            Transfers &       reform      nomic reform market
                consumption                                                       Taxation Privatisation
                            subsidies 1/                                 incenti-
                     1/
                                                                           ves

Ireland 1           XX           XX            X               X            X        X              X
Ireland 2            X           XX            X                            X        X              X
Sweden               X           XX            X               X            X        X              X
Canada              XX           XX            X                            X        X              X
Finland             XX           XX            X               X            X        X              X
Belgium             XX           XX                            X            X
Netherlands 1        X            X            X               X            X        X
Netherlands 2        ~           XX            X                            X        X              X
Spain                ~           XX            X                            X        X              X
UK 1                 X            X            X               X            X        X              X
UK 2                 X            X            X                            X        X

All                  9           11            10              6           11        10             8



8 For the importance of fiscal rules and institutions, see, e.g., Poterba and Von Hagen
(1999). Debrun et al. (2008) and Holm-Hadulla et al (2011) focus on the numerical fis-
cal rules in EU countries.


                                                                                               325
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


role of the state in the economy via privatisation.
      Based on the fact that the reforming countries fulfilled the con-
jectures of ambition, high quality and comprehensive reforms it is
not surprising that the impact on public finances and the economy
were quite positive, compared to timid reformers (Chart 5). Panel
a) shows that ambitious reformers (here differentiating early and
late reformers) brought the public expenditure ratio down signifi-
cantly to levels similar or lower than those of timid reformers. This
was mainly achieved through cuts in public consumption and
transfers and subsidies while public investment did not change
much, at least for late ambitious reformers (see panels b)-d)). Panel
e) illustrates that public deficits were brought down very substan-
tially by ambitious reformers. The group of late reformers even rea-
ched sizable surpluses. As regards public debt developments (panel
f)), timid reformers did not achieve any significant reversal in debt
dynamics. Ambitious reformers, by contrast, managed to bring
debt down once fiscal balances had been sound enough.


      Contrary to the concerns of vocal special interests and politi-
cians, ambitious expenditure reforms had very little (if any) adver-
se growth impact even in the very short run while the medium to
long term impact was very positive. Ambitious reformers experien-
ced a significant increase in trend growth by 1-2 percentage points
(panel g). By contrast, timid reformers experienced no such incre-
ase. Real private consumption started to recover as of the first year
of public expenditure reduction and accelerated more strongly
where ambitious reforms were undertaken (panel g). Private invest-


326
The Future of the Euro



Chart 5: Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s.
a) Total public expenditures




b) Public consumption




                                                                   327
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



      Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s.
      c) Transfers and subsidies




      d) Public investment




328
The Future of the Euro



Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s.
e) Fiscal balance




f) Public debt




                                                                           329
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?



      Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s.
      g) Trend growth




      h) Real private consumption




330
The Future of the Euro



   Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s.
   i) Private investment




   Source: Hauptmeier, S., Heipertz, M. & Schuknecht, L. (2007)



ment initially declined or was flat and showed a relatively less
favourable trend than for timid reformers but this reversed in the
medium term. In the seventh reform year, the private investment
ratio of timid reformers had increased by 1pp of GDP while that of
ambitious reformers had increased by 2-3pp (panel i).


  In a next step we assess recent and projected fiscal develop-
ments for 2012 and 2013 in selected euro area countries as well as
the UK and the US in the light of the evidence from past expendi-
ture reform periods described above. We do this on the basis of the
latest European Commission forecast (Autumn 2011) (see Table 7).
For the US we consider the latest IMF World Economic Outlook


                                                                              331
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


projections. For all sample countries, the projections point to sig-
nificant primary expenditure reductions for the period up to 2013
(with the exception of France). This ranges from about 3-4pp of
GDP for Germany, Italy and the US to over 5pp in the UK and
Spain and to 7 to 10pp in the EU/IMF programme countries.
Expenditure reductions show a more or less linear pattern in most
countries. In the case of the US, the primary expenditure ratio
went down quite strongly in 2010. However, it is expected to decli-
ne only by another 1pp of GDP over 2011-13.

        Table 7: Expenditure plans


              % of GDP                              Primary expenditure

                                       Actual                     Forecast
                                     2009   2010   2011   2012    2013    2013 to max(0910)

Programme countries
Greece                               48,7   44,4   43,6    42,4   41,7          -6,9
Ireland                              46,9   43,7   42,1    39,6   37,0          -9,9
Portugal                             46,9   48,3   44,9    42,0   39,9          -8,4

Large euro area countries
Germany                              45,4   45,4   43,3    43,2   42,8          -2,6
France                               53,8   54,2   54,0    54,3   53,9          -0,3
Italy                                47,1   45,9   44,8    43,8   43,0          -4,1
Spain                                44,5   43,7   40,8    39,8   39,3          -5,2

Large non-euro area countries
United States                        42,1   39,3   39,6    39,0   38,5          -3,7
UK                                   49,6   47,7   46,8    45,3   43,9          -5,6

        Sources: Actual and forecasts: EU Commission (Ameco), IMF for the US.




332
The Future of the Euro


  If projected spending developments materialise, primary expen-
diture ratios would decline to around 40% of GDP in most coun-
tries. The main exception is France where the ratio would remain
significantly above 50%.


  Projected spending developments should also be assessed from
a longer term perspective. When comparing the 2013 figures to the
1999 primary expenditure ratios it is noteworthy that spending
would still be 1-7pp of GDP higher in 2013 than in 1999 for 8 out
of 9 countries. This relative increase would be particularly sizeable
for Ireland, the US and the UK and appears unwarranted in view of
the expected ageing-related increases in social security outlays in
the medium and long-term. Only Germany would post a signifi-
cantly lower primary expenditure ratio than at the start of EMU.


  Coming back to the adjustment effort in countries’ expenditure
plans, it is noteworthy that five countries (Ireland, Greece,
Portugal, Spain and the UK) would meet the criteria of ambitious
reformers as applied in the earlier study by Hauptmeier et al. (2007)
whereas a second group of countries could be classified as “timid”
reformers (Germany, USA, and Italy).




5.The need for prudent expenditure rules

  The evidence presented in this study supports the view that
public spending has been a major determinant of unsound public


                                                                   333
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


finance developments in the past. Looking forward, it therefore
seems plausible to address this fact through the implementation of
prudent expenditure rules. Indeed, empirical studies suggest that
well-designed expenditure rules tend to limit the pro-cyclicality of
public spending (see, e.g. Holm-Hadulla et al (2010)). Recent policy
action in Europe goes in this direction. Notably, the EU fiscal sur-
veillance framework has been extended by a so called “expenditu-
re benchmark” which restricts the growth rate of public spending
net of discretionary tax measures to that of potential growth.
However, this new rule does not take into account some of the pro-
blems we identified in Section 3.1. Most notably, an effective rule-
based restriction of spending policies in real-time requires the
maintenance of a margin of prudence. This is necessary to account
for the tendency of overestimating potential GDP growth in real-
time. Given the past experience of systematic and persistent down-
ward revisions in potential growth, a margin of prudence of ½ pp
in expenditure growth per annum appears warranted. In addition,
excessive price developments should not automatically feed into
higher expenditure growth as expansionary fiscal policies may
accelerate an economic overheating. Therefore, the nominal com-
ponent of an effective expenditure growth rule should be capped,
e.g. at the ECB’s price stability objective (“close to but below 2%”).


      Chart 6 shows that the application of such prudent expenditu-
re growth rules during EMU would have resulted in much safer fis-
cal positions. Primary expenditure ratios would have reached
much lower levels in 2009. As a result, also public debt ratios in


334
The Future of the Euro


Chart 6: Actual ratios versus neutral expenditure policies-based ratios (based on
NPG – ½ pp and RPECB – ½ pp rules), 2009
Panel A: Primary expenditure ratios




Panel B: Public Debt ratios




Note: Includes GDP multiplier and compound interest effects.




                                                                                    335
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


2009 would have generally been much closer to 60% of GDP with
the highest ratio of around 90% in Italy. It is important to note,
however, that the proposed expenditure rules are intended to pro-
vide guidance for an appropriate, i.e. neutral, policy stance in the
absence of fiscal imbalances. Any fiscal adjustment, e.g. to regain
sound fiscal positions in the aftermath of the crisis, would of cour-
se require a restrictive policy stance, i.e. spending growth rates
below potential GDP growth.




6. Concluding remarks

      What are the main findings of this study and what policy lessons
can be drawn? Public finances in advanced economies are at a cross-
roads. In the fifth year of the crisis, fiscal deficits remain high and
public debt has reached unprecedented peace-time levels in most
industrialised countries. Public primary expenditure stands at or
near historical peaks in many countries and therefore constitutes an
important determinant of the fiscal imbalances. It therefore seems
straight forward to focus on expenditure restraint when striving to
regain sound fiscal positions in the aftermath of the crisis.


      In the 1980s and 1990s a number of countries undertook ambi-
tious expenditure reforms. Their experience, which was briefly
reviewed here, has been very positive. Within a few years from the
start of expenditure reform, public expenditure ratios went down
significantly, fiscal deficits largely or fully disappeared, public debt


336
The Future of the Euro


was brought on a downward path, and economic growth and pri-
vate consumption resumed swiftly. We argue that this was because
ambitious expenditure reform was conducted in a growth-friendly
manner as part of comprehensive adjustment programmes.


  Our study emphasises the key role of expenditure policies in
explaining fiscal developments during EMU in the euro area. It finds
that, almost all euro area countries (with the notable exception of
Germany) applied expansionary expenditure policies already before
the crisis. This resulted in much higher expenditure and debt paths
compared to a counterfactual neutral expenditure stance. Rules-
based spending policies could have led to much safer fiscal positions
much more in line with the EU’s Stability and Growth Pact (SGP).


  The policy recommendations from these findings are obvious:
countries should focus on reducing public spending in the context
of ambitious reform programmes. Spending based consolidation
efforts need to be complemented by structural reforms, notably
with a view to removing rigidities in national labour and product
markets, to reduce macroeconomic imbalances, improve competi-
tiveness and support potential growth. This will be particularly
important for the vulnerable countries in the euro area which do
not have available the exchange rate mechanism to improve exter-
nal competitiveness. Latest projections suggest that governments’
consolidation plans in a number of countries indeed put a focus on
reducing government expenditure as a ratio to GDP in the coming
years. However, the benefits of reforms are only going to materia-


                                                                   337
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


lise under one condition, namely that all these plans are fully and
adequately implemented. This is their main challenge.


      In addition, the empirical evidence on the determinants of euro
area countries’ expenditure stance provide a number of policy
implications. First, strong national budgetary institutions seem to
limit expansionary spending biases. Second, the European institu-
tional framework needs to feature prominently expenditure moni-
toring and control. The incorporation of an expenditure bench-
mark in the preventive arm of the Stability and Growth Pact in the
context of the recent “Six-Pack” reform therefore constitutes a step
in the right direction. An effective enforcement of this rule should
help to limit overly expansionary spending policies in the future.


      Furthermore, this chapter argues that a potential growth rule
with an extra ½ percentage point deduction from the resulting
annual expenditure growth targets would be a sufficiently prudent
and, thus, advisable expenditure rule for euro area countries. As
economic (e.g., population aging) and political economy reasons
suggest that overestimating potential growth could also occur in
the future, such a rule could provide a reasonably prudent bench-
mark for a neutral expenditure stance looking forward.


      How does the debate on the overhaul of European economic gover-
nance fare against these conclusions? At the time of completing this
study (March 2012), EU member states have set up new EU economic
governance principles with a view to ensuring a tighter and more


338
The Future of the Euro


effective surveillance of economic and fiscal policies at the European
level. At the same time, policy makers have agreed - in the context of
the new fiscal pact - to strengthen national fiscal frameworks.


   All in all, a stringent implementation and enforcement of the
fiscal surveillance at European level could well ensure the necessary
break with past expenditure trends and thus also secure sustainable
deficits and debt dynamics in the future. However, it remains to be
seen whether the main obstacle of the “old framework”—lack of
incentives and enforcement—is really sufficiently remedied.




Bibliography

- Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1995) Fiscal expansions and adjustments in
OECD countries, Economic Policy, vol. 10, pp. 205–48.


- Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1997) Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries:
Composition and macroeconomic effects, IMF Staff Papers, vol. 44, pp. 210–48.


- Brück, T. and R. Zwiener (2006) Fiscal policy rules for stabilisation and
growth: A simulation analysis of deficit and expenditure targets in a mone-
tary union, Journal of Policy Modeling, 28, 357–369.


- Cimadomo, J. (2008) Fiscal policy in real time, Working Paper 919,
European Central Bank.




                                                                         339
Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?


- Coenen, G, C., Erceg, C. Freedman, D. Furceri, M. Kumhof, R. Lalonde, D.
Laxton, J. Lindé, A. Mourougane, D. Muir, S. Mursula, C. de Resende, J. Roberts, W.
Roeger, S. Snudden, M. Trabandt and J. in’t Veld (2010) Effects of fiscal stimulus
in structural models, Working Paper, 10/73, International Monetary Fund.


- Debrun, X., L. Moulin, A. Turrini, J. Ayuso-i-Casals and M. Kumar
(2008) Tied to the mast? National fiscal rules in the European Union,
Economic Policy, 23 (54), 297–362.


- European Commission (2006) Public finances in EMU - 2006, European
Economy, 3, Brussels.


- Hauptmeier, S., M. Heipertz and L. Schuknecht (2007) Expenditure
reform in industrialised countries: a case study approach, Fiscal Studies,
28 (3), 293-342.


-     Hauptmeier, S., A.J. Sánchez-Fuentes and L. Schuknecht (2007)
Towards expenditure rules and fiscal sanity in the euro area, Journal of
Policy Modeling, 33, 597-617.


- Holm-Hadulla, F., S. Hauptmeier and P. Rother (2010) The impact of
numerical expenditure rules on budgetary discipline over the cycle, Working
Paper 1169, European Central Bank.


- International Monetary Fund (2011) Shifting Gears Tackling Challenges
on the Road to Fiscal Adjustment, IMF Fiscal Monitor, April 2011,
Washington D.C.


340
The Future of the Euro


- Menguy, S. (2008) A dynamic rule applied to the threshold imposed on the
European budgetary deficits, Journal of Policy Modeling, 30, 1093–1105.


- Morris, R. and L. Schuknecht (2007) Structural balances and revenue
windfalls - the role of asset prices revisited, Working Paper 737, European
Central Bank.


- Poterba, J. and J. Von Hagen (eds.) (1999) Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal
Performance, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.


- Schuknecht, L. (2009) Booms, Busts and Fiscal Policy. Public Finances
in the Future? London: Politeia.


- Schuknecht, L. (2011) Fiscal activism in booms, busts and beyond, forth-
coming in Banca d’Italia, 2011.


- Tanzi, V. and L. Schuknecht (2000) Public Spending in the 20th century:
a global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.


- Turrini, A. (2008) Fiscal policy and the cycle in the Euro Area: The role of
government revenue and expenditure, European Economy - Economic
Papers 323, European Commission.


- Van Riet, A. (ed.) (2010) Euro area fiscal policies and the crisis,
Occasional Paper 109, European Central Bank.


- Wierts, P. (2008) How do expenditure rules affect fiscal behaviour?, DNB
Working Paper 166.
                                                                          341

More Related Content

PDF
Previsiones 2017 Circulo de Empresarios
PPT
La crisis del euro
PDF
Ante la crisis de España y del euro
PPT
Dossier crisis del euro.
PDF
Naturaleza y causas de la crisis del euro por José Carlos Díez
PPTX
Crisis en la Euro Zona
PDF
PDF
Así está the economy... December 2016 Circulo de Empresarios
Previsiones 2017 Circulo de Empresarios
La crisis del euro
Ante la crisis de España y del euro
Dossier crisis del euro.
Naturaleza y causas de la crisis del euro por José Carlos Díez
Crisis en la Euro Zona
Así está the economy... December 2016 Circulo de Empresarios

Similar to The Future of the Euro (Brown book 2012) (20)

PDF
Santander International Banking Conference “Solutions for growth and stability”
PDF
Role of Spanish banks in Spain’s Debt Crisis
PPT
Part 3 finance class summer 2010 forum nexus
PDF
POLICY PAPER-MOU Impact on Cyprus, Gr. & Portug. Economies.-CCEIA-FINAL-4.11.15
PPT
Spain
PDF
Van Rompuy y Rajoy
PDF
The European crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance by Jue...
PDF
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis by José Carlos Díez
PDF
Money Deficits and Inflation Evidence and Policy Issues of Euro Zone during D...
DOCX
Lessons From the European Union 2013
PDF
Report on The need for a common fiscal policy in the eurozone
PDF
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis by Jaime Requeijo
PDF
Cyprus Bailout: A big risk for Europe (and the World)
PDF
Davos the nordic way
PDF
Viviane Reding
PDF
Conclusions for europe 2018
PDF
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
PDF
PDF
European Commission: A European Economic Recovery Plan
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
Santander International Banking Conference “Solutions for growth and stability”
Role of Spanish banks in Spain’s Debt Crisis
Part 3 finance class summer 2010 forum nexus
POLICY PAPER-MOU Impact on Cyprus, Gr. & Portug. Economies.-CCEIA-FINAL-4.11.15
Spain
Van Rompuy y Rajoy
The European crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance by Jue...
Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis by José Carlos Díez
Money Deficits and Inflation Evidence and Policy Issues of Euro Zone during D...
Lessons From the European Union 2013
Report on The need for a common fiscal policy in the eurozone
The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis by Jaime Requeijo
Cyprus Bailout: A big risk for Europe (and the World)
Davos the nordic way
Viviane Reding
Conclusions for europe 2018
Decomposing the Growth of Portugal: A Case for Increasing Demand, not austeri...
European Commission: A European Economic Recovery Plan
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
Ad

More from Círculo de Empresarios (20)

PDF
Así está la economía... abril 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
PDF
Economy at a glance... April 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
PDF
Así está la empresa... febrero 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
PDF
Business... at a glance February 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
PDF
Economía-a-la-sombra-de-la-geopolítica-Informe-Trimestral-Febrero-2024-Circul...
PDF
Economy in the shadow of geopolitics-Quarterly-Report-February-2024-Circulo-d...
PDF
Corruption Perceptions Index 2023
PDF
Índice de Percepción de la Corrupción 2023
PDF
Economy at a glance... January 2024
PDF
Así está la economía... enero 2024
PDF
Así está... la empresa enero 2024_Circulo_de_Empresarios
PDF
Business... at a glance January 2024
PDF
Economy at a glance... December 2023
PDF
Asi esta la economia...diciembre 2023
PDF
Attractiveness for investment and venture capital 2023
PDF
Atractivo para la inversión y el capital riesgo 2023
PDF
Economy at a glance... November 2023
PDF
Asi esta la economia...noviembre 2023
PDF
Business at a glance... November 2023
PDF
Así está la empresa... noviembre 2023
Así está la economía... abril 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
Economy at a glance... April 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
Así está la empresa... febrero 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
Business... at a glance February 2024 Círculo de Empresarios
Economía-a-la-sombra-de-la-geopolítica-Informe-Trimestral-Febrero-2024-Circul...
Economy in the shadow of geopolitics-Quarterly-Report-February-2024-Circulo-d...
Corruption Perceptions Index 2023
Índice de Percepción de la Corrupción 2023
Economy at a glance... January 2024
Así está la economía... enero 2024
Así está... la empresa enero 2024_Circulo_de_Empresarios
Business... at a glance January 2024
Economy at a glance... December 2023
Asi esta la economia...diciembre 2023
Attractiveness for investment and venture capital 2023
Atractivo para la inversión y el capital riesgo 2023
Economy at a glance... November 2023
Asi esta la economia...noviembre 2023
Business at a glance... November 2023
Así está la empresa... noviembre 2023
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
Neurology of Systemic disease all systems
PPTX
pharmaceutics-1unit-1-221214121936-550b56aa.pptx
PPSX
namma_kalvi_12th_botany_chapter_9_ppt.ppsx
PPTX
MMW-CHAPTER-1-final.pptx major Elementary Education
PDF
anganwadi services for the b.sc nursing and GNM
PPTX
IT infrastructure and emerging technologies
PPTX
operating_systems_presentations_delhi_nc
PDF
Disorder of Endocrine system (1).pdfyyhyyyy
PPTX
4. Diagnosis and treatment planning in RPD.pptx
PPTX
Math 2 Quarter 2 Week 1 Matatag Curriculum
PPTX
Thinking Routines and Learning Engagements.pptx
PDF
WHAT NURSES SAY_ COMMUNICATION BEHAVIORS ASSOCIATED WITH THE COMP.pdf
PDF
Unleashing the Potential of the Cultural and creative industries
PPTX
Neurological complocations of systemic disease
PPTX
ACFE CERTIFICATION TRAINING ON LAW.pptx
PDF
GSA-Past-Papers-2010-2024-2.pdf CSS examination
PDF
faiz-khans about Radiotherapy Physics-02.pdf
PPTX
CHROMIUM & Glucose Tolerance Factor.pptx
PPTX
Cite It Right: A Compact Illustration of APA 7th Edition.pptx
PDF
Physical pharmaceutics two in b pharmacy
Neurology of Systemic disease all systems
pharmaceutics-1unit-1-221214121936-550b56aa.pptx
namma_kalvi_12th_botany_chapter_9_ppt.ppsx
MMW-CHAPTER-1-final.pptx major Elementary Education
anganwadi services for the b.sc nursing and GNM
IT infrastructure and emerging technologies
operating_systems_presentations_delhi_nc
Disorder of Endocrine system (1).pdfyyhyyyy
4. Diagnosis and treatment planning in RPD.pptx
Math 2 Quarter 2 Week 1 Matatag Curriculum
Thinking Routines and Learning Engagements.pptx
WHAT NURSES SAY_ COMMUNICATION BEHAVIORS ASSOCIATED WITH THE COMP.pdf
Unleashing the Potential of the Cultural and creative industries
Neurological complocations of systemic disease
ACFE CERTIFICATION TRAINING ON LAW.pptx
GSA-Past-Papers-2010-2024-2.pdf CSS examination
faiz-khans about Radiotherapy Physics-02.pdf
CHROMIUM & Glucose Tolerance Factor.pptx
Cite It Right: A Compact Illustration of APA 7th Edition.pptx
Physical pharmaceutics two in b pharmacy

The Future of the Euro (Brown book 2012)

  • 1. BROWN BOOK ANDRÉS DOMINGO AND DOMÉNECH VILARIÑO / XXVIII EDICIÓN DEL LIBRO MARRÓN The Future of the Euro DÍEZ GANGAS / DONGES / GARCÍA ANDRÉS / GROS Y ALCIDI / MARTÍNEZ RICO / REQUEIJO GONZÁLEZ / SÁNCHEZ FUENTES, HAUPTMEIER AND SCHUKNECHT / BROWN EDITION BOOK XXVIII The Future of the Euro El futuro del euro The Brown Book in 2012 meets his XXVIII edition. Year after year since 1984, this flagship publication of the Círculo de Empresarios has offe- red the most varied backgrounds a platform from which to contribute their ideas and proposals on economic policy that requires our country to its further development. The Brown Book contributes to one of the founding objectives of the Círculo as the center of the view that encourages and promotes debate on key issues for the benefit of Spanish society as a whole. JULIO 2012 CÍRCULO DE EMPRESARIOS C/ MARQUÉS DE VILLAMAGNA, 3, 10ª. 28001 MADRID TEL 915781472. FAX 915774871 www.circulodeempresarios.org July 2012
  • 2. The Future of the Euro Brown Book Madrid, July 2012 EDITION SPONSORED BY
  • 3. © 2012, Círculo de Empresarios C/ Marqués de Villamagna, 3, 28001 Madrid The partial or total reproduction of this publication, or its hand- ling by software, or its transmission under any circumstance or by any means, whether electronic, mechanical, by photocopies, recording or other means, without the express written consent of the copyright holders, is strictly forbidden. The articles reflect the opinions of the contributors, and not necessarily those held by Círculo de Empresarios. Legal deposit: M-24161-2012 Design of collection: Miryam Anllo [email protected] Illustration: María José Ruiz Publishing: Loft Producción Gráfica C/ Martín Machío, 15-1º. 28002 Madrid (Spain) Printed by Atig, S.L. Parque Empresarial Neinor - Henares edificio 3 - nave 10 4
  • 4. The Future of the Euro Index Prologue 7 1. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession 15 Javier Andrés and Rafael Domenech 2. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis 63 José Carlos Díez 3. The European crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance 97 Juergen B. Donges 4. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity 131 Gonzalo García Andrés 5. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments 197 Daniel Gros and Cinzia Alcidi 5
  • 5. 6. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain 227 Ricardo Martínez Rico 7. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis 265 Jaime Requeijo 8. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? 289 A. Jesús Sánchez Fuentes, Sebastian Hauptmeier and Ludger Schuknecht 6
  • 6. Prologue The crisis in Spain is, to a large extent, the crisis of the Euro. On the one hand, the sustainability or otherwise of the monetary inte- gration project hinges on Spain, as the fourth economy in the Eurozone. On the other, Spain has no leeway available for fiscal sti- mulus packages, and the success of its adjustments required stabi- lity in the Eurozone. Hence, both crises are the two sides of the same token. The crisis faced by Euro economies and the adjustments made and which will be made in the most vulnerable ones, are coming at a high price which has not yielded tangible results to date. Círculo de Empresarios believes that the current situation calls for an impro- vement in European institutional architecture, in regard to greater integration and, above all, more commitment to reforms in Spain. The natural environment of our country is the Eurozone. Over the last few weeks, citizens are beginning to live with the different rescue modalities, as they had already done with the risk premiums. Financial aid for troubled economies is quite diverse in terms of implications, instrumentation, conditionality and scope of application, therefore requiring detailed analysis for determination. Although each carries its benefits and disadvantages, in the opi- 7
  • 7. nion of Círculo de Empresarios, the greater scope and conditionality scenarios – known as country-rescue – are not a desirable option. This is why these must be avoided. Indeed, an intervention or rescue, of its own accord, without advancements made in the Eurozone architecture, shall not protect any of its members from future scares. Domestic adjustment may be less effective if no advancements are made in fiscal and banking union, and in the European capacity to provide asymmetrical res- ponses to national situations which are also different. The most vulnerable countries in the Eurozone must no longer be perceived as foreign currency debtors and it is imperative that the coordina- tion of economic policies of Member States is improved. Without such adjustments, a sustained growth path will not be possible to achieve. On the other hand, the crisis in Spain is the result of an accu- mulation of imbalances due to a series of inadequate signals and policies. Spain must face up to its responsibilities in terms of fiscal consolidation and structural reform. All in the interest of recove- ring competitiveness and encouraging a suitable environment to attract growth-contributing investments. In such circumstances, Círculo de Empresarios cannot help but take part in the debate on the future of the Euro. The XXVIII edi- tion of the Brown Book is dedicated to this matter and gathers a varied number of authors, all with broad experience in the issue 8
  • 8. and proven academic and professional records. Therefore, this publication, with the sponsorship of BBVA as in previous years, maintains its nature as a publication which is open to different ideas and opinions, not necessarily shared by Círculo de Empresarios. As in previous editions, the articles appear in alphabetical order by the surnames of their authors, although these can be grouped into three broad categories: the crisis of the sovereign debt in Europe and the future of the Eurozone; the reform of economic governance and operations of the institutions in order to solve the sovereign debt crisis in Europe; and the integration into the Eurozone, the fiscal coordination mechanisms, Eurobonds and the assignment of sovereignty. In their paper, Javier Andrés and Rafael Doménech analyse the challenges faced by the Eurozone and the proposals to handle them by improving economic governance. To this end, they begin by reviewing the reasons underlying the accumulation of signifi- cant imbalances in developed economies and among EMU coun- tries, mainly from 2001 until the start of the crisis in 2007, as a result of an unsustainable growth pattern in many developed eco- nomies. Secondly, the magnitude and implications of such imba- lances and the heterogeneity between EMU countries are closely examined. Finally, the authors analyse the challenges involved in the improvement of economic governance of the EMU on the fis- cal, financial and economic integration fronts, which will determi- ne its short and long term economic future. 9
  • 9. José Carlos Díez analyses the Euro crisis. He reviews the histori- cal background of the European and single currency projects, and the theory of exchange rates to provide conceptual support to ena- ble an understanding of the nature and the causes of the crisis. According to him, this is an infrequent, but highly destructive, dise- ase found in economics, especially in developed countries, since it causes devastating damage to the employment and public debt of the affected countries. For this reason, he believes it is essential to come up with the correct diagnosis in order to define the economic policy that will put an end to the crisis. The main causes analysed are financial integration, the under-assessment of risk, local imba- lances within the Eurozone and the Great Recession. The aim of Juergen B. Donges is to bring the current debate on the need for economic governance in the European Union, and par- ticularly in the Eurozone, into the context of political realities. He analyses the issue of governance from a historical and current pers- pective, and highlights the significant fact that the Eurozone does not constitute an optimal monetary area. He then moves on to analyse the forms of governance to date and considers new approa- ches to European governance. Finally, he ends his analysis with a tone of moderate expectation. If the Governments of the Euro countries understand that the solidity of public finances and the application of struc- tural reforms are their responsibility and act in accordance, no State must rush to the aid of another due to over-indebtedness and overspending, and the ECB may stop indirectly funding the States and focus on its own duty, which is to ensure the stability of the price levels within the Eurozone. 10
  • 10. Gonzalo García Andrés highlights that, despite having taken decisive steps in national policies and institutional framework reform, the Euro crisis has worsened to the point of calling its sur- vival into question; and no definitive solution is yet on the hori- zon. In his article he attempts to offer an interpretation of what has happened, assuming the extreme complexity both of the starting point (with accumulated imbalances and structural deficiencies in several countries), as of the outbreak, the contagion and the esca- lation of the crisis. And he does so in the broader context of the global financial crisis, which has affected economic and financial development for five years, in order to determine which specific aspects of the Euro have played a key role. All this with a view to encouraging a reflection on solutions, bringing together the most urgent and the ones with a longer term effect. Cinzia Alcidi and Daniel Gros point out that the Eurozone cri- sis encompasses different dimensions, from foreign debt and current account balance problems, to the weak situation of the ban- king sector. The document focuses on this last issue, the situation of the banking system, and attempts to show the way in which current characteristics of the regulatory framework of the financial market have influenced the development of the crisis. In addition, they express their concern about the false idea that the recently sig- ned fiscal convention shall become the fundamental ingredient of the recipe to overcome the crisis, when the banking sector conti- nues to be heavily indebted and exposed to the vicissitudes of sove- reign States. For this reason, they present a few ideas to break the 11
  • 11. close ties between governments and banks, since these links them in a common fate and constitute a clear impediment to recovery from the crisis in the Eurozone. Ricardo Martínez Rico, throughout his work, analyses the way in which the sustainability of public finances requires a sold fiscal institution and a firm political commitment by European govern- ments. Subsequently, he tackles the close relationship between fis- cal rigour, macroeconomic stability and growth, concluding that, in order to achieve a positive inter-relation, the establishment of fiscal rules which are simple, transparent, automatically applied and with preventive control mechanisms for all Public Administrations, is essential. All these items are key when designing a fiscal policy which contributes to recovering the credibility required by Europe along its route towards greater integration to handle the sovereign debt crisis. Lastly, he examines the measures taken in Europe and Spain since the start of the sovereign debt crisis, and reflects on the next steps that should be taken towards a fiscal institution. The work of Jaime Requeijo aims to provide a reasoned expla- nation of the causes of the financial shocks affecting several Eurozone countries, and which endanger the survival of the single currency (the Monetary Union is a poorly built structure because political urgency has prevailed over economic prudence; the fiscal irresponsibility of many member state governments has translated into the appearance of large public debt; such debts generate doubts as to their holders; and, contributing factors such as the 12
  • 12. effects of contagion or of the opinions of the rating agencies and IMF predictions). In the article he also attempts to reply to three questions on the measures taken, the results thereof, and the impact of a potential decomposition of the euro. The article ends with a brief final reflection on the solution to be applied in order to maintain the Monetary Union. A. Jesús Sánchez-Fuentes, Sebastian Hauptmeier and Ludger Schuknecht state in their article that an ambitious fiscal reform within a broader programme of reforms would have highly positi- ve effects insofar as it would provide for a safer fiscal position, in line with the requirements of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). Expenditure control policies must therefore go hand in hand with structural reforms, mainly focused on reducing rigidity in the labour and product markets, on the correction of macroeconomic imbalances, on the improvement of competitiveness and on sus- taining potential growth. This becomes particularly key for the most vulnerable countries in the Eurozone, which no longer have the option of currency devaluation to increase competitiveness. Finally, and on behalf of Círculo de Empresarios, I wish to thank all the authors for their contributions to this new edition of the Brown Book and I trust that these articles help to shed light on a solution to the European trilemma. Mónica de Oriol President of Círculo de Empresarios 13
  • 13. /JAVIER ANDRES * / RAFAEL DOMENECH**/ The future of the Euro after the Great Recession 1 Summary; 1. Introduction; 2. From the Great Moderation to the Great Recession; 3. The imbalances in Europe and in the EMU; 4. The new European governance and the future of the Euro; 4.1. Changes in fiscal governance; 4.2. Financial integration; 4.3. Economic integration; 5. Conclusions. Summary In this chapter we shall analyse the challenges the Eurozone is facing and proposals to deal with them via improved economic governance. To do so, * Javier Andrés is professor of Fundamentals of Economic Analysis at the University of Valencia and visiting professor of the University of Glasgow. http://iei.uv.es/javierandres/ ** Rafael Doménech is Chief Economist of Developed Economies, BBVA Research and Professor of Fundamentals of Economic Analysis at the University of Valencia. http://iei.uv.es/rdomenec 1 The authors thank A. Deligiannido, A. García, M. Jiménez, and E. Prades for their assis- tance and comments on this work, as well as the help from CICYT projects ECO2008- 04669 and ECO2011-29050. 15
  • 14. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession we shall first examine the reasons behind the accumulation of significant imbalances in the developed economies and among the EMU countries, mainly since 2001 until the crisis in 2007, as a result of a pattern of unsus- tainable growth in many developed economies. Secondly, we shall offer an in-depth analysis of the significance of such imbalances and the heteroge- neity which exists between EMU countries. Lastly, we shall study the cha- llenges presented by the improvement of the economic governance of the EMU from a fiscal, financial and economic integration perspective, which shall determine its economic future in the short and long term. 1. Introduction The international economic crisis which begun in 2007 is having an extraordinary impact on the European economy, and for the coming decades, will leave a deep mark in many of its mem- bers. The crisis has shown that the growth process undergone bet- ween 1994 and 2007, particularly following the creation of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) in 1999, had entered into an unsustainable dynamics in the long term. The appearance of important macroeconomic imbalances among EMU members was taking shape within the framework of steady growth, inflation under control, very low interest rates and a very reduced risk assess- ment (partly as a result of the disappearance of currency risk) in the context of a world saving glut. Although the Eurozone as a whole presents smaller aggregate imbalances in terms of deficit and pri- vate, public and foreign debt than, for instance, the US or the United Kingdom, the expectations of economic convergence 16
  • 15. The Future of the Euro among Eurozone countries and the appearance of financial bubbles with the promise of high yields, led to very significant capital flows among its members. This added to a spiralling increase in house- hold debt and businesses in some of the member countries, gene- rating very considerable and longstanding deficits in current account balances. These expectations petered out sharply as of the subprime crisis of 2007 and, since then, Europe has been experien- cing different surges of financial crises, economic crises and sove- reign debt crises, which have been following on and feeding off each other over time.2 The result of this complex situation has been that, albeit with differences in the intensity and the severity of the problems (see, for instance, Doménech and Jiménez, 2010), a sig- nificant number of European countries have experienced a situa- tion similar to that of the sudden stops experienced in the past by some emerging economies, leaving public and private sectors heavily indebted and, in some cases, extremely high rates of unemployment. The aim of this chapter is to analyse the changes required by the EMU and proposals with which to face such challenges with suc- cess. In order to understand what the problems are and, therefore, their possible solutions, in the second section we analyse the rea- sons why important imbalances accumulated in the developed eco- nomies and among the EMU countries during one of the most sta- ble periods of economic prosperity in the last decades (the Great Moderation), which nevertheless gave way to an unsustainable 2 Shambaugh (2012) performs an excellent analysis of the interaction between fiscal, financial and economic crises in the Eurozone. 17
  • 16. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession growth pattern in many economies. In the third section, we offer an in-depth analysis of the magnitude and implications of such imbalances throughout the crisis, which are well summarised in the Excessive Imbalance Procedure (EIP) recently implemented by the EU, as well as the current heterogeneity among EMU countries. The fourth section analyses the challenges of improvement of economic governance of the EMU from a fiscal, financial and economic inte- gration standpoint, which shall determine its short and long term economic future. Lastly, the fifth section presents the main conclu- sions reached in this paper. 2. From the Great Moderation to the Great Recession In the period between the mid-1990s and 2007, developed eco- nomies enjoyed one of the greatest economic growth periods, known as the Great Moderation due to the low volatility of growth rates in those years. Graph 1 shows evidence of this for the US and the EMU in terms of GDP per person of employable age. As can be seen, from the mid-1990s to 2007 there was sustained growth, with levels well above the historical trend estimated since 1970 for both geographical areas. In fact, the growth in GSP per person of emplo- yable age was slightly higher in the EMU than in the US, although not enough to bridge the gap between both economies. The Great Moderation generated the perception that economic cycles would have less volatility, as a result of better managed eco- 18
  • 17. The Future of the Euro nomic policy (see, for instance, Galí and Gambeti, 2009, or the references appearing in this article). In fact, these high growth rates with low volatility came hand in hand with inflation under con- trol and low interest rates across the board of financial assets, with practically inexistent risk premiums in many cases as a result of the underassessment of the risk. In light thereof, some analysts went as far as to proclaim the disappearance of the economic cycle and the capacity to avoid significant economic recessions. It was the com- binations of these forces which fed the financial imbalances which, for economists like Rajan (2005) or Borio & White (2005), among others, are behind the crisis which began in 2007. There are various economic factors which contributed to genera- te this combination on which the Great Moderation was erected. In the first place, the central banks of the developed economies carried out a low interest rate policy or money glut, as a result of: i) the drop in the inflation of sellable assets following the inrush of exporting countries in the international economy with a very abundant and cheap workforce and depreciated currencies; ii) the benign neglect policy in regard to the high prices of financial and real estate assets (Bordo & Jeane, 2002, or Bean 2004 & 2010); and iii) the attempt to prevent the recession in the US, following the burst of the techno- logical bubble, or in Germany, following the costly process of reu- nification and the burst of its real estate bubble. Secondly a savings glut took place on a worldwide level in China, Japan, Germany, oil producing countries or the pension 19
  • 18. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession funds of developed economies. Thirdly, and as a response the savings glut in some countries and sectors, a formidable increase took place in the demand of safe assets, moving from the pre-eminence of individual savers to that of large sovereign funds, investment funds or pension funds which prioritize safety over yield and which seek to channel savings towards fixed income rather than towards the acquisition of any other kind of asset. At the same time that the demand for safe financial assets (i.e. AAA) increased, there was a relative scarcity of such assets in the case of sovereign debt, due to the fiscal consoli- Chart 1 GDP per person of employable age in the US and in the EMU Source: OEDC (2012) Economic Outlook Database. 20
  • 19. The Future of the Euro dation taking place simultaneous in many developed economies as a result of the high growth in GDP. This surplus demand for safe assets created enormous pressure in the financial markets and in certain types of assets, which in turn led to the appearance of bub- bles in certain market segments. The pressure was such that finan- cial deregulation and engineering came to the rescue, enabling the response of the financial markets to this scarcity in AAA assets to be the creation of multiple derivatives and the issue of huge volu- mes of asset backed securities, as shown in Graph 2. In turn, this generated enormous liquidity to fund those assets acting as the underlying assets (for example, mortgages on homes), thus crea- Chart 2 Issue of Asset backed Securities 1985-2011 Source: SIFMA 21
  • 20. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession ting a circle in which asset demand stimulated supply, which in turn was fed back into the process by boosting demand with the creation of new assets. As a result of this process, a specialization in asset production took place on an international level, leading to enormous hetero- geneity by country, sector and agents. Whereas some countries generated a surplus in net savings, others (US, Spain or Ireland) res- ponded to the very low interest rate incentive by generating the real investments which served as the underlying assets for finan- cial securities. The US produced assets on a world scale considered safe by the markets, thanks to the specialization of its financial ser- vices. Other countries, such as Spain and Ireland, carried out a similar role, but on a European scale, producing assets backed by safe collateral (homes) or with no collateral, but issued by financial institutions deemed to be safe, which attracted savings funds or large European banks. In fourth place, the creation of the EMU meant the disappearan- ce of exchange rate risk among its members. This removed an impor- tant barrier to capital flows within the EMU and encouraged the pre- viously described process. But its effects went even beyond the disap- pearance of currency risk. In the international financial markets, as well as in the EMU countries, expectations that the greater monetary and economic integration ensured the economic convergence of its members were generated, which justified the disappearance of any type of risk premiums (see Ehrmann et al, 2011). 22
  • 21. The Future of the Euro Graph 3 clearly shows the almost full disappearance of risk pre- miums for countries becoming part of the EMU. Without doubt, Greece was a paradigmatic example of this process, going from fun- ding at 25% in 1993 to do at the same interest rate as Germany, follo- wing its entry into the Eurozone. Chart 3 10 year public debt interest rates in the EMU, 1995-2011 Source: ECB, Bloomberg The implications of such expectations of economic convergence were very important in terms of imbalances in the current balance. Under the assumption that a real and economic convergence pro- cess was taking place, well beyond the nominal, it seemed natural that capital should flow towards the economies with lower per capi- 23
  • 22. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession ta incomes, as economic theory predicts (see, for example, Barro, Mankiw & Sala-i-Martin, 1995). In fact, as the risk premiums were disappearing, the correlation between the savings rated and investment rate were reduced. As was already anticipated by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002), since 1999 to the start of the crisis, the Feldstein-Horioka paradox disap- peared completely, as shown in Graph 4. Coinciding with the reduction in the typical deviation of risk premiums, which reached Chart 4 Typical deviation of risk premiums and correlation between the rate of investment and the rate of savings, EMU, 1993-2011 Source: Bloomberg 24
  • 23. The Future of the Euro almost zero as of 1998, the correlation between the national invest- ment rate and the savings rate was observed to have been nil or even negative, compared to the positive and statistically significant values of the beginning of the nineties. In fifth place, a permissive regulation, together with reduced interest rates and very high competition in the financial sector generated the incentives required for the generation of profit to be done via transaction volume instead of via price margins (mainly interest rates), favouring a very important leveraging of broad seg- ments of the private sector. One of the results of this process was the intensification of a new banking business model, based on the granting of collateral backed loans, the generation of financial assets from such loans and the distribution thereof as asset-backed securities in asset packages (originate to distribute) which transfe- rred credit risk in full to the purchasers of these new generated assets. Compared with the traditional bank business, in which financial institutions that grant the credits keep the risk on their balance sheets, this new business model led to greater intercon- nection of the balance sheets among financial institutions all over the world and a significant increase in contagion risk. 3. The imbalances in Europe and the EMU The financial crisis was preceded by a period of economic prospe- rity, measured by conventional indicators of growth, macroecono- 25
  • 24. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession mic stability and inflation, during which enormous imbalances of a financial and competitive nature have been created. However, a glance of the macroeconomic picture of the EMU reflects a situation of balance which we do not find in other important economic regions of the world (Table 1). Both the deficit and public debt levels and the net foreign positions and private indebtedness are generally lower to those recorded in the United States or the United Kingdom. However, the EMU has had other problems hanging over it which have led the economy of the region – and that of the whole of the EU by extension – to the situation of stagnation which it is currently undergoing. Some of these problems are of a structural nature, and others are related to the extraordinary disparities between member states in their key indicators to which, until very recently, we had paid little attention. Among the first are demographic evolution and low productivity growth which in turn have provoked a limited rate of growth in employment. But the disparities and the heterogeneity within the EMU are the most outstanding imbalances, as they call for a serious amendment in the operation of the Euro, whose main objective was to accelerate convergence among countries who adop- ted the single currency along with other common institutions. The European Commission has recently implemented a pro- gramme to monitor a number of indicators to detect and track macroeconomic and financial imbalances in countries within the EU (the EIP). One of these indicators summarises, over all others, the nature of the main problem facing the European economy: 26
  • 25. The Future of the Euro the gradual and persistent disparity in the current account of its member countries. Although the EMU and the EU are economies which can be described as economies which contribute (and demand) little net savings to (and from) foreign savings, their aggregate results is the sum of extremely disparate realities. As Lane (2010) points out, in 2010 European countries accounted for approximately one third of all current account deficits and sur- pluses worldwide. As can be seen in Graph 5, the current account deficits and surpluses of the EMU have gradually polarised from levels ranging between the [-3%-, +3%] interval, in proportion to the GDP to position itself outside of this range and even persis- tently above it by 5%. The underlying causes and macroeconomic implications of this type of imbalance are extremely complex. Table 1 Debts and deficits in the EMU, US and United Kingdom (% GDP) EA17 US UK Budget balance of 2011 -4.4 -9.6 -8.9 public administrations Debt of public 2011 87.6 100.0 84.8 administrations Household debt 2010 67.3 92.1 106.1 Corporate debt 2010 119.1 74.6 123.7 Current account 2011 0.1 -3.1 -2.7 balance Net international 2010 -7.2 -17.0 -13.9 position Sources: AMECO, Haver, IMF, national sources and BBVA Research 27
  • 26. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession It is true that this polarisation is not an exclusively European phenomenon, as it happens in parallel with the so-called “global imbalances” generated during the recent globalisation process. However, in contrast to what is happening on a world scale and par- ticularly in a series of developed countries (the Anglosphere) and emerging countries (particularly China) in Europe there is a positi- ve correlation between levels of income per capita and sales deficit, so that the capital flows from the more advanced countries to the less developed. This has rendered such imbalances less conspicuous, as they have been associated with the real convergence process. The traditional view considered foreign indebtedness as a natural con- sequence of the catching up process during which the countries undergoing rapid growth required foreign savings to fund strong domestic investment in commercial goods. Thus, the availability of savings and the Euro allowed for the funding of the productivity convergence without financial and exchange rate strangulation. The international allocation of savings was deemed to be optimal (“consenting adults”, Obstfeld, 2012), and there was no reason for public political intervention – what became known as “benign neglect” by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002) or Edwards (2002). It is not easy to determine an optimal level, or even an adequate one, for the current account deficit which already reflects the gap between domestic savings and investment in a country which is assumed to have been optimally determined by consumers and busi- nesses, unless it is associated with high public deficit, in which case we would be dealing with a fiscal problem. Moreover, a country may 28
  • 27. The Future of the Euro have a deficit current account without having a serious foreign financing problem, or may have it despite having a regularised account, in this case because despite a reduced net capital flow, what matters in the event of a financial crisis is the size of the gross flows, as nothing guarantees that national savers are willing to fund domestic liabilities should the international markets become una- vailable. However, the evolution of the current account of EMU coun- tries (EU) reflects more deep-rooted problems where the adjustment role of the market mechanism has proven insufficient and in which gross financial flows have grown in a fast and imbalanced way. Chart 5 Current account balance (% GDP) Source: BBVA Research with data from national sources 29
  • 28. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession The deficits have not been linked with productivity convergen- ce, as is evident in the cases of Spain, Portugal and, to a certain extent, Ireland, which accumulated growing deficits despite the slow growth of total productivity of the factors. As can be seen in Graph 6, productivity grew by 1% on average, whereas the current account balance varied between surpluses over 5% (the Netherlands and Germany) and deficits of 10% (as in Portugal and Spain). In fact, it has not only been the lure of investment but mainly the fall in savings in peripheral countries which has caused the gap in commercial deficit which has exceeded both in volume – percentage of GDP – and in persistence, that observed in many emerging countries prior to the crisis of the eighties and nineties. Moreover, much of the foreign financing to the receiving countries has not been channelled through direct and portfolio investment, but by way of bank bonds, which increases the risk of bank crises and ‘sudden stops’ (Jaumotte and Sodsriwiboon, 2010; Land, 2010). However, the most worrying characteristic of the unequal per- formance of the current account in Europe is its persistence. Far from being a transitory phenomenon, the divergence between commercial balances has sharpened until 2007 (see Graph 5). The design of the Euro took into account that the absence of own currency would hinder the traditional adjustment to which most countries resorted in times of crisis in the balance of payments. The impossibility of this recourse to devaluation has not come hand in hand with the strengthening of real devaluation mecha- 30
  • 29. The Future of the Euro nisms, that is, with a more flexible response by prices and salaries. Between 2000 and 2010, enough time has lapsed to have expected that the countries with most foreign debt and strong real apprecia- tions should have begun a process of correction towards a surplus in the commercial balance. Nevertheless, this has not been the case. The correlation between the commercial deficit and the net foreign position was positive in 2011 and in 2010 (Graph 7) as it had been in the last decade, indicating that the private savings/investment balance does not seem to respond to the cumu- lative net foreign position. Chart 6 Current Account Balance in 2007 (% of GDP) and average productivity growth bet- ween 2000 and 2009. Source: BBVA Research based on AMECO 31
  • 30. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession In 2010 only four EMU countries had a net positive foreign posi- tion – Belgium, Germany, the Netherlands and Finland – and only Finland had managed it after correcting a very negative position in 2001 (that is, after a decade of foreign rapid growth and surplus). Practically all other EMU countries saw their net indebtedness increase substantially or, at best, such as in France or Austria, they managed a moderate reduction thereof within the first ten years of the single currency. Therefore, the performance of the current account is a very use- ful indicator – although naturally not infallible – of the way in which a country responds to the commercial and financial globa- lisation process and to the existence of other types of imbalances associated with private sector debt, both financial and non-finan- cial. Before reviewing these indicators for the EMU (EU), it is worth asking why the (market) adjustment mechanisms have failed in this case and what the risk of this situation is happening again in the future. The conventional current account approach indicates that financial flows are a mere counterpart of commercial flows, so that sustainability of foreign debt must be guaranteed by the expecta- tion of future current account surpluses or, what is the same, by a significant proportion of the commercial goods production in the economy. Foreign financing is no at risk while foreign investors consider the economy to be competitive. The domestic economy must maintain a high productivity growth rate and competitive 32
  • 31. The Future of the Euro labour costs, as the opposite would render the foreign deficit unsustainable, foreign investment would drop, reducing prices and salaries and improving the foreign balance. In this way, given rea- sonable elasticity in the demand of exports and imports, the periods of real appreciation and foreign deficit can be reversed wit- hout deep structural changes. However, this market mechanism has not worked in peripheral Europe. Foreign funding has been used to a large extent to fund Chart 7 Current account balance and net international position Source: BBVA Research based on Eurostat 33
  • 32. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession non-commercial goods, leading to strong expansion of demand, of prices and of labour costs (see Graph 8). Despite the loss of com- petitive capacity, the appeal for foreign lenders continues provided the value of the asset with real guarantees – such as homes – con- tinues, which is perceived as relatively safe. Thus, the worsening competitiveness is the effect and not only the cause for the dete- rioration of the current account. But the existence of high com- mercial deficit is not corrected of its own accord nor is it done in a smooth and orderly manner. When the bubble bursts and prices of the assets used as guarantees plummet, foreign investors perceive that the national economy is no longer able to guarantee their debt, leading to the well-known processes of flight to quality, increase in the cost of debt and, in extreme cases, to sudden stops. This integration process has led to a number of other imbalan- ces in the European economies. The objective of the EIP is to go beyond the control of deficit and debt, and to follow a number of economic indicators which enable the detection of inadequate macroeconomic development in a country and can lead to locali- sed financial crises and even contagion in the future. Such indi- cators come hand in hand with a number of ‘limits’ that are con- sidered to be security measures which, when exceeded by a country, special tracking must be carried out by the Commission. If an economy is showing imbalance in several of these indicators, it must propose a plan of action for correction thereof which, if not suitably applied, might result in some form of political or eco- nomic penalty. The list of indicators is the following (the limits 34
  • 33. The Future of the Euro above which a form of relevant imbalance is detected appear in brackets): current account balance (% GDP, -4%, 6%); net inter- national position (% GDP, -35%); real effective exchange rate (variation rate, -5%, 5%); export market share (growth rate, -6%); nominal unitary labour cost (growth rate, 9%); cost of housing (growth rate, 6%); credit flow to private sector (% GDP, 15%); pri- vate sector debt (% GDP, 1605); public debt (% GDP, 60%); and unemployment rate (10%). Chart 8 Growth of nominal salaries and real productivity Source: BBVA Research based on Eurostat 35
  • 34. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession The first report issued on the monitoring of these indicators shows that in the third year since the start of the crisis (2010), the imbalances accumulated in recent years are far from being correc- ted, some of them having worsened since 2007 (Table 2). Greece, Portugal, Ireland and Spain are the countries with worse qualitati- ve results. They belong to the Eurozone periphery, where they fail in at least five of the ten criteria.3 It is within the framework of such imbalances that we must interpret the fiscal crisis that has been reflected in the general growth of risk premiums of sovereign debt in Europe, especially in peripheral countries – although not exclusively. The levels of public debt in the EMU are comparable to those in the rest of the develo- ped world, both if we consider the region as a whole or the coun- tries within it separately. As is shown in Graph 6, only in 2008 three EMU countries (Greece, Italy and Belgium) had a public debt above that of the US and in any case much lower than that of Japan. The growth in public debt during the crisis period places EMU countries – with the exception of Greece and Ireland – in the realm of 20%, similar to what had happened in most of the deve- loped countries. Therefore, behind the sovereign debt crisis there are issues related to the economic governance of the EU in general and the Eurozone in particular. But also, deeper reasons which have 3 The situation is worse if we take into account that indicators such as the growth rate of housing prices and credit for the private sector are nowadays within the limits accep- ted by the MIP as a result of the extraordinary restriction on credit suffered by most EU economies. 36
  • 35. The Future of the Euro become evident following the segmentation of the financial mar- kets due to the crisis. On the one hand, we have the demographic and structural characteristics of most of the countries, which herald for the future a scenario of lesser growth than that before the crisis. Graph 9 shows the growth rates up to 2007 and the fore- casts made by the IMF up to 2015 for EMU countries, the United Kingdom, Japan, and the US. The aging population and its effects on participation in the labour market, the low savings rates – with the ensuing difficulties in funding investments – and the slow rate of productivity growth explain such expectations, which in turn severely affect the capa- city to absorb the strong increase in public indebtedness. In second place, the economic crisis itself has generated an additional burden on public finances by way of contingent liabili- ties, the realisation of which shall depend on the performance of the private debt and the need to apply measures to assist in the reconversion of the financial sector. As stated by Reinhart & Rogoff (2008 and 2009), one of the main consequences of financial crises is that a large part of the private sector debt becomes public. Table 3 (ECB, 2012) shows the impact on public finances of the two main contingent-type averages within the EMU: provisions for the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and the guarantees for the banking sector. The sum of both would mean an additional impact on the public debt in the EMU of almost 13% of the GDP. It is true that such contingencies do not necessarily have to mate- 37
  • 36. 38 Table 2 Imbalances at the EMU Source: European Commission (2012): First Alert Mechanism Report (moving averages, 3 or 5 years) The future of the Euro after the Great Recession
  • 37. The Future of the Euro rialise, but it is also true that provisions have proven insufficient and have had to be extended in successive programmes. Chart 9 GDP Growth in 2007 and 2015 Source: IMF (2012) Lastly, the aging of the population gives way to the generation of implicit liabilities which are not considered in public debt figu- res but should be taken into consideration when evaluating the sustainability of public finances (Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli, 2010). In 2009 the IMF (IMF, 2009) calculated the sum of implicit and contingent liabilities in securities exceed – in present value – 400% of the average GDP of the G20. Of these, those of a contingent nature associated with the crisis account for approxi- 39
  • 38. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession mately one tenth, whereas that associated with an aging popula- tion – pensions and social security – account for much higher implicit obligations. As a whole, this type of liability will demand a remarkable effort from public finances in the future. Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli (2010) place the additional permanent financing required to meet such obligations at between 5 and 10 GDP points assuming a public debt at levels similar to the current ones in developed countries. In summary, some European economies may have reached debt levels which exceed or are dangerously close to their fiscal limits, defined as the maximum level of debt which a country is able to fund. The fiscal limit depends on the political will of its citizens and the capacity to increase income by means of tax rate rises (Bi, 2012 and Leeper & Walker 2011) which makes it specific to each country. This might explain, at least in part, the differences obser- ved in risk premiums between countries with similar levels of debt or even that some countries pay a higher cost of financing that others with much higher levels of debt. Moreover, the relationship between the risk premium and the fiscal limit is non-linear, incre- asing rapidly when fiscal performance places debt at such levels that the likelihood of reaching the limit is significant (Bi, 2012). That is to say, in order to observe significant risk premiums, it is enough for investors to understand that the fiscal strategy of a country leads it to a fair likelihood of reaching the maximum level of debt financed, even if the probability of this taking place in the short term is very small. This probability in turn grows over the 40
  • 39. The Future of the Euro economic cycle, which obliges countries with greater volatility in economic activity and unemployment to opt for stricter fiscal rules.4 Table 3 Contingent Obligations of the governments 2008-2010 Banking sector EFSF guarantees Belgium 7,3 12,7 Germany 8,22 3 Estonia 12,46 0 Ireland 42,8 Greece 25,8 Spain 8,61 6,2 France 7,97 3,1 Italy 8,78 2,7 Cyprus 8,78 15,7 Luxembourg 4,66 3,2 Malta 10,91 0 The Netherlands 7,32 6,1 Austria 7,19 5,7 Portugal 9 Slovenia 10,23 4,4 Slovakia 11,05 0 Finland 7,34 0 EMU 7,71 5,2 Source: BCE 4 When the economies reach this limit, the efficacy of the fiscal and monetary policy is substantially reduced and both instruments no longer have the expected effects on economic activity. The fiscal multipliers are reduced and the monetary authority loses the capacity to control inflation, irrespective of the aggressiveness of its monetary policy. 41
  • 40. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession 4. The new European governance and the future of the Euro The economic crisis has highlighted the need to carry out important changes in European governance. It is obvious that there have been failures in coordination in the economic policy and mistakes in the policies adopted by national government, which have generated a sovereign debt crisis and a financial crisis. And it is also obvious that Europe was not first resorting to the supranational institutions and bodies to prevent the crisis and to provide a rapid and efficient response once it had begun. The EU, and particularly the EMU, need to improve their economic gover- nance in at least three areas: fiscal, financial and economic inte- gration. Below we shall analyse each of these aspects and the cha- llenges faced in each by the EMU. 4.1. Changes in fiscal governance In regard to fiscal integration, over recent months important inroads have been made, among which are the Stability, Coordination and Governance Treaty and the creation of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). The new Treaty, which shall come into force on 1 January 2013, has been signed by all EU coun- tries except for the United Kingdom and the Czech Republic, and aims to make public finances sustainable and prevent the onset of excessive public deficits, in order to safeguard the stability of the Eurozone as a whole. In fact, this Treaty can be interpreted as a second version of the Maastricht Treaty of 1992, with the differen- 42
  • 41. The Future of the Euro ce that whereas the former determined the conditions to enter the EMU, the new treaty can be said to detail the conditions to be met by the members of the EMU to continue to belong to the Eurozone. To this end, the Treaty introduces specific rules (the structural defi- cit may not exceed 0.5% of the GDP, as of a date to be determined by the European Commission, and a public debt below 60% of GDP) and automatic mechanisms which enable the adoption of corrective actions in the event of deviation from targets. The rules introduced by the Treaty are in general well designed. When establishing an objective in terms of structural fiscal balance it allows for the influence of automatic stabilisers, the minimum being between 0.5% of structural deficit and the deficit limit of 3%. However, a good design does not necessarily guarantee a good imple- mentation, as was the case with the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). It is true that the new Treaty entails a criterion of “reverse majority”: from now on the adoption of corrective or disciplinary mechanisms proposed by the European Commission must be rejected by a majo- rity, whereas in the SGP the majority needed to be reached in order to approve such proposals. It is also the experience of the current debt crisis has led to an accumulation of collective knowledge which shall prove very useful when adopting the right decisions in the future to prevent new crises of this kind. Just as eighty years later the Federal Reserve is currently preventing some of the well-known mistakes which were made during the Great Depression of the 1930s, the European Commission and the European Council shall endeavour to prevent imbalances similar to those we are currently undergoing. 43
  • 42. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession Available empirical and theoretical literature (see, for instance, Andrés & Doménech, 2006, and the references included in this paper), indicates that use of fiscal rules has proven useful in the containment of public debt and the deficit, without the effective- ness of the automatic stabilisers adversely affecting the effective- ness of the discretionary fiscal policies. Therefore, the fiscal rules like those included in the Stability Treaty do not have to be an impediment for the fiscal policy to carry out its duty of stabilisa- tion of economic cycles. Quite the opposite: when the economic agents know, that as a consequence of the existence of such rules, expansive fiscal policies in the short term shall be offset in the medium term by counter-adjustment measures in order to prevent the accumulation of public debt, the effectiveness of these discre- tionary stabilisation policies increases, as has been proven by Corsetti, Meier and Müller (2011). In any event, it shall be very difficult to achieve an optimal implementation of the Treaty. In the first place, because all govern- ments are often too complacent when allocating probabilities to possible risk scenarios which may render public finances unsustai- nable. Secondly, because it is difficult that sanctions may come about from the European Union Court of Justice on the basis of fai- lure to meet the structural deficit targets, which depend of estima- tes of the cyclical position of the economies and the elasticity of public income and expenses to this cyclical position. Nevertheless, what the Stability Treaty does provide is that, prior to reaching sanctions, the Commission may exert much greater pressure on 44
  • 43. The Future of the Euro national governments and alert markets about excessive imbalan- ces, so that it is the markets themselves that impose discipline via higher interest rates. As for the ESM, at the ECOFIN on 30 March the decision was taken to extend it to 500 thousand million euros, which shall be provided over two years, and beginning on 1 July 2012. The extent to which this fund will be sufficient is still unknown, in that it shall depend on how it is used and whether it allows for fund leve- raging. Without leveraging, the fund shall only be enough to cover the financing needs of small or medium sized economies in the EMU, but not of the big four. However, it may prove effective for specific, selective but highly intensive interventions designed to reduce risk premiums, that is, to replace the ECB in its Securities Market Programme (SMP). In addition, if the ESM should obtain liquidity from the ECB itself, each of these entities might be able to separately specialise in the management of a risk: the SMP would manage the ‘solvency risk’ of sovereign debt and the ECB would managed the ‘liquidity risk’, thus enabling the central bank to resu- me the natural role for which it was created, as it would be creating an EU fund, with a joint and several guarantee, instead of sove- reign debt with a national guarantee. It is very important that the intervention of the SMP is as effi- cient as possible. To this end, the Commission must be clear about which countries are solvent, with adoption of any necessary adjust- ment measures and structural reforms, and which countries need 45
  • 44. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession some kind of debt restructuring. In the first case, which is clearly applicable to countries such as Spain and Italy, SMP intervention on risk premiums should be as intense as necessary until market doubt and uncertainty have been obliterated. It would otherwise be very difficult to convince sovereign, pension or investment funds to purchase the public debt of such countries if Europe is not the first to refrain from doing so. Obviously, a more decisive intervention by the SMP, which would lead to a rapid relaxation of the European sovereign debt markets, requires the adoption and follow-up of the necessary adjustments and reforms, but with sufficient time frame so as not to asphyxiate the economic growth of the countries adopting such policies. Specifically, the EU could change the fiscal consolidation strategy which is currently being demanded from member states. The obsession for nominal deficit targets should be replaced by a more plausible, rigorous multi-annual fiscal policy strategy which, in seeking to prevent a spiralling negative growth, truly contribu- tes towards supporting sustainability in the long term of the public finances of all countries. Specifically, the European consolidation strategy should be based on the following principles: 1. Deficit reduction targets should refer to structural deficit inste- ad of nominal deficit, as proposed by the new Stability Treaty. This implies that countries should be asked to take specific and detailed measures to ensure a certain amount ex ante in terms of reduction in expenditure or increase in income in the 46
  • 45. The Future of the Euro coming years. If, as a result of such measures, the economic activity should be adversely affect with an impact on nominal deficit (by the mere intervention of the automatic stabilisers), the member states should not be obliged to take new savings measures in that same financial year. 2. The pace of structural consolidation should be ambitious enough to ensure sustainability in the medium to long term of public finances, and gradual enough to prevent excessively adverse effects on activity and employment in the short term. 3. The long term balance of public finances requires reforms which guarantee the sustainability of public systems of pen- sions and social protection. Blanchard (2011) recently recommended that, in order to return to prudent levels of public debt, it would be advisable to apply the pro- verb of “slow and steady wins the race”. A similar recommendation to that of De Long and Summers (2012), for whom a fiscal consolidation which is too intense and too fast might endanger the very sustainabi- lity of public finances instead of guaranteeing it. In regard to the debate on Eurobonds, although not necessary or sufficient, these can indeed become a useful tool in the con- text of streamlined national finances. They are not necessary, as the Eurozone can operate without them, if the Stability Treaty and the mechanism for the prevention and correction of excessi- 47
  • 46. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession ve imbalances work properly. And they are not sufficient to pre- vent debt crises if the fiscal or current account imbalances are not corrected. If growth is imbalanced (private indebtedness, current account balance deficit), they imply a permanent transfer of income from one country to another, which is unsustainable in the long term. But they are convenient as an efficient mechanism to ensure and pool risks in the face of asymmetric shocks and, above all, as an element of political legitimacy of the European project: European citizens must see that there are specific bene- fits to belonging to the EMU. And Eurobonds are one of these benefits, particularly now when many countries need to make considerable sacrifices and carry out adjustments and reforms. In this regard, the Eurobond proposal (blue and red) of Delpla and von Weizsäcker (2010), has the advantage that it would allow countries to benefit from risk pooling and the creation of a more liquid asset (the blue bond) than that of the debt of each of the EMU members, which would strengthen the euro as an internatio- nal reserve currency, but with the benefit of preserving market dis- cipline for national debt issued over and above 60% of GDP (red bonds).5 This proposal consists of the EMU countries pooling their 5 Attinasi, Checherita and Nickel (2009) believe that this market discipline is behind the increase in sovereign spreads between 2007 and 2009, as a result of the increase in risk aversion and the concern for the sustainability of public finances. However, Favero and Misale (2012) believe that this market discipline acts in an interrupted fashion over time and, occasionally, in an exaggerated way, which in fact justifies the issue of euro- bonds. 48
  • 47. The Future of the Euro public debt up to 60% of their GDP as senior debt under the joint and several responsibility of all members, whereas the issue of national debt beyond such a limit would be junior debt under indi- vidual responsibility. From this perspective, it is easy to conclude that the decision of the European Council reached in December 2010 to ensure the solvency of the debt issued until June 2013, but not that issued as of that date was a mistake, as the decision should have been the opposite: ensure as of a given date all debt issued under 60%, which would in effective terms be equal to the creation of the Eurobonds proposed by Delpla and von Weizsäcker (2010). 4.2. Financial integration As Pisany-Ferri and Sapir (2010) have pointed out, to date the EMU has worked without a European institution able to rescue transnational financial entities and without authentic European stress tests for its banking institutions. Oversight duties have remained with national authorities and coordination problems have been managed by means of a combination of discretionary cooperation and dependence on rules approved by the EU. One of the lessons to be learned from the current crisis is that it is difficult to manage a financial crisis on a European scale wit- hout supranational regulators, supervisors and insurance mecha- nisms. A large part of the head start that the US has over Europe in terms of crisis management and resolution is precisely due to the non-existence or the delay in creating such bodies. The US has 49
  • 48. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession federal institutions to manage banking crises, whereas Europe does not, which renders true the saying that banks are internatio- nal when expanding and national upon demise. The problem is that, for some governments (Ireland is a perfect example of this), banks are too large in relation to their public budgets. Likewise, the US has a federal regulation, whereas Europe has enormous national dispersion of its regulations, despite the efforts of the European Commission and regulators to homoge- nise and converge towards a common financial regulation. Occasionally, headways made in certain rules give rise to inequa- lities among the agents who intervene in the markets, due to other rules continuing to be different. This was the case, for ins- tance, of the requirement of the European Banking Authority that potentially systemic banks must exceed a capital ratio of 9% before 30 June 2012, when the measurement of risk weighted assets is regulated by different rules. Banking oversight in Europe is furthermore carried out via national supervisors instead of via a single European institution, which introduces heterogeneity in oversight levels of the financial system. The result of this financial fragmentation is that one can- not speak of a single market, which generates the possibility of regulatory arbitrage, different conditions of competency, ineffi- ciencies and, in general, a disadvantage in regard to other world financial areas. 50
  • 49. The Future of the Euro In summary, financial integration requires an improvement to be made in the mechanisms through which information is shared on the financial systems of each country and the way in which their activities are supervised, the harmonisation of the guarantees on bank deposits and of consumer protection regulations, the creation of European bank restructuring and rescue mechanisms, and the advancement towards a Single Market not with more, but with a bet- ter, European regulation which, instead of adding to and prevailing over national legislation, should simplify and replace it. 4.3. Economic integration With greater fiscal and financial integration the Eurozone could operate with less tension in the future, without ensuring the economic convergence among countries. Is convergence of income or welfare levels in European countries necessary? Probably not, but it is still con- venient, as has been stated earlier, to enable societies to believe that being within an economic and monetary union has advantages well beyond those which are provided by monetary stability. One of les- sons to be learned from the Eurozone crisis is precisely that monetary integration does not ensure economic convergence, as this requires an advancement in convergence of the determining factors (economic, social and institutional) of economic growth. Table 4 shows that the differences in medium and long term determinants of per capita income are very significant. The relati- ve position of each country has been obtained on the basis of the 51
  • 50. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession IMF analysis (2010), whereas the allocation of each country to one of three groups under consideration has been carried out on the basis of the criteria put forward by Hall and Soskice (2001). On the basis of a number of criteria, both institutional and based on the workings of economic relations, Hall and Soskice classify the varie- ties of capitalism into liberal economies (the US being the pro- totype) and coordinated economics (Scandinavian countries are the paradigm). In both models (either with high or minimum coordination), the economies can function efficiently. Market eco- nomies which cannot be classified into either group are classified as mixed economies. In order to transform the qualitative IMF indicator into a quan- titative one, such as analysing its correlation with per capita inco- me, values of 1 to 3 have been allocated for each of the three levels considered by the IMF, where a higher score suggests a greater need for implementing structural reforms. This enables the obtention of an average for each country and for each of the nine indicators which are shown in Table 4. The differences shown in this table are very marked, not only between developed economies, but also bet- ween European ones. In light of this evidence it is not surprising that, except in the case of Ireland, the countries which have accu- mulated the most imbalances and which are suffering more form the tensions in the debt market are precisely those which shown greater structural weaknesses and the ones which must implement the most reforms. Countries which in turn have been classified as mixed market economies, presenting more inefficient institutions. 52
  • 51. Table 4 Structural capacity of the developed economies Source: BBVA Research (2010) based on IMF (2010) and Hall & Soskice (2010) 53 The Future of the Euro
  • 52. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession The changes in the regulations which affect the operation of the labour, goods and services markets, trade, telecommunications markets, are easier to implement in the short term, although the changes thereof are felt in the medium term. An example of this can be found in the recent reform of the labour market in Spain, which is bringing its operation in line with that of countries like Germany (in terms of internal flexibility mechanisms) or to that of free market economies (by prioritising company agreements and opt out clauses for collective bargaining agreements). Making headway in these types of reforms (for example, linking salaries to productivity) is crucial to remove the differences in competitive- ness which exist between EMU countries, particularly bearing in mind that the crisis may have had an effect on the potential growth of these economies (see, for example, the European Commission analysis, 2009). However, in long term indicators such changes can take a lot longer and, in some cases, even decades. This is the case with human capital. Even in the event that the many younger workers of countries such as Spain, Italy, Greece or Portugal should enter into the labour market with the same human capital as in better placed countries, 25 years would be needed to half the distance for the whole of the population of employable age. 54
  • 53. The Future of the Euro 5.Conclusions The economic crisis has highlighted the excessive complacency of the markets, agents, supranational institutions and governments when interpreting the imbalances which were being generated in the previous expansion period and the absence of supranational institutions and mechanisms, firstly to prevent the imbalances which led to the crisis and secondly, to provide a fast and efficient response once they had happened. Such institutions and mecha- nisms are necessary because the evidence shows that the markets react in a discontinuous way, and occasionally in an exaggerated way, are pro-cyclical and do not generate of their own accord suf- ficient disciplinary mechanisms in the short and medium term whenever these are needed. Insofar as the current Eurozone crisis has taken place mainly in three areas (debt crisis, banking crisis and crisis in growth and competitiveness, with huge heterogeneity between countries), the EU and, particularly the EMU, need to improve their economic governance in at least three areas: the fis- cal, the financial and that of economic integration. As for the improvement in fiscal governance, the Treaty of Stability, Coordination and Governance needs to be effectively applies in a preventive way and that, during its transition towards medium and long term structural deficit targets, this is done with sufficient rigor and the right flexibility to prevent that countries required to make the most efforts in the short term should enter into a negative growth spiral. In this regard, intervention by the 55
  • 54. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession ESM on risk premiums should be as intense as necessary until market doubts and uncertainty have been removed, so that the countries which are implementing fiscal adjustments and structu- ral reforms have a sufficiently broad time period to enable such measures to have positive effects on economic growth. As for the Eurobonds, although they are not necessary or sufficient to ensu- re the operation of the EMU, they are indeed convenient as an efficient mechanism providing assurance and pooling risk in the face of asymmetrical shocks and, above all, as a political legiti- macy item in the European project: European citizens must disco- ver that there are specific benefits to being part of the EMU. Although it is difficult for such Eurobonds to become a viable ins- trument in the current situation of divergence, they must become an essential part of the future European Treasury when the main imbalances are well under way to being corrected through the decisive application of the reforms in the various countries in the EU. The second area where headway must be made is that of finan- cial integration, in order to prevent future banking crises and to manage them in a more efficient and rapid way. Europe must have supranational financial institutions, regulators and supervisors, as the current financial fragmentation prevents us from speaking of a single market. An important limitation which gives rise the regu- latory arbitrage, different competency conditions, inefficiencies and, in general, a disadvantage in regard to other world financial areas competing against the European entities. 56
  • 55. The Future of the Euro Lastly, although greater fiscal and financial integration may suf- fice to enable the Eurozone to operate with less tension in the futu- re, it is worth establishing the bases for greater economic conver- gence among its members, in order to increase the political legiti- macy of the economic and monetary union project, with benefits which go beyond those provided by economic stability. The diffe- rences between the EMU countries in the workings of factor, goods and services markets are very significant, as well as in long term growth determinants. The structural reforms undertaken to enable the markets to work more efficiently can bring positive effects in a relatively reasonable period of time, enabling competitiveness to improve and the imbalances accumulated during the expansion and the crisis to disappear more rapidly. In this regard, it is essen- tial to ensure the success of the Excessive Imbalances Procedure and other imbalance monitoring mechanisms, ensuring a more efficient preventive and corrective action than that provided by the Stability and Growth Pact. However, in terms of long term growth determinants, such changes can take longer and, in some cases, even decades; it shall therefore be necessary for Europe to boost the solidarity mechanisms required to accelerate this conver- gence process in a more effective and efficient way than that done in the past. To simultaneous progress on all these fronts, both at suprana- tional and national levels, is a necessary condition for the Euro to overcome this crisis and for its members to continue to form part of this project in the future. Insofar as the starting point is very 57
  • 56. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession different in each country, the main challenge now facing the EMU is to combine in a fair way the rigor and the ambition of the adjustments and structural reforms, on the one hand, with an appropriate time frame and solidarity with all other members of the Eurozone, on the other. If, on the contrary, the member states should fail to show such determination, any attempt towards European economic gover- nance will be due more an intention than a hard reality. The Eurozone would have an uncertain future. The alternative of a Political European Union, in which all necessary economic policies could be implemented from a community Executive under the control of a European Parliament and with all democratic rights, is currently not expected for the time being. Bibliography - Attinasi M. G., C. Checherita y C. Nickel (2009): “What Explains the Surge in Eurozone Sovereign Spreads during the Financial Crisis of 2007-09?”, ECB Working Paper no. 1131/2009. - Barro, R. J., N. G. Mankiw y X. Sala-i-Martin (1995): “Capital Mobility in Neoclassical Models of Growth”. The American Economic Review, 85(1), 103-115. 58
  • 57. The Future of the Euro - BBVA Research (2010): Spain Economic Watch. Noviembre. - Bean, Ch. (2004): “Asset Prices, Financial Instability, and Monetary Policy”. The American Economic Review, 94(2), 14-18. - Bean, Ch. (2010): “The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction”. - Bi, H. (2012): “Sovereign Default Risk Premia, Fiscal Limits, and Fiscal Policy”. European Economic Review, 56 (2012) 389–410. - Blanchard, O. y F. Giavazzi (2002): “Current account deficits in the euro area: the end of the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 147-186. - Blanchard, O. (2011): “Blanchard on 2011’s Four Hard Truths”. Vox EU. - Bordo, M. y O. Jeanne (2002): “Monetary Policy and Asset Prices: Does 'Benign Neglect' Make Sense?” International Finance, 5(2), 139- 64. - Borio, C. y W. White (2004): “Whiter monetary and financial sta- bility? the implicatios of evolving policy regimes”. BIS Working Papers No 147. 59
  • 58. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession - Cecchetti, S., M. Mohanty y F. Zampolli (2010): “The Future of Public Debt: Prospects and Implications”. BIS Working Paper No. 300. - Comisión Europea (2009): "Impact of the Current Economic and Financial Crisis on Potential Output". European Economy Occasional Papers, 49. - Comisión Europea (2012): First Alert Mechanism Report. - Corsetti, G., A. Meier y G. J. Müller (2011): “Fiscal stimulus with spending reversals“. The Review of Economics and Statistics (en prensa). - DeLong, J. B. and L. H. Summers (2012): “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy”. Mimeo. - Delpla, J. y J. von Weizsäcker (2010): “The Blue Bond Proposal”. Bruegel Policy Brief. - Doménech, R. y M. Jiménez (2010): ”La Primera Gran Crisis de la Unión Económica y Monetaria”, Pensamiento Iberoamericano, 6, 49- 80. - Edwards, S., 2002. "Does the Current Account Matter?," en Sebastian Edwards y Jeffrey A. Frankel, eds, Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets, pages 21-76 NBER. 60
  • 59. The Future of the Euro - Ehrmann, M., M. Fratzscher, R.S. Gurkaynak y E.T. Swanson (2011). ‘Convergence and Anchoring of the Yield Curves in the Euro Area’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(1), 350–64. - Favero, C. y A. Missale (2012): “Sovereign Spreads in the Eurozone: Which Prospects for a Eurobond?” Economic Policy, 27(70), 231–273. - FMI (2010), “Regional Economic Outlook. Europe”. - Galí, J. y L. Gambetti (2009): "On the Sources of the Great Moderation." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1): 26–57. - Hall, Peter A. y David Soskice, 2001a: An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism. In: Peter A. Hall y David Soskice (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–70. - Florence J. y P. Sodsriwiboon (2010): “Current Account Imbalances in the Southern Euro Area”. WP/10/139. IMF. - Lane, P. (2010): A European Perspective on External Imbalances. Swedish Institue for European Policy Studies. Report nº 5. - Leeper, E. M. y T. B. Walker (2011): “Fiscal Limits in Advanced Economies”. Working Paper 16819. NBER. 61
  • 60. The future of the Euro after the Great Recession - Obstfeld, M. (2012): “Does The Current Account Still Matter?” Working Paper 17877. NBER. - Pisani-Ferry, J. y A. Sapir (2010): "Banking crisis management in the EU: an early assessment". Economic Policy, 341-373. - Rojan, R. (2005): “Has Financial Development Made The World Riskier?”. NBER WP 11728. - Reinhart, C. M. y K. Rogoff (2008): “Is the 2007 US Sub-Prime Financial Crisis So Different? An International Historical Comparison”. American Economic Review, 98(2), 339–344. - Reinhart, C. M. y K. Rogoff (2009): This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press. - Shambaugh, J. C. (2012): “The Euro’s Three Crises”. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (de próxima publicación). 62
  • 61. /JOSÉ CARLOS DÍEZ * / Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis Summary; 1. Introduction; 2. Historical background of the Euro; 3. Nature of the Euro crisis; 4. Fixed versus flexible exchange rates: a review; 5. Causes of the Euro Crisis; 6. Conclusions; Bibliography Summary This work analyses the Euro crisis. It includes a review of its his- torical background and the exchange rate theory to provide con- ceptual arguments to help understand the nature and causes the- reof. It is an infrequent pathology in economics, particularly in developed countries, but with an enormous destructive capacity. * José Carlos Díez is an economist who has combined his academic and corporate roles throughout his professional career. His academic activity is linked to the University of Alcalá, where he was an undergraduate and PhD student and now is Professor of Fundamentals of Economic Analysis. He is currently the Chief Economist at Intermoney, a company founded in 1979 and leader in Spain in money market brokerage. He contributes with his forecasts to the panel of experts of the ECB on European economy and the panel of FUNCAS on the Spanish economy, and advises companies, financial entities and institutions both natio- nal and international. 63
  • 62. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis For this reason, it is important to get the right diagnosis when defi- ning the economic policy that will solve the crisis. The main cau- ses analysed herein are financial integration, the under-assessment of risks, local imbalances within the Eurozone and the Great Recession. 1. Introduction The world financial crisis, whose first symptom was the collap- se of the subprime asset-backed securities market at the start of 2007, has been changing. It is currently focused on Europe, and is calling into question the future viability of the Euro and the European project itself. This work aims to classify the nature of the Euro Crisis and to identify the main causes thereof. Although the objective is not to analyse potential economic measures designed to solve the crisis, without an accurate diagnosis of the origin and dynamics of the crisis, finding the right solution would be an exer- cise in chance. To this end, section 2 includes the history of the European pro- ject and the single currency. Section 3 describes the nature of the crisis, which is a seldom seen pathology in economics but which causes devastating damage to unemployment and public debt of affected countries. In order to provide the conceptual arguments required to analyse the crisis, section 4 contains a review of the lite- rature on exchange rates. Section 5 analyses the main causes of the crisis, which are: i) financial integration and under-assessment of 64
  • 63. The Future of the Euro risk; ii) local imbalances; and iii) the Great Recession. Finally, sec- tion 6 includes the main conclusions reached in the article and establishes the requirements to be met by the roadmap in order to put an end to the Euro Crisis. 2. Historical Background of the Euro The Euro is the first monetary experiment of the 21st century. It is not the first in history and shall not be the last, but it affects an economy like that of the Eurozone which accounts for 15% of the GDP and for 40% of world exports. The European Union is a poli- tical project designed to prevent a third world war in Europe. The first assignment of sovereignty was control by a supranational body of the coal and steel production in France and Germany, basic raw materials to produce weaponry. Europe was not an optimal monetary area; therefore, if a country suffered from an asymmetri- cal disturbance which did not affect the rest and it saw the effects thereof on tis unemployment rate, this could not be offset by wor- kers migrating to other countries with lower unemployment rates. The bubble in Spain is a good example of this. Spain created one third of the jobs in the Eurozone during the boom years, but wor- kers from Germany, where the unemployment rate was reaching historical levels, did not come: instead, it was workers from outsi- de the Eurozone who came. When the bubble burst, our unem- ployment rate shot up, but very few Spanish workers have gone to work in Germany. 65
  • 64. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis The example of an optimal monetary area is always the US. However, we tend to forget that in order to get there; they first had to annihilate the original settlers and then have a civil war which led to a default on payment of foreign debt. The European project belongs to the 21st century and when in Asia, America or Africa integration processes begin, they look to Europe for inspi- ration. Nevertheless, the Euro was a risky headlong rush. Since the end of the Bretton Woods agreement, Europe has tried to avoid the unfair competition of competitive devaluations within a cus- toms union. Germany, with the strongest currency in the system, has always led the monetary agreements, as its companies suffe- red the industrial delocalisation created by devaluations, mainly that of the Italian Lira, a country a few hours away by lorry from Bavaria. After the fall of the Berlin Wall, the acceleration of the monetary union was decided so that it would become the striker of the political union. However, the political union reached stag- nation after the severe German crisis of 2000, and the single currency project began to crack. 3. Nature of the Euro Crisis The nature of the crisis which is hitting the European Union is a classical debt deflation crisis (Fischer, 1933). Since the Great Depression, this type of crisis had mainly taken place in emerging countries and was associated with countries with financial vulne- rability, with little tradition of macroeconomic stability and insti- 66
  • 65. The Future of the Euro tutional fragility. Japan had suffered a crisis of this kind in the nineties and its economy is today trapped under deflation and liquidity, but it was viewed as an exotic case in the Far East. In 2008, the Great Recession led to an abrupt disruption of the paths of growth in developed economies, and the ghost of the Great Depression began to haunt the world. By contrast, the decisive and coordinated action of global economic policies prevented another Great Depression (Eichengreen, 2010). Since then, world trade and industrial production are 10% higher to levels prior to the Great Recession, although the MSCI world stock index continues to be 20% below the levels of spring 2008. Nonetheless, the crash of Lehman Brothers led to the collapse of world trade, and all countries and areas entered abruptly into reces- sion, which favoured policy coordination. But the recovery from 2009 was asymmetric, and the coordination of world economic policies was conspicuously absent. In the Eurozone, from summer of 2008 to spring of 2009, the euphoria in support of an interven- tion to avoid a depression gave way to exit strategies in autumn of that same year and to begin implementing these in spring of 2010. The debt crisis affected a country with huge imbalances in the balance of payments and high level of indebtedness such as Greece, which accounts for 2% of the GDP and population of the Eurozone, and has extended first to Ireland, then to Portugal, and now to Italy and to Spain. One third of the GDP of the area is alre- ady affected, and it has thus become a systemic and global pro- blem. This is a crisis in the balance of payments, but the existence 67
  • 66. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis of a currency and the high level of indebtedness mean the lack of any comparable historical precedents, which in turn makes the diagnosis and the search for policies to solve it much harder. For this reason, we must carry out a review of classical literature on exchange rates in order to establish the conceptual bases for the explanation of the crisis, without which the search for a solution would become a random wander. 4. Fixed exchange rates versus flexible exchange rates: a review An exchange rate is a relative price between two hypothetical shopping baskets of two countries. However, exchange rates are closely related to interest rates (Keynes, 1992), and we are therefo- re speaking of a relative price which is essential when explaining economic development. Probably for this reason and as a result of the advance of globalisation, both commercial and financial since the fifties, in recent decades economists have paid special attention to exchange rates. Exchange rates can be: i. Free floating: the exchange rate is set freely in the market on the basis of supply and demand, without the intervention of the central bank or the government of a country. The Euro and the Dollar are the closest free floating currencies. ii. Dirty or managed float: the government or central bank suppo- sedly does not intervene but there are verbal interventions or 68
  • 67. The Future of the Euro changes in monetary policy which attempt to alter the bases of supply and demand in the currency market. At times of maxi- mum volatility both the US government and the European ones verbally intervene in the market. During the Great Recession, the Federal Reserve, without expressly acknowledging this, has applied a monetary policy which has significantly weakened the dollar. The ECB has always followed in the footsteps of the Fed but in 2011 it managed to exceed its action by weakening the Euro, also without express recognition thereof. Japan is without question the best example of dirty flotation. The country sup- posedly enjoys free exchange rates but when there is tension in the markets and the savers repatriate capital, the central bank intervenes massively in the currency market to counteract the pressures of appreciation on its currency, which would have a very negative repercussion on activity and employment. iii. Fluctuation bands: the European Monetary System or EMS, the predecessor of the Euro, was the clearest example of this system. A central parity and fluctuation bands were established. Whilst the exchange rate in the market fluctuated within the bands, the system behaved like a flexible currency rate, but if it reached the bands then the central bank intervened to prevent these being exceeded, therefore becoming a fixed Exchange rate. iv. Fixed on a currency basket: equal to a fixed rate, but instead of fixing the anchor on one single currency it is fixed on a basket. It has been speculated for some time that China wants to apply 69
  • 68. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis this system. It makes more sense that just fixing it against the dollar, as the basket should replicate the composition of the current account and financial balance and would allow for bet- ter stabilisation of real exchange rates, which are the ones which determine the impact on activity and employment. v. Fixed adjustable: this is a fixed exchange rate which allows for adjustments. These may be discretionary or else subject to rules such as in the Bretton Woods system, or periodically adjustable. The latter were used in emerging countries which had sustained soaring inflation rates in the eighties and nineties during their stabilisation programmes, especially in Latin America. vi. Non-adjustable or true fixed rate: the country fixes a nominal anchor with a fixed rate relative to another currency with no possibility of change. Middle Eastern countries have fixed exchange rates against the dollar, which is justified by income from oil being collected in dollars. China had a fixed exchange rate against the dollar until 2005, when it moved onto daily fluctuation bands which it has recently broadened to +/- 1% daily. vii. Cash conversion: the monetary supply of a country is determi- ned by the level of currency reserves, and thus monetary sove- reignty is subject to capital flows. This was the exchange system in Argentina until 2001. 70
  • 69. The Future of the Euro viii.Exchange Union: the countries waive their national sove- reignty and assume a new currency. This may be a dollarization as has been proposed in some Latin American countries, or else a Euroization where the dollar would be adopted but without representation in the central bank. Or else a monetary and exchange union such as the Eurozone, where countries assume the same currency and are represented in the central bank and in monetary and exchange decision making processes. The debate on fixed or floating exchange rates is as old as macroe- conomics. During the happy twenties and then during the Great Depression, capital movements were accused of being speculative due to the extreme volatility of exchange (Nurkse 1942). Subsequently, another school of thought argued that the volatility was caused by destabilising economic policies and that freedom and speculation had stabilising effects (Friedman 1953). Rudiger Dornsbush opened up a new avenue of research according to which, even with investors with rational expectations, there was volatility in exchange rates. An incre- ase in the money in circulation by the central bank would increase inflation expectations and lead to a depreciation in the exchange rate. However, for investors to buy once again there should be expectations of appreciation; the exchange rate should therefore over-react and exceed its level of equilibrium to enable capital flows to return to the country. The truth is that neither the theory nor the empirical evidence are conclusive in this debate. The problem facing the countries is 71
  • 70. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis threefold: exchange rate stability, monetary independence and financial aperture. Conceptually speaking, flexible exchange rates are the optimal solution, but for these to be stable the country must have monetary credibility. Flexible exchange rates provide leeway to the central bank in terms of fiscal policy, whereas the fixed exchange rate means this is lost and it becomes dependent on the decisions made by the central bank to which it has anchored its currency. The problem is that credibility takes a long time to achieve and takes very little time to lose. Moreover, it cannot be imposed; it is the society of the country in question which must understand stability to be a public asset and to accept sacrifices and limitations in order to preserve it. Countries lacking monetary credibility have hardly any leeway in monetary policy, and this reduces the costs of accepting a fixed exchange rate. If the country has suffered from hyperinflation or a spiralling inflation, a nominal anchor on a stable currency allows for stabilisation of the prices of imported goods in the shopping basket and, combined with a stabilisation plan, proves to be highly effecti- ve to get the economy out of hyperinflation. This is what happened in Argentina in 1990, but then the fixed exchange rate allowed imba- lances to go beyond what was sustainable and ended up by explo- ding in mid-air and amplifying the effects of the severe crisis of 2001. During the nineties the debate in Europe prior to the creation of the Euro was very intense (Rodríguez Prada, 1994). Most econo- mists did not call into question the fact that Europe was an opti- 72
  • 71. The Future of the Euro mal monetary area (Meade 1957 and Mundell 1961). Although much progress has been made in the freedom of movements of capital and people, the labour markets continue to be segmented, mainly due to language and cultural differences, and when a region suffers an asymmetric disturbance with an increase in unemploy- ment, this is not offset by transferring workers from another region as they do, for example, in the US. In this scenario, the country needs to transfer capital and work to the sector of non-corporate goods to the corporate goods sector and needs to depreciate the real exchange rate. Without the capacity to devaluate the nominal exchange rate, all the adjustment must be made via inflation or productivity. When the central country has inflation rates close to 2% the strategy must be deflationist, which is where the problems start, as many economists warned prior to the creation of the Euro and has been proven since the Great Recession (Obstfeld 1998). Nevertheless, the lack of an optimal monetary union is clearly a downside to the creation of the euro, but in the nineties it was the benefits that were highlighted (De Grauwe 2009). The main bene- fit is that we Europeans already had a customs union and high level of commercial integration. Nowadays, approximately 70% of the Spanish exports are concentrated in the European Union and 60% of what we import comes from our partners. Therefore, natio- nal exchange policies were very destabilising in this scenario, put- ting the European project at risk. 73
  • 72. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis The main benefits were concentrated in the financial area. Integration would enable the removal of currency risk and risk pre- miums, leading to a drop in real interest rates and therefore incre- asing the potential growth of the Eurozone and of each of the countries therein, in turn allowing for convergence in income per inhabitant with the US, which experience a sharp boom in pro- ductivity in the nineties. Chart 1 shows how the introduction of the euro did not achieve the desired convergence, except in the case of Spain. Chart 1 Gross Domestic Product per inhabitant Source: Eurostat structural indicators and own work 74
  • 73. The Future of the Euro In the debate of costs and benefits prior to the creation of the Euro, many economists warned of institutional problems in the design of the monetary union. The main ones were the absence of a fiscal union which would offset the asymmetric disturbances that might take place in some states and, that in the absence of exchange rates and monetary policy, the country would be left without economic policy leeway to counteract them (Eichengreen 1998). The other main limitation was the absence of a true lender of last resort which the statutes imposed on the ECB (Obstfeld 1998). 5. Causes of the Euro Crisis The Euro crisis is extremely complex like all debt deflation cri- ses in history (Díez 2012), which is why we shall now review the main events to enable us to understand the fundamentals of the over-indebtedness without which we shall not be able to come up with appropriate economic policies to help digest this. 5.1. Financial integration and under-assessment of risk When a country adopts a fixed exchange rate and investors con- sider it sustainable in the future, the risk premium drops. A rational investor must choose between an infinite variety of international assets in which to invest his savings, but his yield estimates are made in local currency as the objective of purchasing financial assets is to protect against the impairment of purchasing power 75
  • 74. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis caused by inflation during the investment period. If an investor purchases an asset in another currency that then appreciates during the investment period, his yield will increase in the local currency, but if it depreciates it will drop, which explains the direct relationship between interest and exchange (Dornbusch 1976). In the case of the Euro we are dealing with the exchange rate with the largest commitment and greatest exit costs; therefore its added credibility is also greater, just as the drop in risk premiums is also highly intense. Chart 2 shows the intense process of financial integration which took place in Europe following the creation of the single currency. Investment funds and financial institutions in the Eurozone went from having 20% of assets from other countries in the region in their portfolios in 1998, to 45% and 40% respecti- vely in 2007. This means a huge transfer of capitals from countries with a savings surplus, mainly Germany, to countries with savings deficits and especially those with higher risk premiums. This arrival of capital flows, along with the credibility granted by the investors to the Euro since its inception, help to explain the intense convergence of interest rates between the public debt of the various member countries that can be observed in Chart 3. However, as is the case with all bubbles, at the beginning there are fundamentals which justify investor behaviour, but usually, follo- wing such sharp changes in financial flows, there is usually and over-reaction and asset prices move away from the fundamentals. 76
  • 75. The Future of the Euro Chart 2 Financial integration Source: European Central Bank Chart 4 shows how not only did convergence take place in public debt interest rates, but that the process was more intense in private debt. Covered bonds are the assets with the least likelihood of default following the public debt of a country and it might even be the case, in extreme cases, of default on Treasury bonds but not on covered bonds, as has happened in Greece. The covered bond is a bond with a senior guarantee from the financial institution that issues it, but which also has a second guarantee. The issuing entity selects its highest credit quality mortgages, those for the main resi- dence, with a debt under 80% of appraisal and a monthly instal- ment below 35% of the household income, and these are attached as bond guarantees. Therefore, in the event of bankruptcy of the 77
  • 76. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis Chart 3 10 years Public debt spread v. Germany Source: Bloomberg and own data entity, the buyers of the covered bond would prevail over the rest of creditors to collect on such mortgages until recovery of their investment, irrespective of whoever purchases the bankrupt entity. This is what distinguishes them from asset-backed securities where the investor assumes the direct default of the mortgages. In the case of the covered bond, the risk belongs to the entity and, second to the default of the mortgages, and thus they have a dual guaran- tee and lesser likelihood of default. Moreover, the rating agencies require the over-collateralisation of the issue, so that if an institu- 78
  • 77. The Future of the Euro tion issues a covered bond worth 1000 million euros, they would be required to provide between 1300 and 1500 in mortgage portfo- lio as a guarantee. Hence, the entity would first have to be declared bankrupt and then it should have to have a default in the mortga- ge portfolio of over 50% for the investor not to recover 100% of his investment. This helps one to understand that since 2007 no cove- red bond issued by a European entity has experienced default. These types of assets do not exist in the US, as the Fannie Mae and Freddy Mac played the same role, but evidence has shown that the European system, by maintaining the risk in each institution, was more efficient and, in fact, there are legislative proposals under way to develop a covered bond market in the US. Until 1997, the companies of peripheral countries such as Spain found it difficult to issue bonds on the international markets. The Peseta was a currency which had experienced several devaluations over the last few decades, its financial markets were very narrow and were practically taken over in full by public debt. The entry of the Euro enabled Spanish financial entities to access an organised market of covered bonds with a longstanding tradition and depth in Germany, which rapidly spread to all other countries in the area. As we shall explain shortly, this coincided with a deep and complex debt crisis in Germany, as a result of the excesses of its Unification, which increased the savings rate in a structural way, and thus the supply of top quality credit assets for its financial institutions, insu- rance companies and pension funds, which in turn boosted the rapid growth of this market as well as its (Díez 2012b). 79
  • 78. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis Chart 4 Spanish covered bonds spreads Source: Bloomberg and own data In Chart 5 we can see how such structural changes in the fun- damentals led to a credit boom in the Spanish economy. The ori- gin of the boom was justified by the fundamentals, but in the end the only fundamentals were the self-realisable expectations, lea- ding to the bubble. In 1995, when the likelihood assigned by inves- tors that Spain would form part of the founder members of the Euro was very low, practically all of the Spanish bonds in the hands of non-residents were public. Since then, the percentage of public debt over GDP had become constant, but when our incorporation 80
  • 79. The Future of the Euro into the single currency was approved in 1998, the international issues market opened up for the private sector and grew exponen- tially until it doubled that of public debt in terms of GDP. The hea- ding “other resident sectors” includes the asset-backed securities funds, rendering most of debt as pertaining to banks. Chart 5 Spanish bonds in the hands of non-residents Source: Bank of Spain, INE and own data Covered bonds are purely a bank product, despite carrying a second mortgage guarantee, and are accounted for as bank debt. The most developed covered bond market in the world was the German 81
  • 80. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis one of Pfandbrife but in Chart 6 one can see how in 2006 the Spanish banks issued 70,000 million euros in covered bonds, 30% less than the German banks which had a balance three times as large as that of Spanish banks. In summer 2007, before the start of the financial crisis, the outstanding balance of covered bonds issued by Spanish banks exceeded 300,000 million euros, 30% of the GDP and an amount equal to the outstanding balance of Spanish public debt. In 2006, the issues of covered bonds and asset-backed securi- ties by Spanish banks comfortably exceeded the current account deficit which was approaching 100,000 million and were the main financing instrument of our economic, without which it is not pos- sible to explain the credit and real estate bubble. The dynamics were straightforward. The Spanish banks used the loans granted in retail banking as a guarantee for new issues which allowed the granting of new credits. The issues of covered bonds were carried out at variable interest rates of Euribor plus 10 basis points and the mortgages were granted at Euribor plus 50 basis points. A strong growth in credit, low rate of default and spreads between stable asset and liability rates constituted the basis of the demand for funds of Spanish banks. What were the fundamentals of the supply of funds? The key lay in the Shadow Banking System (FSB 2011, European Commission 2012). This consisted mainly of vehicles created by international banks, based in tax havens and not consolidated in their balance sheets and thus outside the peri- meter of oversight by the central banks. The vehicles purchased assets, mainly of high credit quality and were funded by the com- 82
  • 81. The Future of the Euro Chart 6 Issues of Covered Bonds Source: International Monetary Fund mercial paper market using those assets as guarantees. Let us assu- me that the vehicle bought a covered bond at Euribor plus 10 basis points and was funded by Euribor commercial paper. This resulted in a profit of 10 basis points per transaction. If the vehicle only had 5% of capital and 95% of debt, this meant a 20-fold leverage, such that the yield over equity was Euribor plus 200 basis points. The growth of the shadow banking system was exponential and in 2007 in the US reached 20 billion dollars, whereas the non-sha- dow banking system supervised by the Federal Reserve amounted 83
  • 82. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis to 16 billion dollars. The asset-based leverage which used mortgage guarantees already granted enabled the banking system to generate liquidity in an endogenous manner without having to resort to the central bank, leading to the loss of monopoly by the monetary aut- horities of the issue of money in circulation. When in February 2005 Alan Greenspan, then President of the Federal Reserve, announced that there was an enigma in the behaviour of the bond market, he was responsible for this for allowing the development of the shadow banking system. Until 2009, no statistics were publis- hed on the shadow banking system but, once they became public, it was much easier to understand the causes of the largest global cre- Chart 7 Current account balance Source: International Monetary Fund 84
  • 83. The Future of the Euro dit bubble burst since the Great Depression and which was parti- cularly severe in some Eurozone countries, including Spain. 5.2. Local imbalances: Over the last few decades, the economic paradigm has analysed the real economy and the financial economy separately. The Great Recession has proven the failure of the paradigm and, as we were shown by Luca Paciolo in the 13th century, when an economy is analysed, the assets and liabilities cannot be separated. Therefore, although it is evident that the hurricane began in the financial realm, there are imbalances in the real economy which also help to explain the crisis. Chart 7 shows the divergence between current account balances among developed and emerging coun- tries in the last decade. Several causes help explain this phenome- non which the literature has called “global imbalances” (Caballero 2009). The main cause was the aftermath of the Asian crisis of 1997. The affected countries had large current account deficits and low levels of currency reserves before the crisis, and subsequently they geared their economic policy towards exports. This led to current account surpluses and high currency reserves, and the ensuing structural increase of the world savings rate (Bernanke 2005). The accumulation of reserves was concentrated on sovereign funds and central banks with a conservative approach, which significantly increased the demand for fixed income funds of top credit quality, 85
  • 84. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis known as AAA. Without understanding the Asian crisis and its con- sequences it is not possible to understand the intense development of the shadow banking system and the strong increase in leverage in the world banking system which has been analysed in the pre- vious section (Caballero 2008). Chart 8 shows how the Eurozone was hardly affected by the phenomenon of Global Imbalances, with a current account balan- ce close to equilibrium since the Asian crisis. However, Chart 8 shows that there have indeed been huge differences between the countries within the Euro and, for this reason, the phenomenon has now been called Local Imbalances. In 2001 Germany suffered a debt crisis similar to the one suffered at present in Spain, although it hardly translated into a current account or foreign debt deficit. Germany, as was the case in Japan in the eighties, suffered from a problem of over-indebtedness of households and businesses, with real estate bubble, burst and depression all thrown in to the packa- ge. Following the burst of the bubble in 2000, German households were reluctant to take on debt and structurally increased their savings rate to reduce such a debt. Private consumption plumme- ted and businesses sought the supply that was absent in the domes- tic market in the export market. The fiscal revenue dropped dra- matically and Germany failed to meet the Stability Pact and wat- ched its public debt increase significantly until 2005. The birth of the euro and the credit boom in peripheral coun- tries enabled Germany to overcome the severe recession thanks to 86
  • 85. The Future of the Euro the strength of its exports. Moreover, German savings found an easy path without assuming exchange rate risk with its partners in the Eurozone. The causes of the Euro crisis are focused on the analysis of the imbalances of debtor countries, but it is not possi- ble to understand and explain the crisis without analysing the saver countries, particularly Germany. Debtor countries are facing a prolonged period of debt reduction, which will ensure a weak internal demand, and shall be obliged to show a current account surplus as was the case in Asia in 1998 and in Germany in 2001. But this will not be possible if the creditor countries reduce their current account surpluses and boost internal demand. Chart 8 Current account balance Source: International Monetary Fund and own data 87
  • 86. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis 5.3. The Great Recession: The European Monetary Union was born with institutional pro- blems but these did not become evident and to put its viability at risk until 2009. Chart 9 shows how the Great Recession which rava- ged the world and Europe in 2008 has been the worst for seventy years, although it did not reach the depth and length of the Great Depression, which it is being called the Great Recession. Without an earthquake of this force, it is possible that the institutional flaws of the European project could have endured for longer, but the cri- sis has highlighted them and the Euro is now at a crossroads. In 2007 it was financial disturbances which anticipated the recession. Chart 6 shows how the covered bond market practically dried up for Spanish banks as well as for all other indebted coun- tries. This brought the credit boom to a halt and acted as the trig- ger for the recession. In 2008 the disorderly collapse of Lehman led to the worst global run since the Great Depression. The investors quickly resorted to short term public debt of the internal reserve currencies, the money markets dried up as did the currency mar- kets, and world trade collapsed in a matter of weeks. The coordi- nated reaction of the G20 with the most expansive monetary, fis- cal and financial policy in history prevented the world from ente- ring into a depression and enabled a V-shaped recovery of world economy and trade in 2009. 88
  • 87. The Future of the Euro Chart 9 GDP EU 15 Source: Angus Maddison. University of Groningen Economics is an empirical science but it is difficult to find homogeneous experiments to compare policies, but this crisis has provided one. The Great Recession was synchronized and most countries entered into recession at the same time. However, the recovery since 2009 has been disparate and the economic policies have been very different between the US and the Eurozone, which enables a comparison of its effects to be drawn. Europe began fis- cal consolidation at the beginning of 2010, despite the boost given in 2008 to get out of the recession, whereas the US has con- tinued to renew its fiscal incentive plans. The ECB has been reluc- tant to intervene and has only done so when the markets have been on the edge of collapse and it even took the liberty of incre- 89
  • 88. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis asing the interest rated in July 2011, making the same mistake as in July 2008, anticipating the recession. The Federal Reserve has kept its rates at 0% and has renewed its quantitative policies. After two years of experimenting, what has the result been? The growth in the US has been twice that of Europe, its inflation has also doubled and its unemployment rate has reduced to 8.5%, whereas in Europe it has exceeded 10%. In the US, several states, among them California and Florida, burst their real estate bubbles and California defaulted on payments and created its own currency, what was known in Argentina as Patacones. Therefore, the Euro crisis is not the cause of the problems in Europe but simply the result of mistakes made in economic policy in Europe since 2009. Neither is the argument of the greater rigidity of European labour markets and the mobility problems between countries valid. In the US, the unemployment rate increased with equal intensity in states which did not have a real estate bubble, thus confirming that the cause of the growth in unemployment was a sharp drop in demand caused by an intense banking crisis and credit restriction. But the most spectacular result of the expe- riment is probably what happened with public finances. The US, without resorting to raising taxes, without great cuts and simply by freezing public expenditure has managed to increase fiscal revenue by 12% and has reduced the deficit by four percentage points of GDP. Europe, by raising taxes and cutting costs has managed a revenue increase of 6% and a reduction of the deficit of two points of GDP. 90
  • 89. The Future of the Euro The emergence of almost ten points of public deficit in a new Government in Greece was the spark which ignited the Euro crisis which we currently face. The Greek Tragedy spread first to Portugal, then to Ireland, and currently threatens Spain and Italy, thus having affected one third of the GDP of the Eurozone, (Díez, 2012). Chart 2 shows how the Great Recession began a process of finan- cial disintegration in the Eurozone which was intensified by the Greek Tragedy and the contagion of all other economies. In a monetary union, the outflow of capital is equal to a contractive monetary policy and, on the contrary, the inflow of capital is expansive. This helps us to understand why the countries subjected to financial tension entered once again into deep recession in 2011 whereas Germany, the main receiver of capital flows, has continued to grow. 6. Conclusion The European project is a political one and it is born out of the need to end wars and conflicts which had ravaged Europe in the 20th century. The Euro was an attempt to accelerate the political union but has ended up being a headlong flight. · The Euro is the most extreme version of a fixed exchange rate. Indeed, it is reinforced and with high cost of departure, which renders it more credible, but while it lacks a political union there will always be doubts as to whether it will be a single currency. 91
  • 90. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis · In the nineties the benefits – and there were some which have been clearly demonstrated – of the creation of the euro were overvalued. But at the same time there was an under-assessment of the costs which reality has proven were also there. The two main institutional problems which must be solved are: i) the absence of a fiscal union to complement the monetary union and ii) the absence of a lender of last resort due to the limita- tions imposed on the ECB in its bylaws. · Financial integration and the undervaluation of risk, both glo- bal phenomena, are essential to explain the credit boom and the problem of over-indebtedness which are the origin of the Euro Crisis. The case of the covered bonds is a good example that not only were credit risks undervalued, but liquidity risk was likewi- se under-assessed. · The Local Imbalances, the high current account surplus in Germany and the deficits in Spain and other countries forced the transfer of financial flows and boosted the credit boom and over-indebtedness. Countries subjected to financial tension are implementing sharp reductions in their current accounts, but Germany has hardly reduced its foreign surplus since 2007. · The institutional problems of the Eurozone became apparent at the Great Recession, as a result of the sharp drop in activity and the collapse of the financial markets and credit channels which have rendered many debts unsustainable and unpayable. 92
  • 91. The Future of the Euro Without such a deep recession, the problems would have taken longer to appear. · The aim of this article was not to discuss solutions, but from the analysis of the nature and causes of the Euro crisis, we can con- clude that the solution must: i) dispel doubts as to the future via- bility of the euro, ii) to do so we must work towards the fiscal union and the creation of Eurobonds would be the precedent for a future single European treasury, iii) we must change the bylaws of the ECB so that it may act as a lender of last resort as the Federal Reserve does in the US, iv) we must halt the process of financial disintegration and ensure the return of part of the capi- tal flows which have exited from peripheral countries, and v) we must urgently reactivate growth in Europe. In order to do so, the monetary policy must opt for quantitative strategies of debt pur- chase, the fiscal policy must be less restrictive and the financial institutions and countries with greater solvency problems must be recapitalized in order to restore the credit channels as soon as possible. 93
  • 92. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis Bibliography - Bernanke, B. (2005). “The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit”. Federal Reserve Speech 10 March. - Bernanke, B. (2007). “The Financial Accelerator and the Credit Channel”. Federal Reserve Speech 15 June. - Caballero, Ricardo J., Farhi, Emmanuel and Gourinchas, Pierre- Olivier (2008), "An Equilibrium Model of ‘Global Imbalances' and Low Interest Rates," American Economic Review, vol. 98 (1), pp. 358-93. - Caballero, Ricardo J. and Krishnamurthy, Arvind (2009), "Global Imbalances and Financial Fragility," American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, vol. 99 (May), pp. 584-88. - European Commission (2012) “El Sistema Bancario en la Sombra”. Libro verde, Marzo. - De Grauwe, Paul (2009) Economics of Monetary Union 9 ed. Oxford University Press. Oxford. - Díez, José Carlos (2012) “Crisis de la Deuda Europea: crisis de emer- gentes o sumergidos” Papeles de Economía Española 130 January, pag. 150-166. 94
  • 93. The Future of the Euro - Díez, José Carlos (2012b) “El Sistema Bancario tras la Gran Recesión” Mediterráneo Económico 20 January, pag. 329-345. - Dornbusch, Rudiger. (1976) "Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics." Journal of Political Economy 84: pag. 1161-76. - Eichengreen, Barry, and Wyplosz, Charles (1998) “The Stability Pact: Stabilizing or Destabilizing?” Economic Policy 26 April, pag. 65- 113. - Eichengreen, Barry and O’Rourke, Kevin (2010), A tale of two depressions: What do the new data tell us? February 2010 update, VoxEU.org, 8 March. - European Commission (1998) “Convergence Report 1998”, Bruselas. - European Monetary Institute, Convergence Report, Frankfurt am Main, March 1998. - FSB, Financial Stability Board (2011) Shadow Banking: Strengthening Oversight and Regulation. October. - Friedman, Milton (1953) The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates. Essays in Positive Economics. 95
  • 94. Nature and Causes of the Euro crisis - Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953, pp. 157-203. Chicago. - Keynes, John M. (1992) Breve Tratado sobre la Reforma Monetaria. Fondo de Cultura Económica de España. Madrid. - Meade, James (1957) The Balance of Payments Problems of a Free Trade Area. - Economic Journal, Sept. 67, 379-96. - Mundell, Robert (1961) A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. The American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4., pp. 657-665. - Nurkse, Ragnar (1942). International Currency Experience. Lessons from the Inter-War period. League of Nations, p. 188. Genova. - Obstfeld, Maurice (1998) EMU: Ready, or Not? Working Paper. University of California, Berkeley. - Rodríguez Prada, Gonzalo (1994) Teoría y estrategias de la integra- ción económica y monetaria: con aplicaciones a los casos de la UE, el NAFTA y el MERCOSUR. Universidad de Alcalá. Alcalá de Henares. - Torrero, A. (2006) Crisis Financieras: Enseñanzas de Cinco Episodios. Marcial Pons. Madrid. 96
  • 95. /JUERGEN B. DONGES * / The European crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance 1. Introduction; 2. The root cause of the problem: too much economic diver- gence; 2.1. A suboptimal monetary area; 3. Attempted governance in an indirect manner; 3.1. Breach of the fiscal rules; 4. Governance as activism against the crisis; 4.1. Constituent principles, violated; 4.2. Financial assis- tance, a never-ending story?; 4.3. Political pressure to impose discipline, insufficient so far; 4.4. Financial markets, with capacity to persuade; 5. New governance design: own responsibility as the key; 5.1. The euro Plus Pact, it is not binding on anyone; 5.2. The Fiscal Stability Pact, a test of nine; 5.3. The Macro-economic Governance Pact, with vague parameters; Conclusion * Professor emeritus of economics at the Faculty of Economic and Social Sciences of the University of Cologne (Germany). From 1969 to 1989 he managed several economic analysis departments at the Kiel Institute for the World Economy, in which he was the Vice-chairman for the previous six years until he took the chair in 1989 in Cologne. He is currently a Senior Fellow of the Cologne Institute for Economic Policy. He was the Chairman of the German Council of Economic Experts (the so-called “Five Wise Men”) and the German Commission on Economic Deregulation. He is an economic advisor in several academic institutions and foundations in Germany, Spain and in other coun- tries. He is also a member of the Supervisory Board of several multinational companies. He is the author of several books and articles published in academic journals on inter- national economy and public policies in the field of macro and micro economy. 97
  • 96. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance 1. Introduction The purpose of this article is to focus the current discussion on the need for economic governance in the European Union (EU) and, in particular, in the euro area, in the context of the political reality. This is not such an easy task, as it may seem; in practice the rela- tions between national governments, on the one hand, and these and the European Commission and the European Parliament, on the other, end up being profoundly redefined, with more European powers and less national sovereignty. This topic is not new; it has been on the table at the mee- tings of the European Council of the Heads of State and Government since the formation of the European Single Market 25 years ago (1986 Single European Act). We can interpret agreements leading to a coordination of economic policies, as the initial step towards “smooth” European economic governance, specifically to (i) promote employment (1997 European Summit of Luxembourg), (ii) apply structural reforms conducive to flexibility in the product and factor markets (1998 Cardiff Summit), and (iii) institutionalise macro-economic dialogue among the governments, the European Central Bank (ECB) and social partners (1999 Cologne Summit). Apart from the above steps we should add (iv) the agreement of the European Council in 2010 to launch a strategy of structural reforms that would make the EU at the end of that decade the most dyna- mic economic area in the world. 98
  • 97. The Future of the Euro These agreements which were then celebrated as a landmark in the European integration process have not given the desired results. The reason is very simple: over and above the rhetoric, the govern- ments were not willing to co-operate if the alleged or true national interests indicated otherwise. Such governance installed in the European Council, the Ecofin and in other councils of ministers involved, lacked any kind of power of management and supervi- sion of the economic and fiscal policies of the member states. At the current debate the great hope is that in the future national interests will come second, giving way to the “More Europe”, as the new political logo reads. The aim is to reach gre- ater and efficient intra-European co-ordination of the economic policy of the member countries. This aim was raised in 2011- 2012 in three basic agreements: (i) the Euro Plus Pact (to strengt- hen the competitiveness and growth capacity of the economies), (ii) The Fiscal Stability Pact (Fiscal Compact to guarantee in all the countries the sustainability of public finances in the medium and long term) and (iii) the Macro-economic Governance Pact (Economic Governance Six Pack, to ensure economic and fiscal policies compatible with the internal and external balance in the economies). Now, the declarations of intent are one thing, put- ting them into practice and applying the appropriate economic policies, is quite another. Why should what politicians promise today be believable, if in the past (and today, as many of them are still around) did not fulfil their commitments? 99
  • 98. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance I will now analyse governance in its past and present dimen- sions. The following section emphasises the significant fact that the euro area is not an optimal monetary area. In the third and fourth sections the forms of governance relied on until now are analysed. The fifth section deals with the new approach for European governance. The last section concludes the analysis in a tone of moderate hope. 2. The root cause of the problem: too much economic divergence The crisis of the sovereign debt in Europe has shown a serious fault in the formation of the single currency: trusting that the governments of the member countries would apply quality econo- mic policies in accordance with the common interest of all the partners, as set forth in the EU Treaty (articles 2 and 121), was naive. In Germany, I together with many other economists noticed this fault then, but political leaders took no notice or it was labe- lled as “academic” and, therefore, irrelevant to take great historical decisions. The leaders simply invoked the criterion of the so-called supremacy of politics over economics, as they do today when they run from one summit to the next to rescue certain countries from bankruptcy and try to stabilise the euro area. 100
  • 99. The Future of the Euro 2.1. A suboptimal monetary area The architects of the euro area, from the 1989 Delors Report, knew that a monetary union would not be feasible in the long run without a fiscal union, not to mention political union. The history of the different monetary unions in Europe in the 19th Century had left an unequivocal message: all of them failed because of incompatibilities among the budgetary policies of the member countries. However, during the negotiations of what would become the Maastricht Treaty (of 1992) the prerogative of national budge- tary policy was sealed. The then two main characters of the European project, the German Chancellor Helmut Kohl and the French President François Mitterrand, fascinated their counterparts with their vision of the euro as a pacemaker to accelerate and to go into greater integration. More than one will remember the famous statement of the French Finance Minister, Jacques Rueff, ‘Europe shall be made through the currency, or it shall not be made’ (1950), and they took it literally. The French statesman could never have imagined such a deteriorated environment of public finances as we have today in many European countries. It was also clear that the five convergence criteria set forth in the Maastricht Treaty, even if they could be fulfilled (something that not all countries have done), did not guarantee an optimal mone- tary area (in terms of the theory of Robert Mundell and others). In Europe, it would have been essential for the countries to be quite homogeneous in terms of economic development and functioning 101
  • 100. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance of the institutions or the prices and salaries in the various countries should have been flexible enough (especially downwards in coun- tries with weak growth and great structural unemployment), or for European mobility of labour to be high (from backward regions with high unemployment rates to dynamic regions with shortage of workers). These conditions for an optimal monetary area did not happen twenty years ago and do not happen today. The difference between Europe and the United States in this is significant. Only a group of countries in the euro area (in central and nort- hern Europe) at least met then and meets now the condition of homogeneity. The countries in the southern periphery were not, strictu sensu, ready for their accession in 1999 to the monetary union and, therefore, to waive a monetary and exchange rate policy as adjustment facilities of internal imbalances (inflation) and external imbalances (current account deficit) and to under- take tax regulations that would restrict government deficit and the level of government debt. It is not a coincidence that these countries have had for the past two years a risk of insolvency (not to have the capacity to re-finance the debt in the capital market under affordable conditions), as only sovereign countries have, if the State may not resort to the Central Bank to secure financing and must get it by issuing bonds in a foreign currency. Greece may be the most illustrative example of having done what the German Council of Economic Experts has classified as an “origi- nal sin”, in other words, having rushed into accessing the mone- tary union in 2001, forced even through deceit (hiding the truth 102
  • 101. The Future of the Euro of their fiscal statistics): the country is now at the mercy of the international financial markets (rating agencies), after having revealed the serious structural deficiencies in the economy and the public institutions, which has led to a low growth potential and low levels of productivity and competitiveness clearly insuf- ficient at this time (globalisation of competition). 3. Attempted governance in an indirect manner It was conceptually logical that with the creation of the single currency the powers on monetary policy would be transferred from the National Central Banks to the new ECB. However, as the budgetary policy would carry on being a national responsibility, two principles constituting the euro area were established in order to guarantee the sustainability of the public finances in the member countries and to ensure that the monetary union would work as a price stability union. • The two principles proclaimed in the Maastrich Treaty are the prohibition to bail out insolvent partners, on the one hand, and the prohibition imposed on the ECB to finance govern- ment deficits (no monetisation), on the other hand. These clauses are contained in the most recent version of the Treaty on the European Union (the Treaty of Lisbon of 2007) in arti- cles 125 and 123, respectively. 103
  • 102. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance • The two provisions were supplemented with the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) approved in 1997 at the European Summit in Amsterdam; in it a ceiling for national budget deficits (3% of GDP) and government debt (60% of GDP) were established under the assumption that the growth rate of the nominal GDP in the euro area would be 5% in the medium term.1 With all this, indirect governance elements were created, in other words, formally maintaining national powers in budgetary policy, but controlling the use of the powers that could destroy the feasibility of the euro area. The monetary union was not designed to pay debts jointly and generate financial transfers from certain States to others, as many today think that that is the case, appealing to solidarity among peoples. There was already solidarity, and there still is, in the good sense of the concept: the more developed countries of the EU must help the least developed for these to advance in real convergence; the various European Structural Funds are for this. But it is not compatible with the concept of solidarity; it rather constitutes a “perversion” (Issing) of it, having to rescue a society that underestimates saving, tends to consume ostentatiously, tolerates waste by the public authorities, does not fulfil tax obli- 1 For a profound analysis see A. Brunila, M. Buti and D. Franco (ed.), The Stability and Growth Pact: The architecture of fiscal policy in EMU. Houndsmills/Basingstoke (United Kingdom): Palgrave, 2001 – Círculo de Empresarios (ed.), Pacto de Estabilidad y Crecimiento: alternativas e implicaciones. Libro Marrón 2002. Madrid (December). 104
  • 103. The Future of the Euro gations and claims social benefits beyond the means of the country, given its own resources. 3.1. Breach of the fiscal rules The architecture of indirect governance crumbled when it had to pass the first real test, in 2002/03. In those days, Germany (Schröder) and France (Chirac) violated the the fiscal rules of the game. In Germany, government deficit had reached 3.7% of GDP in 2002 and 3.8% in 2003; in France, it was 3.2% and 4.1% respec- tively. In both cases, most part of the deficit was structural. The European Commission had activated, according to the SGP, the supervisory mechanism for ‘excessive government deficit’ against these two countries. The German Chancellor explicitly rejected the intervention from Brussels, the same as the French President. They both imposed their criterion at the European Council in November 2003, which suspended the process (against the votes of Austria, Spain, Finland and Holland). The then President of the European Commission, Romano Prodi, had described the SGP in an inter- view (on 18/10/02) as “stupido”, which is highly surprising coming from the custodian of the European Treaties. At the European Summit held in March 2005, the SGP was amended, watering it down a great deal: with new exceptions for breaking the rules, an assessment of the budgetary situation on a case-by-case basis, considering the special circumstances of each country, relaxing the periods to take the necessary adjustment 105
  • 104. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance measures, the differentiation among countries as regards the goal of budgetary consolidation in the medium-term and some com- plex and non-transparent supervisory mechanisms.2 We must remember this in order to understand the reason for the current proposals to depoliticise (“automate”) the decisions on sanctions in case of an infringement of the fiscal regulations. With the erosion of the SGP, the factors that determined the cri- sis of the current sovereign debt, put down roots, a crisis which would have happened anyway, if the 2007-09 global financial and economic crisis had not have appeared. If the governments of the two main countries of the euro area are skipping the Treaty of Europe and the SGP, why wouldn’t the rest do the same if this is what is best for them and open the tap of non-productive public expenditure? Structural government deficits increased conside- rably and with this the volume of the government debt. With this precedent, the supervision of national budgetary policies by the European Commission was reduced to merely a rhetorical exercise that did not scare the rulers much. Economic governance in an indirect manner had failed. The ECB, however, fulfilled its role and its first president, Wim Duisenberg, did not allow political leaders to tie his hands, despite their attempts. 2 For this purpose, the European Commission adapted the original regulations No 1466/97 and 1467/97 of 7/7/1997; see COM (2005) 154 and COM (2005) 155 of 20/4/2005. 106
  • 105. The Future of the Euro 4. Governance as activism against the crisis The threat of Greece’s suspension of payments two years ago showed lack of efficient European economic governance. Instead, a rare and disconcerting political activism appeared. The nume- rous measures taken since May 2010 in Europe seem more like an exercise of muddling through than implementation of a consis- tent and long-term strategy. 4.1. Constituent principles, violated It all started in the worst possible manner: the Governments eli- minated in one fell swoop the two principles establishing the euro area mentioned above. The lifting of the non-rescue clause created the problem of moral hazard for Governments with a tendency to excessive public expenditure and for reckless banks when it comes to buying government bonds. The Governments could pass the cost of exces- sive indebtedness to taxpayers from other countries (who had no right to speak or vote when the budgets of the State in question were drafted). The banks started a tremendous communication campaign to warn of the danger of the euro area (systemic risks) if indebted countries were not rescued, efficiently concealing to the public opinion that their true intention was to protect their share- holders. 107
  • 106. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance Under the presidency of Trichet, the ECB was under pressure to undertake a new role: the role of being a “repair shop” for the faults in the fiscal and growth policies. It acquired in the Securities Markets Programme, big sums of Treasury bonds from countries in trouble which nobody wants. Here lies the difference with other relevant central banks (the Federal Reserve, the Bank of England, the Bank of Japan), they also buy government securities in the con- text of their non-conventional monetary policies, but these are assets with considerable profitability. Furthermore, the ECB currently grants unlimited liquidity to banks for three years, at a symbolic interest rate (1%) and it accepts low quality securities as guarantee. But it is not in its hand to lead banks to proper granting of credit to companies or households in the country under affor- dable conditions; the ECB must resign itself to banks choosing more profitable business in the short-term, as purchasing the debt of the State; therefore, there is not much change in the scenario of credit restriction in the private sector in several countries, like in Spain. The European monetary entity is not only “a last resort len- der” anymore, which in situations of financial emergency is justi- fiable, but it has also become “a public debt buyer of last resort”, which is more questionable, because it delays the fiscal adjust- ments of the Governments (and it caused in 2011 the resignation of two German senior members of the monetary authority bodies, first the resignation of Axel Weber, President of the Bundesbank and ex officio member of the ECB Governing Council and, subse- quently, the resignation of Jürgen Stark, member of the Board of the ECB and its chief economist). The role that the ECB is playing, 108
  • 107. The Future of the Euro for the moment also under its new president (Draghi), may dama- ge its reputation as an institution independent of political powers and commited to price stability, which is what it has been entrus- ted with in the European Treaty. An additional problem is that the same standards of asset qua- lity, which are used as collateral in the re-financing of commercial banks by the National Central Bank itself (and, as such, part of the Eurosystem), do not govern in the whole of the euro area anymo- re. In several countries in trouble, especially with persistent current account deficits which (already) do not finance in a conventional manner import of capital or through financial assistance from abroad, the respective National Central Banks, with permission from the ECB, accept low quality securities as guarantee of loans, more than what is allowed for emergency liquidity assistance. It is as if they were using the money printing press. This somewhat undermines the monopoly of the ECB to create money. What is questionable from an economic perspective is hidden behind the enormous increase in the amount of these operations in the Eurosystem Target 2 in the past years, which has been vehemently warned by the Ifo Institute of Munich for the last year.3 The Bundesbank has become a gigantic creditor of hundreds of millions of euros for the National Central Banks of the other countries, wit- 3 See H.-W. Sinn and T. Wollmershäuser, “Target Loans, Current Account Balances and Capital Flows: The ECB’s Rescue Facility”, NBER Working Paper, No 17626 (November). CESifo, “The European Balance of Payments Crisis”, CESifo Forum, Special Issue, January 2012. 109
  • 108. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance hout protection and right to any kind of compensation if there is any significant bankruptcy of banks and savings banks or if the euro area collapses. The Governments of debtor countries have in reserve a powerful argument to manage to get from others, espe- cially from Germany, concessions in the negotiations over finan- cial assistance. 4.2. Financial assistance, a never-ending story? Political leaders believed, and some of them still do, that the creation of a common rescue fund is the solution to the problems of countries in trouble and it eliminates possible spillover effects. The first rescue mechanism was created with the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF).4 This fund is provisional (three years, until 2013) and at the beginning had a provision of 440,000 million euros in loans guaranteed by the euro countries; as the Fund wanted to place their issues with the highest ranking ‘AAA’ to get attractive profitability, the real lending capacity would be lower than the allocation, about 250,000 million euros. Ireland (87,500 million euros) and Portugal (78,000 million euros) had to resort to this Fund. Subsequently, in July 2011, the European Council decided to increase the real lending capacity of this rescue fund to 440,000 million euros and, in addition, increase their 4 EU Council of Ministers (Ecofin), EFSF Framework Agreement, 9/5/10 and 7/6/10. Web page: http://www.efsf.europa.eu (Legal documents). 110
  • 109. The Future of the Euro powers and relax the conditions for granting the loans to countries in trouble. It even received leverage instruments (with a 4 factor) and the so-called ‘special purpose vehicles’ (off-balance); such ins- truments, applied by private banks, were exactly the ones that trig- gered very harmful effects for the global financial crisis to break in 2008. In mid-2012, six months in advance to the original schedule, a new permanent rescue fund will come into force, the ‘European Stabilisation Mechanism’ (ESM).5 This fund will have a provision in nominal terms of 700,000 million euros (with capital contribu- tions from the member countries amounting to 80,000 million euros); the real lending capacity of this new Fund is 500,000 million euros. Provisionally, the amount of available resources may amount to about 800,000 million euros, by transferring the unused EFSF resources. The IMF, the OECD, the United States and China, among others, recommend a higher firewall (up to 1.5 billion euros). In parallel with these events, a special treatment has been given to Greece. After the initial financial assistance plan approved in May 2010 (110,000 million euros, of which 30,000 million euros came from the IMF), of which politicians said that it would enable 5 European Council, Treaty Establishing the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), 25/3/11. Internet: http://www.efsf.europa.eu (Legal documents). – European Council, Treaty sig- ned by the 17 euro area Member States, 2/2/12. Internet: http://www.european.council.europa.eu. 111
  • 110. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance the country to return to the capital market in 2013, in February this year a second package was agreed (130,000 million euros, including a contribution from the IMF, to which a further amount of 24,400 million euros of the first package pending payment will be added). The latest thing is that private creditors will undertake (about 85.8% voluntarily and the rest will be obliged by law) a deduction of 53.5% and will agree for the rest of their securities an exchange for new Greek long-term treasury bonds and of the EFSF Fund at a moderate interest rate (which will reduce the Greek public debt in about 107,000 million euros of a total of 350,000 million euros). Greece’s main public creditor, the ECB, has escaped this operation and the asset losses derived from it, by means of a trick, quickly exchanging their former Hellenic bonds, which would have undergone a reduction, for new exempt bonds under the same condition. The official aim is to get the public debt to be reduced from the current 160% of GDP to about 120% of GDP in 2020. The Ecofin believes that this level is sustainable, which is quite surprising for three reasons: firstly, this level was what Greece had in 2008/09, already in the increase and considered unsustainable then; secondly, the tax authorities must improve a great deal in order to promote the capacity to collect taxes and stop tax fraud and capi- tal flight; and thirdly the IMF’s estimates of 2-3% economic growth per year from 2014 must be fulfilled, which implies that the neces- sary structural reforms must be quickly implemented and the eco- nomy must reach considerable gains in international competitive- 112
  • 111. The Future of the Euro ness by substantial salary and price reductions (according to the estimates, about 50%). All of these points are question marks. The most probable thing is that the announced aim of debt reduction will not be attained and that the European governments sooner or later will again have on the negotiating table Greece’s request for further financial assistance. 4.3. Political pressure to impose discipline, insufficient so far The European form of governance since the sovereign crisis star- ted in Greece has always been “more of the same”: to want to solve a problem of excessive indebtedness with more debt. The critical public opinion, as in Germany, was calmed down by saying that no cash was going to be paid from national budgets and, therefore, from taxpayers (although there will be in the ESM), but that each government “only” had to provide guarantees (distributed among the countries according to the holdings of the national central banks in the share capital of the ECB). As if guarantees could not be enforced at the demand of the creditors, in other words, buyers of the securities issued by the EFSF/ESM! The expectations to calm down the markets, restore confidence and stabilise the euro area were not met. The markets had noticed that, in the countries badly affected by the sovereign debt crisis, progress in fiscal consolidation and structural reforms that raise the potential of growth and com- petitiveness, which there are, were too slow and incomplete. 113
  • 112. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance This was caused from outside. The aided governments have not forgotten the political messages launched from the beginning of the crisis from Brussels/Paris/Berlin. The messages that are least for- gotten and carry on being repeated with slight variations, are the following: (i) “We will rescue the euro, no matter what it costs” (Barroso); (ii) “We will not allow anyone to fall into insolvency” (Sarkozy); (iii) “If the euro fails, Europe fails” (Merkel). There could be no better invitation for irresponsible governments to blackmail. That is how a government in trouble is tempted not to consistently take pure and hard measures, therefore reducing the cost of loss of political support, which any severe fiscal adjustment plan (with unnavoidable cuts in salaries and social benefits and necessary rise of taxes) would imply. In Greece it is already normal for the Troika (the European Commission, the ECB and the IMF), each time that it visits Athens to verify if Greece’s government has implemented its commitments, to confirm that there is lack of forcefulness in the policies applied, especially in relation to the structural reforms. But as the President of the euro group, Juncker, and the Ecofin finally have given the green light for new aid tranches to be given, the government (after Papandreou, Papademos) could, after long nego- tiations, according to the demands of his European partners, and once at home, do half of it. He could even reject the proposals made by his partners (Germany, the first) to provide administrative advi- ce in situ, for instance, in order to create an efficient tax agency and to design and manage infrastructure investment projects. 114
  • 113. The Future of the Euro If with the aid programmes the idea was to buy time to imple- ment structural reforms in the real economy, as the political leaders repeatedly emphasised, time was not used productively in all the countries involved, and Spain was no exception during the last part of Zapatero’s government, when the crisis was not officially denied anymore: fiscal and economic consolidation policies arri- ved late and lacked consistency and force. 4.4. Financial markets, with capacity to persuade One way of overcoming the reluctance of the governments to inexorable political and economic changes in their respective countries comes from the market, specifically the spreads of the risk premiums included in the interest rates where the Treasury may place their issues. As mentioned above, the risk premiums of ten-year bonds, with reference to the German bond, “bund”, reached rocket prices in Greece in 2011 and also considerably in the other peripheral coun- tries with debt problems, including Spain, where the interest rates reached all-time highs of several hundred basis points. The same happened with the credit default swaps (CDS) premiums. No mat- ter how much the governments criticised financial agents for this, not to mention also the three main rating agencies (Fitch, Moody’s, Standard & Poor’s), we cannot understimate its deterrent effect when it is intended to go into greater debt. The increase in price of the debt convinced political leaders in the countries in trouble that 115
  • 114. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance the time of spending happily had gone and that they had to be prepared for a future characterised by austerity. The new govern- ment of Spain (Rajoy) is an example of strict action to modify unsustainable habits in society and restore the economy. In Italy there was a big change of direction since a government of techno- crats (Monti) started in November last year. Ireland had already started in March 2011, after early parliamentary elections and the formation of the new government (Kenny). Three months after that, the same happened in Portugal (Passos Coelho). Therefore, any decision to artificially reduce the interest rates of government bonds, as it has already been taken within the context of rescue packages and as some governments claim, is counterpro- ductive. Eliminating the mechanisms of the market that act, wit- hout political interference, in favour of the quality of public finan- ces, is pointless. Mutualisation of the sovereign debt, no matter how much it is proclaimed by certain political circles (also Spanish, irrespective of ideologies), as well as academic (including German, Keynesian ideas) and financial (especially the most important banks which are anxious to operate in capital markets with great liquidity, comparable to the U.S. market) circles, is also pointless. There is no reason why we should think that issuing eurobonds would improve the quality of the economic policy in the euro area. On the contrary, a reduction in the price of credit in the countries in trouble, which the eurobond would entail, would deteriorate the estimates of low cost, which all categories of public sector outlays and any decision by the public authorities on loan finance, would 116
  • 115. The Future of the Euro be subjected to; furthermore, it would be impossible to put pressu- re on a government from outside to control expenditure and opti- mise tax collection; and, in addition, restructuring processes in the real economy, which are so important to raise the potential of growth, would be postponed. It is far better for the financial mar- kets to deploy their penalising effects and thus complement the relevant mechanisms planned by the SGP and the coming Fiscal Stability Pact. 5. New governance design: own responsibility as the key It seems that European leaders got it into their heads that the euro area needs another kind of governance different from what we have had until now. We will have to carry on thinking in the need for official assiss- tance for certain countries, not only for Greece. As regards Greece, maybe we must think of two options: one, exiting the euro, in principle on a provisional basis (until the fundamental problems have been solved) and continue as a EU member; two, exiting the Economic and Monetary Union, also for a certain time, but kee- ping the euro as dual currency circulation with their own currency. Politicians now understand better than in the past that, for the feasibility of the monetary union in the long term, we need robust and resilient foundations to prevent external shocks of offer and 117
  • 116. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance demand, both from outside and from inside (which in some way or another will happen again). It is not enough to have a determined common monetary policy dealt with by a competent European aut- hority with aims of stability and orderly functioning of inter-bank market. This is only one of the required conditions. Two further fun- damental conditions are inexorable for the context of national eco- nomic policies: • On the one hand, there must be some rules on behaviour in bud- getary and economic policy compatible with the efficiency crite- ria in the allocation of production factors and with growth and employment aims. The problem of “moral hazard” must be totally eliminated. • On the other hand, there must be unconditional willingness of the governments to observe these rules and act according to them. There must be a clear division of work and responsibility between the governments and the ECB. Indeed, efficient European governance means the transfer of the national sovereignty to the European Union in budgetary matters and in areas essential to the real economy. This would entail a qua- litative leap in the process of integration. The three pillars of the new architecture are: • The Euro Plus Pact (approved at the European Summit of 24-25 March 2011, with immediate effect); • The Fiscal Stability Pact (approved at the European Summit on 1st March 2012, with the exception of the United Kingdom and 118
  • 117. The Future of the Euro the Czech Republic, and estimated to come into force, after rati- fication by the national parliaments, on 1st January 2013); • The Macro-economic Governance Pact (approved by the European Parliament in September 2011 and ratified by the European Council, which is in force already). The three Pacts complement one another. Without quality of public finances there will be no appropriate economic growth (“dis- trust effect”), but without economic growth it will be impossible to have organised public accounts (“tax collection weakness effect”), and with no macro-economic balance growth will be slower (“effect of inefficiency in the allocation of production factors”). 5.1. The Euro Plus Pact, it is not binding on anyone This Pact is based on right diagnosis: the potention of growth in southern countries and the capacity to create employment (to a gre- ater or lesser extent) are low owing to the persistence of negative national factors: non-qualified labour, insufficient technological innovation in companies, over-regulation of the labour market and of various services, inefficient bureaucracy, deplorable tax fraud and corruption. For this reason, structural reforms in the economy and the institutions are so necessary. The governments of the countries of the euro area have under- taken to implement it; other six countries of the EU have also 119
  • 118. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance undertaken this commitment (for this reason the term “Plus” has been added to the name of the Pact).6 The scope of action that the Pact contemplates affects the labour market, the educational sys- tem, the environment for research, the tax system and a long etce- tera. All this is praiseworthy. But the main problem of the Pact is that it gives full freedom to the governments to take the measures that they deem appropriate and not to take others that would also be necessary from an objec- tive point of view. There is no sanction in case of lack of strictness. Therefore, this pillar of economic governance of the euro area does not offer security. 5.2. The Fiscal Stability Pact, a test of nine Rightly, the inexorable key is the commitment from the govern- ments to maintain orderly and balanced public finances in the future. This is no dogmatic approach (“neoliberal”, as some call it pejo- ratively), but it is the consequence of an economic analysis, sup- ported by theory and empirical experience. Government deficit must be limited, owing to the “Domar condition”, according to which, for reasons of assignative efficiency, long-term interest rates 6 European Council, Conclusions 24/25 March 2011, Annex I: The Euro Plus Pact – Stronger Economic Policy Coordination for Competitiveness, Bruselas, 25/3/11 (EUCO 10/11, CO EUR 6, CONCL 3). 120
  • 119. The Future of the Euro must be higher than the economic growth rate. With no ceiling for government deficit sooner or later we reach a point from which the financial expenditure of the State (for servicing the debt) increases substantially, which progressively reduces the room for manoeuv- re of the government to seek its economic and social aims. The level of public debt must be limited because of the “Reinhart/Rogoff rule”, derived from econometric studies, which establish a critical threshold of 90% of GDP, from which the secu- lar economic growth rate may diminish at least half a percentage point per year for three reasons: one, because public debt servicing reduces the margin for productive investment of the State (infras- tructures); two, because payment of interest to foreign creditors reduces available national income and, therefore, the capacity of consumption of households; and three, because the need to re- finance sovereign debt makes financing of private companies in capital markets difficult (“expulsion effect”). The Ltmus test is characterised by strictness under which the governments deepen in budgetary consolidation. Despite the fact that in different countries of the euro area some measures invol- ving tax adjustment have been taken already, public finances are not consolidated at all. According to the European Office of Statistics (Eurostat), government deficit is excessive (more than 3% of GDP) in most of the countries, also in Spain (2011: 8.5% of GDP). Germany (1%) and four small countries (Estonia, Finland, Luxembourg and Malta) are the few exceptions. Most of the government deficits are structural, in other words, not cyclic but 121
  • 120. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance permanent, and, therefore, destructive for the good functioning of the economy. The level of public debt is also too high (higher than 60% of GDP) in almost all the countries, including Germany (2011: 81.2%) and France (85.8%) and now also Spain (68.5%), for the first time since 2011, Spain (68%). Where public debt greatly exceeds all acceptable levels according to the “Reinhart/Rogoff rule” is in the three countries that have been rescued (Greece, Ireland and Portugal) and in Italy. For the latter country, however, there is a differentiating factor in its favour, most of the public debt is internal and, thus, its servicing may be managed directly with its own instruments (by increasing fiscal pressure on its citizens). As mentioned above, the rules on sustainability of public finan- ces as set forth in the Treaty of the European Union and in the SGP have not been efficient to impose budgetary discipline. Its applica- tion has been highly politicised. The mechanisms of penalisation have never been implemented. The new Fiscal Pact has been arran- ged in such a manner that it could put the screws, firstly, on the euro countries on which the agreement is binding.7 The most important advances as regards the SGP, for the moment only on paper, are the following three: • Firstly, the seriousness of government deficit is explicitly ack- nowledged when it is structural. The explicit ceiling established 7 European Council, Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union, 2/3/12, artículos 3-8. Internet: http//:eur-lex.europa.eu. 122
  • 121. The Future of the Euro is 0.5% of GDP, maintaining the threshold of 3% for total defi- cit. There is thus a large margin for the operation of “automatic stabilisers” in the economic cycle and for discretionary govern- mental measures if there is recession. • Secondly, the aim of limiting the level of public debt at 60% of GDP through a procedure which, if the debt exceeds this per- centage, may activate the supervisory mechanism for “excessive government deficit”, even if the deficit is below 3% of GDP. The country in question shall be forced to reduce it at an average rate of one twentieth per year as a benchmark (“1/20 clause”). • Thirdly, the obligation for each member country to define its medium-term budgetary objective (MTO), quantifying an indi- cator for public expenditure evolution and making sure that the estimated expenditure shall be financed by sustainable income (“golden rule” of budgetary balance). If a country does not orga- nise its budgets in a balanced manner it will be required by the European Commission to submit new budgetary plans. If the new rules are important, a mechanism to enforce them is equally important. The most relevant three new elements are the following: • First, continuous supervision of the policies applied in both summits of the euro area has been devised (two per year, at least, called and chaired by the President of the EU, currently Herman Van Rompuy). • Second, there is a change in the decision process on financial sanctions (of up to 0.2% of GDP) in case of breach and non-ful- 123
  • 122. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance filment of the specific recommendations to remedy the situa- tion in the sense that a proposal of the European Commission is considered approved if the Council of the Heads of State and Government of the euro area does not vote against it with a qua- lified majority (until now such a majority was required for the European Council to approve the sanction). Therefore, there will be less room for political maneuvre to prevent the fine (as it was normal in the past after the Schröder/Chirac precedent mentio- ned above). The sanctions are not totally automatic as one would like them to be, but they are moving in that direction. Furthermore, they have a broader scope than before, because the manipulation of fiscal statistics shall also be punished. • Third, the obligation for each member country to transpose the fiscal stability rule into its national legislation is established and, therefore, be explicitly responsible for its fulfilment. The Court of Justice of the EU shall ensure its fulfilment. For the States to decide the medium-term budgetary stability (equivalent to the economic cycle), the most credible formula is to constitutionally estabish a ceiling for structural government deficit. Germany has already done it (0.35% of GDP for the central govern- ment, from 2016, and cero deficit for the federal states, from 2020). Spain is moving in that direction after the reform of article 135 of the Constitution at the end of the previous term of office and the recent approval of the Budgetary Stability Law which will require from 2020 cero structural deficit to the public authorities (which could be up to 0.4% of GDP in exceptional circumstances). Other 124
  • 123. The Future of the Euro countries are moving in that direction. The advantage of a consti- tutional rule as regards de margin of debt of the government is that, if a country incurs deficit and constitutional breach, it will need bet- ter arguments for its society than if it only needs to be explained before the Community authorities and take there the relevant war- nings; Brussels is “far” and it is “under suspicion” of meddling in national affairs. The Fiscal Pact will only work if the euro area countries are willing to do without most of its sovereignty in budgetary matters, which will be transferred to Community institutions. Obviously, this affects the main prerogative of national parliaments, which is to shape the budgets of the State and decide how to finance expen- diture. This will meet great opposition, in all the countries. It is not a trivial matter that the Fiscal Pact must be institutionalised through an inter-governmental agreement, that is to say, a level lower than the Treaty of the EU, which reform would have requi- red the unanimous approval of the twenty-seven, which was not reached. This procedure has opened in the legal field a debate to decide if the procedure chosen is compatible with Community Law, specifically in relation to the mechanisms of sanctions for excessive government deficit as set forth in article 126 of the Treaty. For European leaders to have lowered the quorum required for parliamentary approval of the inter-governmental agreement is not a trivil matter either, to 12 of the 17 States that form part of the euro area. Could it be that some partners are not reliable? It is true that it has been decided that the countries that do not ratify the 125
  • 124. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance Pact and transpose to their national legislation the ceiling of government deficit will be excluded from possible financial bai- lout. However, is this credible, especially if the stability of the euro area is at risk? This being so, it would be better not to be too hope- ful about this Fiscal Pact. 5.3. The Macro-economic Governance Pact, with vague parameters The same caution is advisable with regards to the solemnly proclaimed Six Pack (so called because its content has been draf- ted through a Community directive and five regulations). Nodoby doubts that, for the feasibility of the euro area, macro- economic stability is a necessary condition (although not enough if the requirements for an optimal monetary area are not fulfi- lled). Furthermore, it is true that macro-economic stability goes beyond budgetary balance, as it has been proven with the recent experience of different countries (inflationary pressure, property bubble, excessive private sector debt, competitive weakness of companies, current account imbalance, etc.). However, the European Commission, the European Parliament and the European Council seem to have faith in the capacity of economic policy to handle crucial factors in the real economy. This is highly questionable. An alert mechanism scoreboard was created for the appearance of internal and external imbalances in the countries, which will be 126
  • 125. The Future of the Euro managed by the European Commission based on ten parameters, as follows: 8 • Internal imbalance parameters: evolution of unit labour cost, unemployment rate, private sector indebtedness, credit to the private sector, evolution of property prices and government indebtedness. • External imbalance parameters: surplus and deficit of current account balance, net international investment position, change of export market shares and change of the real effective exchange rates of the euro. For these parameters, critical thresholds have been established, from which the alarm would be triggered, and this would start a procedure to analyse the causes in order to decide from Europe if corrective measures need to be taken or not. For instance, for unit labour costs the threshold is an increase of 9% in three years, for unemployment rates it is 10% of the workforce as a three-year ave- rage or for current account balance the threshold established is 3 year backward moving average of the current account balance as a per cent of GDP, with a threshold of +6% of GDP (surplus) and -4% of GDP (deficit). If there is excessive imbalance, the European Commission will make the relevant recommendations for the government of the country in question to remedy the imbalance; in case of non-fulfilment, a fine may be imposed (up to 0.1% of GDP). 8 European Commission, EU Economic governance “Six Pack“ enters into force, MEMO/11/898, 12/12/2011. 127
  • 126. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance The thresholds set are not a consequence of a detailed economic and empirical analysis that may indicate for sure when an imba- lance is excessive for a country and negatively affects the euro area as a whole. The numerical values rather represent the perception of politicians of the recent events; therefore, they are, unavoidably, arbitrary. But the fundamental question is different: How can a government act efficiently? We must remember that the EU proposes an open market eco- nomy with free competition (article 119 of the Treaty of the EU). All euro countries have this concept of economic system, some becau- se of the Ludwig Erhard tradition (Germany), and others with reser- vation in favour of the government (France). In a market economy, the government lacks the instruments to control the variables con- templated in this Macro-economic Governance Pact. Therefore, the governments should activate a series of interventionist measures, with no guarantee of their efficiency and with a high risk of distor- ting efficiency in the allocation of production factors. In a market economy, responsibilities are distributed in a different way: for level of employment, social partners (unions and employers); for export development, private companies (technology); or for granting loans, commercial banks (based on the appropriate risk estimate). The current account balance, among other things, represents the saving trend rooted in society and objective conditions for fixed capital investment (as explained by the “macro-economic equa- tion” and the “Böhm-Bawerk theorem”). Unions will not accept government interference in the negotiation of collective agree- 128
  • 127. The Future of the Euro ments and companies will not stop being creative or innovative in organisational management and product development for which elasticity-income of international demand is higher than the unit, and banks will not neglect their classical business, which is to pro- vide credit to companies and households. This economic governance project has no clear future. In the best-case scenario, the new Summits of the euro area would have matters to discuss. The countries in which the economy works well could be taken as a benchmark for the others to rectify their struc- tural deficiencies and improve their productive and competitive- ness levels. In the worst-case scenario, the euro area would be expo- sed to continuous political conflicts, which would not promote economic growth with high employment. It is so easy, and espe- cially politically profitable in countries with domestic problems, to look for the villain abroad, maybe Germany? Conclusion The sovereign debt crisis has had a healthy effect in convincing politicians that by providing liquidity to governments and banks the stability of the euro area will not be attained in the medium and long term. The quality of the economic policy must improve in the countries, there must be impeccable follow-up by indepen- dent institutions to weigh up the economic and fiscal situation and it must be guaranteed that national accounts and other relevant statistics are arranged under utmost scientific accuracy at all times. 129
  • 128. The European Crisis and the challenge of efficient economic governance If in all the euro countries the governments understand that sound public finances and application of structural reforms is their responsibility and if they act seriously according to them, no State will have to rescue another State because of over-indebtedness and waste, and the ECB may stop indirectly financing States and focus more on its task, ensuring stability in price levels in the euro area. The ESM fund would be reserved to emergency situations caused by external factors beyond the government’s control. The Fiscal Pact would have fulfilled its mission and the Euro Plus Pact would be filled with efficient contents. We would not need to resort to mar- ket interventionism as entailed with the Six Pack. If, on the contrary, there is no determination in the member countries, any attempt of European economic governance would result more from proactive intentions than harsh reality. The euro area would have an uncertain future. The alternative of a European Political Union, in which all necessary economic policies could be undertaken from a Community Executive under the control of the European Parliament, with all democratic rights, cannot be seen on the horizon. 130
  • 129. /GONZALO GARCÍA ANDRÉS * / The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity 1. Introduction; 2. Anatomy of the crisis: Greece, the contagion and the per- verse dynamics of debt; 2.1. Sovereign credit risk within the euro: from zero to infinity; 2.2. A fiscal problem, not the fiscal problem; 2.3. Contagion: the fragmentation of the single monetary policy; 2.4 A particular manifestation of the global financial crisis; 3. The Eurosystem at a crossroads; 3.1. Intra- system balances as an expression of the fragmentation of monetary policy; 3.2. Quantitative easing for banks only; 4. The definitive solution must begin in 2012; 5. Conclusion; Bibliography * Member of the Technical Body of the Spanish Civil Services (Técnico Comercial Economista del Estado) and Graduate of Economics at Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. He has spent a large part of his professional career in the current General Office of Treasury and Financial Policy in the Ministry of the Economy and Competitiveness of Spain. He held the office of Deputy Director of Financial and Strategic Analysis, res- ponsible for financial stability and crisis management issues, international financial policy (EU, G20) and adviser to the Social Security Reserve Fund. In September 2009 he was appointed Deputy Director of Funding and Debt Management, where within a few months he was involved in the adaptation of the Treasury funding programme to the instability generated by the Greek fiscal crisis and its contagion throughout the rest of the euro region. From September 2010 to January 2012 he has held the office of Director General for International Finance, which has enabled him to form part of the manage- ment boards of the European Investment Bank and of CESCE. He has likewise been Associate Professor in Economic Theory at Universidad Rey Juan Carlos and has publis- hed several articles on regulatory, financial and monetary matters in Spanish journals. 131
  • 130. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity 1. Introduction The Monetary Union is a political construction, the boldest and most significant step forward by the European project since the Treaty of Rome. Its conception also had an economic basis, that of completing the consolidation of the economic integration process which was begun in 1985. However, its implementation was a great adventure. The countries that use the euro are far from constituting an optimal monetary zone. In addition to the evident initial diffe- rences in the economic and institutional structure of the countries and in their histories of stability, the euro was forced to make room for disparate economic philosophies. The European leaders elected to create a very light institutional structure, with an independent federal monetary authority, an apparently severe budgetary discipline (the Stability and Growth Pact or SGP) and the rule of no mutual support (in order to rein- force the individual fiscal stability of each State). During its first ten years the euro appeared to be working relati- vely well. Average real growth exceeded 2% and both the level and the volatility of inflation improved in comparison to the previous He is currently an adviser in the General Deputy Office of Financial and Economic Matters of the European Union and the Eurozone which is part of the General Office of the Treasury and Financial Policy. The opinions expressed in this article pertain to the author and under no circumstance may be attributed to the Ministry of the Economy and Competitiveness. 132
  • 131. The Future of the Euro decade, although the differences in the macro-economic and finan- cial behaviour of the members were quite considerable. Although the Stability and Growth Pact was reformed mid-decade, no signi- ficant alterations were made to the institutional framework and the number of members gradually grew. The onset of the financial cri- sis in 2007 initially underlined this perception of the euro as somet- hing imperfect but solid. However, a little after its 11th anniversary, three interconnected calamities fell upon the euro. Firstly, one of its members plumme- ted towards insolvency in just three months. Secondly, the politi- cal pact on which the single currency was built began to shake when financial assistance within the area became inevitable. And thirdly, the unity in regard to monetary policy fell apart with the dislocation of the public debt markets. Two years later, and despite having taken decisive steps in natio- nal policies and in institutional framework reform, the crisis of the euro has deteriorated to the point of calling its survival into ques- tion; and a definitive solution is yet to be glimpsed. With the bene- fit of hindsight, it is worth attempting to interpret was has happe- ned, taking into account the extreme complexity both of the initial situations (with accumulated imbalances and structural deficien- cies in several countries), as well as the outbreak, contagion and escalation of the crisis. And to do so moreover against the broader backdrop of the global financial crisis, which has influenced eco- nomic and financial evolution for five years, in order to identify 133
  • 132. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity which specific aspects of the euro have played a vital role. All the above with the aim of helping come up with solutions, bringing together the most urgent ones and those of a longer term basis. 2. Anatomy of the crisis: Greece, contagion and the perverse dynamics of debt 2.1. Sovereign credit risk within the euro: from zero to infinity The natural starting point of the analysis of the crisis is the behaviour of sovereign debt markets. The creation of the euro gave way to a number of markets for debt securities issued by sovereign states but denominated in the same currency. This is an atypical configuration with few precedents, given that sovereign debt secu- rities are usually associated with the bond that exists between the issuer and monetary sovereignty. Until 2007 the markets considered that the very creation of the Monetary Union had reduced sovereign credit risk to a very small level. For example, the spread between the ten year Greek bond and the ten year German bund fell within a range between 10 and 30 basis points between 2002 and 2007. In spite of GDP growing at relatively high rates, the level and performance of the fiscal and current account imbalances in Greece had justified a much higher risk premium. 134
  • 133. The Future of the Euro With the outbreak of the global financial crisis, credit risk spre- ads among Eurozone countries widened. But this trend – common to all of the world financial markets –, was mainly due to risk aver- sion and an increase in the demand of assets deemed to be safer (Barrios et al, 2009). The spreads thus adopted a trend towards moderation throughout 2009, all amid a context of low absolute financing costs for the sovereign issuers. Towards November 2009, an alteration in the behaviour of sove- reign debt markets took place, which in hindsight can be conside- red as a structural change. The almost perfect convergence since the beginning of the Monetary Union1 therefore gave way to a cumulative bifurcation, reflecting the binary behaviour of the mar- kets. This is a dynamic system with two main features: • Systematic inefficiency. Bond market prices do not reflect the fundamental information on credit risk determining factors. Until 2009, the spreads had been smaller than would be justified by the main variables (debt stock, deficit, international invest- ment position, real exchange rate); since autumn 2009, the spre- ads have been systematically higher than would be justified by the performance of the fundamental variables. This gap betwe- en market prices and economic fundamentals has been noted in several empirical studies (Aizenman, Hutchison & Jinjarak (2011), De Grauwe & Ji (2012)). 1 The average 10 year debt spread in Eurozone countries against Germany was of only 18 basis points between 1999 and mid-2007. 135
  • 134. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity • Tendency towards instability. The euro sovereign debt markets have shown themselves to be incapable of adjusting their credit risk assessments in a stable manner. Their capacity for discrimi- nation has been non-existent for years, with a high demand for bonds from countries exposed to vulnerability, which were dee- med to be almost perfect replacements for the German bund. And in these last two years, the trend has been explosive. In micro-economic terms, instability means that given an excess supply of bonds, a drop in price does not bring it back to balan- ce. But furthermore, we must point out that the explosive natu- re of the sovereign debt markets since the beginning of 2010 has become more noticeable than that reflected in market prices. ECB intervention has lessened the trend towards increases which are sharp and not related with new fundamental infor- mation on the likelihood of default by various countries in the region. On the basis of this general outlook of the dynamics of debt markets, a distinction must be made between the Greek market and the rest. 2.2 A fiscal problem, not the fiscal problem The Greek situation is special. In October 2009, the new Greek government announced that the public deficit for the year would be somewhat over double that which had been forecast (12.7% of GDP versus the expected 6%). This setback of Greek public debt 136
  • 135. The Future of the Euro was thus triggered by a fundamental fiscal surprise of considerable dimensions. Greece has systematically managed its public finances poorly since joining the euro.2 It has taken advantage of the financial benefits of belonging to the euro to increase expenditure, while maintaining a pro-cyclical fiscal orientation during a clearly expan- sive phase. The Hellenic country has thus made real one of the worst fears of the founders of the euro in regard to the risk of free- rider fiscal behaviours. The bad news is that neither the market dis- cipline under the non-mutual guarantee clause nor the Stability and Growth Pact have managed to correct this situation, which has worsened further due to continuous problems regarding reliability of public accounts. The Greek public debt market has also followed a pattern of inefficiency and instability. Gibson, Hall & Tavlas (2011) have identified a systematic bias between the credit risk spread adjusted to the main determining variables and the market spread. Nevertheless, the collapse of the market is not difficult to explain. The depth of the fiscal crisis and its structural nature, added to the uncertainty and lack of confidence generated by the handling of accounts, spread the perception among investors of inevitable insolvency with a certain risk of loss of principal. 2 In fact, its public deficit has never been below 3% since it joined the monetary union. 137
  • 136. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity What is hard to explain is why the Greek crisis spread to the rest of the public debt markets in the area. Firstly, the weight of Greece in the GDP of the Eurozone (around 2.3%) does not justify that its fiscal crisis should become a systemic problem. Secondly, no other Eurozone member country is anywhere near this level of systema- tic poor management of public funds and continuous breach of the rules of the Monetary Union. There are two factors in the Greek collapse during the first semester of 2010 which became important for the operation of the rest of the Monetary Union. To begin with, the fragility of the domestic debt markets within the Eurozone became clear. Secondly, the political tension generated by the intra-zone finan- cial aid revealed a considerable institutional weakness. Discussions prior to the approval of the loan to Greece brought to light that the politics of the countries in the zone were about to take on a hard line of fiscal adjustments and onerous conditions in the financial aid defended by creditor countries, in stark contrast with the posi- tion of countries which were beginning to feel the effect of the tur- bulence in Greece as of January. Even so, it seems impossible to explain how the Greek crisis became a euro crisis in light of only these two factors. Particularly, following the creation in May 2010 in response to the explosive market situation, of the European Financial Stability Facility and the start of the intervention by the Eurosystem via the Securities Market Programme. 138
  • 137. The Future of the Euro 2.3 Contagion: the fragmentation of the single monetary policy The strategy we have chosen to explain the spread from Greece throughout all of the Monetary Union is a two-phased approach. The first phase attempts to define the morphology of the crisis, which may help, at a second phase, to get to the bottom of its nature. These are the main morphological characteristics of the crisis: • Systemic for the entire Eurozone. The crisis is often discussed as if it only affects part of the Monetary Union; along the same lines, it is argued that this is not a crisis of the euro, on the grounds of exchange rate levels or price stability. In fact, since the generalised dislocation of the debt markets was sparked off towards the end of April 2010, the crisis has indeed become a euro crisis. It affects all member countries, albeit in opposite way. There has been a flow of capital from the more indebted countries to the creditor countries, which has been reflected in the yields of public debt and other securities. Thus, the impact of the fiscal irresponsibility of one of the members has not resulted in a generalised increase in interest rates as was expec- ted (Dombret (2012)). It has had an asymmetric impact, punis- hing countries with greater financial vulnerability and benefi- ting the stronger ones. • Specific to the Eurozone. The financial bifurcation movement has been limited to the member states, despite having some 139
  • 138. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity effect on the rest of the world.3 There is no sovereign debt glo- bal crisis; on the contrary, public debt yields in the main deve- loped countries have reached historic minimal levels. Thus, the main non Euro indebted countries (United Kingdom, United Sates) have seen an increase in the demand of sovereign debt as a result of the euro crisis. For instance, at the start of 2010, ten year British debt securities traded at levels similar to the Spanish ones. The worsening of the crisis in the Eurozone has meant that the British debt is just a few basis points away from the German debt. The negative contagion has therefore only affected euro members, whereas the positive contagion of public debt has managed to reach other markets. • Its dynamics are financial and autonomous, not defined by fundamental economic variables. This statement calls for an explanation because… doesn’t Ireland have a serious solvency problem in its banking system? Isn’t Portugal undergoing a current unsustainable imbalance? Doesn’t Spain have a high public deficit and an excess of private debt? How will Italy manage to sustain a public debt stock of 120% of the GDP and a GDP growth trend below 1%? … and we could move on to Belgium and then to France. All the euro countries which have suffered the restriction of their external financing terms in the 3 The Euro crisis has become the main factor threatening the recovery of the world eco- nomy and the consolidation of the progress made in restoring financial stability after the global crisis. However, at this point only direct spreading via debt markets is dis- cussed. 140
  • 139. The Future of the Euro last two years are facing serious problems. But the existence of such problems does not make them causes for the dislocation of the debt markets and the consequences thereof. In fact, in all cases we are dealing with problems with which the markets have been well acquainted for years. There are two ways of illustrating the secondary role played by economic fundamentals in the cri- sis. One is to compare euro countries affected with other non- euro countries with similar fundamentals. Aizenman et al (2011) have done this by matching Spain with South Africa and con- cluding that the greater risk spread in Spain cannot be explained by the worse levels in the variables which have determined cre- dit quality ratings. The other is to verify whether an improve- ment in the fundamentals (including economic policy measures required to achieve this) has had a positive impact on the finan- cing terms. For example, affected countries have considerably reduced their primary deficits adjusted to the cycle, although this has not helped to improve the perception of the fiscal situa- tion. This does not mean that the fundamentals are not impor- tant when determining the vulnerability of a country, or that the economic policies adopted in response to the crisis have not proven vital in halting or slowing down the impact of the crisis. But it is important to stress that the crisis is essentially not a pro- blem of fundamental economic variables. • It has become apparent through the inversion of the capital flow pattern within the euro. For years, the economies with lower rates of savings (such as Greece or Portugal) or higher 141
  • 140. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity investment rates (such as Spain) comfortably financed their large deficits via private flows of capital from countries with hig- her rates of savings and lower investment rates. As of spring 2010, many of these countries have been forced to face an inte- rruption, and in some cases a sudden inversion, of external funds, as shown by the performances of their financial accounts (see Graph 1 for Spain). Part of that capital has been diverted to creditor countries. From this perspective, the crisis can be understood as a series of sudden stops (with their pertaining sudden goes) in capital flows within the Monetary Union. The most acute episodes of the crisis have thus coincided with an intensification of the external financial restriction. In short, it is about a crisis in the balance of payments within the particular framework of the Monetary Union, whose adjustment variable is not the amount of reserves but the net funding of the Eurosystem. By combining these characteristics, the crisis can be defined as a cumulative coordination failure, with a positive feedback.4 The key mechanism underlying this failure is the effect that the dislo- 4 The concept of coordination failure arises as part of an alternative interpretation of Keynes’ analysis to that of the Neoclassical Synthesis, which considers there is a deeper explanation for unemployment and instability problems than salary rigidity. In a first formulation, it can be associated with the Macroeconomics of imbalance. Subsequently, within the framework of New Keynesian Economics, this is analysed with different models which have strategic interdependence and multiple balances in common (Cooper and John, 1991). In the context of the financial crisis, the coordination failu- res have played a core role, linked to uncertainty and the effect thereof on expectations. 142
  • 141. The Future of the Euro Graph 1 Net Loan and Financial Account balance of Spain Source: Bank of Spain cation of the operation of the public debt market has over the mechanism of monetary transmission and, in the last resort, on the financing conditions of the non-financial private sector. Indeed, the public debt markets, in addition to procuring state funding, play a central role in the operation of the monetary and financial systems. The yield curve of public debt, considered to be the risk-free asset, serves as the main price reference for the rest of the credit and securities markets, acting as a floor for financing costs for all other agents. On the other hand, the implementation of monetary policy traditionally uses government securities as asset guarantees. And financial institutions, and credit institutions, UCITs and pension funds in particular, often keep a considerable amount of sovereign bonds in their portfolios. 143
  • 142. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity The dislocation of the public debt markets has had a devastating effect on the affected economies. The increase in volatility (see Graph 2 for the Spanish market) and the upturn in the credit risk spread without any underlying new fundamental information have restricted funding for the non-financial sector in various ways. Directly, insofar as market-funded companies must pay more for issues. And indirectly, and more importantly given the finan- cial structure of the euro economies, it operates via the banking system. Bank access to market funding is restricted in terms of volume and prices, whilst the value of both their public debt hol- dings and other market shares continues to fall. The result is a res- triction in funding available to businesses and households. Graph 2 Historical volatility of Spanish debt Source: Bloomberg 144
  • 143. The Future of the Euro This situation gives rise a contracting spiral which generates a perverse dynamics in the sustainability of public debt. The first reac- tion from countries suffering from a financial restriction mainly of their debt markets is the acceleration of fiscal adjustment which, in principle, appears to be a logical and reasonable response. The pro- blem is that a combination of a strong contractive fiscal approach and financial restriction weakens the nominal GDP. This leads to an increase in the nominal fiscal adjustment required to achieve a deficit target in relation to the GDP. Unemployment rises, disposa- ble income falls and the creditworthiness of businesses and house- holds deteriorates. The result is a deterioration of the Debt/GDP ratio, with a feedback effect. In summary, the dislocation of public debt markets generated an endogenous monetary restriction, equal to a drastic toughening up of monetary policy in the most affected countries. The transmis- sion mechanism of the policy established by the ECB no longer works in a fairly uniform manner, upset by the intensity of the pri- vate funding flows and the effect thereof on expectations. The result is the breakdown of the single monetary policy. 2.4. A particular manifestation of the global financial crisis The symptoms of this disease afflicting the Monetary Union seem very familiar by now: debt markets which no longer work nor- mally, spreads with an explosive tendency, asset liquidation at dis- counted prices (fire sales), banks in the grip of liability restrictions 145
  • 144. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity and falling asset values, gaps between the financial sector and the real economy. In fact the mechanism is identical to that which led to the subprime mortgage debacle in the systemic crisis of develo- ped economies in 2007-2009. The main difference is that both the source and the means of contagion were in that case the private debt markets, whereas in the Eurozone the dislocation has mainly taken place in public debt markets. But the analogy is valid in analytical terms and can prove quite useful when considering the regulatory implications which will result from the crisis resolution. The effect on monetary policy was similar, although at that time the public debt markets carried on as normal and could continue to be used to tackle the endogenous restriction in the financing con- ditions of the private sector with firm and innovative measures. Several studies on the nature of the global financial crisis have highlighted the importance of the increase in uncertainty when seeking to understand and resolve it. Caballero (2010) considers that the financial crisis, which appears similar to a heart attack, is the product of a combination of uncertainty as defined by Knight and the complexity of the structure of the financial system. These two factors amplify the initial shock effect, with forced sales of assets and liquidity strangulations which drive a wedge between the financial sector and the real economy, preventing the proper operation of the economy and the markets.5 The solution requi- 5 This then leads to large scale coordination failure, in the sense mentioned at the end of the previous note. 146
  • 145. The Future of the Euro res the State to become an insurer of last resort, providing insurance against uncertainty to persuade the agents that the less likely nega- tive scenarios will not take place. This enables the coil to snap, thus coordinating agents at higher comfort levels. This financial crisis model can be applied to the Eurozone. The Greek fiscal surprise and its rapid decline towards insolvency would be the initial shock, generating confusion among agents and leading them to reconsider their perception of sovereign risk wit- hin the euro. The complexity of the financial interrelations within the area, along with the emergence of political differences, disse- minates lack of confidence to all other markets. And the rapid dis- location of the debt markets increases uncertainty, hits the banks in affected countries and ends up by paralyzing the workings of their financial system and depressing the real economy. The inten- sity of self-fulfilling prophecies in the markets increases the uncer- tainty regarding the outlooks for the countries and for the Monetary Union as a whole. Investors fear the possibility that the market dynamics should cause solvent countries to lose access to new funding. Definitive uncertainty appears when the disintegration of the Monetary Union, which seemed like a bad joke even at the start of 2010, becomes a scenario deemed likely by main investors. In fact, the persistence of such huge spreads between the public debt of member countries is an unequivocal indicator that the market is taking the possibility of disintegration very seriously. Investors 147
  • 146. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity accept negative real returns in the short term and no return in the medium and long term of the German public debt because they believe that, given a break-up scenario, these assets are the ones which will guarantee the security and continuity of the euro. It is a fact that certain partial insurance mechanisms to deal with the effects of the crisis have been implemented in the Eurozone. On the one hand, the Eurosystem has performed the role of lender of last resort for the banking system with force, adap- ting its role to perceived needs. On the other hand, the creation of a system of financial aid as a component of the institutional fra- mework of the Monetary Union also constitutes a significant collective insurance item. But as we pointed out in the introduc- tion, for the time being these instruments, along with the steps taken at a national level, have not managed to prevent crisis relap- ses. The relapse of summer 2011 was particularly serious, as it underlined its systemic nature and struck both Italy and Spain, with an ensuing financial strangulation that has led to a new reces- sion in the region. 3. The Eurosystem at a crossroads The ECB and the 17 National Central Banks (NCB) comprise the most powerful institution in the Monetary Union. Its legal inde- pendence is greater than that of other central banks in developed countries and, like them, it has the essential power of unlimited cre- 148
  • 147. The Future of the Euro ation of money. In contrast with the rest of Monetary Union bodies, the Eurosystem is capable of making decisions and of expediently executing them. Even so, it is not a central bank like all the others. During its first decade of life, the difficulty entailed in setting a sin- gle monetary policy to be applied to a group of economies with dif- ferent fiscal policies and economic and financial cycles became patently clear. But since the Greek crisis, the task has become extra- ordinarily complicated: on the one hand, due to mix of the fiscal origin of the problem and the financial nature of the contagion; and on the other, as a result of the tension which the solutions con- sidered has produced between the Bundesbank philosophy and that of the more pragmatic (and closer to Federal Reserve and Bank of England standards) monetary policy of the all the others. The Eurosystem has been in the eye of the storm for the last two years and its performance has been the target of criticism from all angles: there are those who resent it not having acted in a suffi- ciently forceful way and there are others who believe that the SMP and the Long-Term Funding Operations are causing it to deviate from its mandate and endanger price stability. With our sights set on the search for a definitive solution to the crisis, let us attempt to better understand the implications of what has happened for the single monetary policy and the response given by the Eurosystem. 149
  • 148. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity 3.1. Intra-system balances as an expression of the fragmentation of monetary policy It would have all been simpler if the impact of the Greek fiscal debacle would have been a generalised increase in public securities interest rates in all other euro members. The Eurosystem would have been able to counteract this effect by adjusting the tone of its monetary policy. However, the contagion has driven a wedge wit- hin the euro-debt financial markets, where capital is flowing towards creditor countries and away from debtor countries. The dislocation of the debt markets has endowed the net fun- ding of the private sector in each country with strongly endoge- nous dynamics, as can be observed in Graph 3. Despite the expan- sive tone of the monetary policy of the ECB, in Ireland, Portugal, Greece and Spain, businesses and households have had to face a drop in the supply of funds, which in recent months has also affec- ted Italy. In countries such as Finland, the net capital inflow has magnified the expansive tone of the monetary policy. The Eurosystem has thus had to face the most difficult problem since its foundation, in that it directly questions the unity of the monetary policy within the area. The alteration in the pattern of financial flows within the region has substantially modified the geographical distribution of balances within the Eurosystem. As we have already mentioned, 150
  • 149. The Future of the Euro within a monetary union a deficit in the domestic balance of pay- ments is best funded with a greater appeal made by the banking system of the country to the Eurosystem. If we take a close look at the evolution of the financial account balance of Spain, excluding the Bank of Spain and the Net Eurosystem Loan granted to the Spanish banking system (Graph 1), we can conclude that deficits in the balance of payments have been offset by an increase in appeals to funding via monetary policy operations. The result of this is that the counterparts of the monetary base (which can be calculated from the Eurosystem consolidated balan- ce sheet) are now more concentrated in those countries which Graph 3 Interannual Growth rate Bank Funding of the non-financial private sector in Feb 2012 Source: Bank of Spain 151
  • 150. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity have experienced the dislocation of their debt markets and the res- triction of private sector funding. The accounting reflection of these financial dynamics can be found in the sharp increase of the so-called intra-system balances. The monetary policy decided by the Eurosystem is applied in a decentralised fashion, in that it is carried out via national central banks. The net balance of the operations of a given country with all other countries in the area generates a book entry shown as the balance variation between each national central bank (NCB) and the ECB. These intra-system balances, required to ensure the iden- tity between assets and liabilities in the NCBs and an appropriate distribution of seigniorage, disappear when the balances are aggre- gated in the consolidated balance sheet of the Eurosystem, as the sum of positive balances is equal to the sum of the negative ones. The component of these intra-system balances which explains its sharp increase during the crisis is the one that relates to the varia- tions in the net balance of outstanding operations settled via TAR- GET2, whose counterpart entity is the ECB.6 These operations can be either private inter-bank transactions or monetary policy opera- 6 The other basic component of intra-system balances is that related with the issue of euro banknotes. Both the ECB and the NCBs issue euro banknotes in accordance with a key (8% allocated to ECB and an adjusted allocation by the NCBs). Then the NCBs release them based on demand. The difference between the allocated issue of bankno- tes and the release thereof into real circulation generates an intra-system balance, which is required for a fair distribution of seniority associated with banknote issue. Germany has the highest negative balance under this heading. 152
  • 151. The Future of the Euro tions between a NCB and a private counterparty. To a large extent, the sign and amount of the balance depend on the relationship bet- ween the public or private source of the money of commercial banks in the central bank. When commercial banks increase their deposits in the central bank as a result of an increase in private fun- ding received (deposits, loans or security issues), they tend to redu- ce their appeal to central bank funding (as we assume that they seek to limit their reserve surplus). The counterpart of this increase in liabilities and decrease in assets as a result of the net loan is a posi- tive balance held by the central bank with the Eurosystem, accruing at the reference interest rate. On the contrary, a drop in private fun- ding makes the banks increase their appeal to the central bank. In this case, the counterpart of the increase in assets is a negative balance in the liabilities with the Eurosystem. Germany, which had a very moderate positive balance before the outbreak of the global financial crisis, has gone on to have over half a billion euros of positive balance by the end of February 2012 (see Graph 4). The German Banks have reduced their appeals to the Eurosystem, as they receive funding at very favourable terms from the market and have furthermore reduced their asset posi- tions in other euro member countries. On the contrary, Greece, Ireland, Portugal and, more recently, Spain and Italy, have experienced an increase in their negative balances to very high levels, due to their banks having had to off- set the loss of private funding. 153
  • 152. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity Graph 4 TARGET2 Balanace Source: Whitaker, Central Bank of Ireland, Bank of Spain, Bank of Greece, Bank of Portugal, Deutsche Bundesbank The growing trend of intra-system balances was interpreted by Sinn (2010) as a stealth bailout by Germany of countries with nega- tive balances, going as far as proposing correction measures there- of. Although it found some support among German academic media (see Declaration of Bobenberg, 2011), Sinn’s interpretation was subsequently refuted in several articles which have attempted to shed light on the nature and significance of intra-system balan- ces (Bindseil & König (2011), Jobst (2011), Borhorst & Mody (2012)). The debate saw a later resurgence, to a large extent due to the concern expressed by the Chairman of the Bundesbank in a let- ter addressed to the Chairman of the ECB.7 Sinn (2012) suggests 7 Shortly after this letter was made public, the Chairman of the Bundesbank published an article in the press which explained the position of his institution in this debate. 154
  • 153. The Future of the Euro the establishment of a system for annual settlement of intra-system balances with liquid assets with guarantees from each country (on real estate assets or on future tax income). In his opinion, it would be a system similar to that which exists in the United States within the Federal Reserve System. In order to adequately interpret the evolution of intra-system balances it is worth remembering the following points: • Balances are the result of the normal execution of monetary policy. These are therefore flows between the Eurosystem and the banking systems (in no case bilateral between central banks), of a monetary nature (these are not real flows of cash or fiscal transfers) and resulting from the use that the Eurosystem counterparts make of monetary policy operations. • Under present conditions, the greater appeal to the Eurosystem Net Loan by the banking system of a country does not reduce the funding available to the banking system of another country. • The risk of loss assumed by the NCB on the assets of the Eurosystem balance is in line with its allocation of the ECB capi- tal and does not depend on the size of its intra-system balance. • Proposals to limit the maximum volume of these balances are equal to calling into question an essential principle of the opera- tion of the Monetary Union, and the adoption thereof would pro- bably lead to the disintegration of the area. It is not appropriate to use the example of the United States, as the Federal Reserve System operates within a fully integrated banking and capital market. 155
  • 154. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity In summary, the accumulation of intra-system balances is the normal result of an asymmetrical crisis in the balance of payments within the area. As is pointed out by Pisany-Ferry (2012), the evo- lution of the intra-system balances is only a symptom of the dise- ase afflicting the Monetary Union: the best expression of the frag- mentation of the monetary policy. As we discussed earlier, access to Eurosystem funding has acted as a security valve to prevent a generalised problem of illiquidity eventually leading to situations of default. However, to date, this insurance mechanism has proven incapable of correcting coordi- nation failure. And on many occasions, the appeal of a country’s banking system to the Eurosystem has been interpreted by the market as a risk factor, so that it has become an additional compo- nent of the self-fulfilling prophecy process. The greater the increase in funding via monetary policy, the greater the restriction on funding from the market. Bear in mind the aberrant nature of this sequen- ce and its lack of sense in an environment other than that of the Monetary Union. During the shutdown of the wholesale financial markets at the end of 2008 and beginning of 2009 nobody thought to judge that a greater appeal to the credit of the Fed or of the Bank of England was an act of weakness.8 8 Among other reasons because the names of the institutions that most used these faci- lities were not known, and because the geographical distribution of the use (in the case of the districts of the Federal Reserve system) was not significant 156
  • 155. The Future of the Euro During spring of 2011, it seemed that the combination of the SMP, the maintenance of the full allocation in monetary policy operations and start of financial aid programmes in the cases dee- med to be more vulnerable (Ireland in November 2010 and Portugal in May 2011) allowed the Eurosystem to take on a less lea- ding role in the crisis resolution. The position of the ECB, as explained by Trichet (2011), was based on the diagnosis that this was not a crisis of the euro, but rat- her a problem of poor macro-economic management, linked to an insufficient budgetary discipline and the persistence of real and financial imbalance. The solution could only come about from a combination of fiscal adjustment and structural reforms at a natio- nal level, and the strengthening of the institutional framework of the Monetary Union. Much emphasis was placed on the impor- tance of the full activation of the EFSF and the future European Stability Mechanism (ESM). As for monetary policy, this supported the principle of separation between the setting of the interest refe- rence rate and the maintenance of unconventional measures to deal with the distortions in the financial markets and the trans- mission mechanisms. As an unequivocal example of application of this principle, the Governing Council decided to raise interest rates on two occasions in response to the inflationist risk associated with the rising price of fuel and raw materials. But the deterioration of the crisis since the end of June 2011 once again placed the ECB at a crossroads. The dislocation of the 157
  • 156. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity Italian public debt market, the second largest in the euro region, triggered a new and virulent bifurcation dynamics which severely punished the banking system. Although the negative balance of its international investment position is moderate, Italy underwent a sudden restriction of external funding which led to the liquidity crisis of its banking system. The value of traded stocks of the banks in the region plummeted and the perception of default risk, reflec- ted in the credit derivative contract premiums, shot up. During those weeks of August and September, the euro crisis reached its most dangerous systemic repercussions since its onset. The Eurosystem was forced once again to react in order to con- tain the spiralling instability which threatened to spread the rest of the world. It reactivated and expanded the SMP, by purchasing Italian and Spanish public debt for the first time. The bloodbath was successfully avoided, but throughout the month of October, in the debates held prior to the European Council and G20 meetings, the need for the ECB to adopt a firmer and more efficient strategy to solve the crisis was the main topic. And the Eurosystem finally took a new step. 3.2. Quantitative easing for banks only The central banks of the main developed economies have had to revolutionise the implementation of monetary policy in order to respond to the financial crisis. At a first phase, they modified the conditions of liquidity provision, both in regard to terms and types 158
  • 157. The Future of the Euro of counterparties and guarantees, maintaining a relatively stable balance. When the crisis became systemic in autumn 2008, it beca- me clear that the cut in the interest reference rate to its minimum level (zero or close to zero) would not prove enough to halt the spi- ralling contraction between the financial conditions and the real economy. Henceforward, the monetary policy of the Fed, the Bank of England and the ECB was implemented mainly through unconven- tional measures, which was the start of the stage in which we remain to date. Despite the sudden departure from the practice of the last two decades, this was not a totally untraveled path. The Bank of Japan had spent years trying unconventional measures in an attempt to overcome the persistent deflation generated by the financial crisis at the end of the eighties. And the Japanese experience, not very suc- cessful, brought about a debate on how to implement an efficient monetary policy in a context of a liquidity trap, distortions in the transmission mechanism and a banking crisis. The Fed paid special attention to the problems of Japan and the conclusion of its analyses served as the basis for the deflation pre- vention policy of 2002 and 2003. Bernanke & Reinhart (2004) iden- tify three categories of these measures: i) the use of communication to influence agent expectations ii) quantitative easing via the incre- ase in the size of the balance sheet and iii) the alteration of the com- position of the balance sheet in order to directly affect the prices of certain financial assets. Each of the aforementioned central banks 159
  • 158. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity has applied the unconventional approach in its own way, but all have coincided in having significantly expanded the balance sheet. Both the Fed and the Bank of England have carried out a three- fold increase of the weight of their balance sheet in regard to the GDP (see Graph 5). And both have done so by the mass acquisition of financial assets, which traditionally made up the main compo- nent of the assets in their balance sheets. The US monetary autho- rity began by concentrating its purchases on mortgage bonds, having subsequently moved on to Treasury bonds. The Bank of England has mainly purchased significant volumes of short and medium term public debt securities (around 14% of GDP and 30% of the amount of securities in circulation). The objective in both cases has been to have a direct influence on the nominal expendi- ture in order to reduce the risk of deflation and help the economy to reabsorb idle resources. Although it is too early to carry out a full evaluation, the evi- dence suggests that the unconventional strategies of the Fed and the Bank of England have proven successful. Estimates indicate a significant positive effect on asset prices, both of those assets which have been directly purchased and those with higher risk and greater impact on the funding terms of the non-financial private sector (See Meaning & Zhu (2011)). The evolution of the nominal demand has also been positive, although in this case it is harder to estimate the impact of unconventional measures. We must also highlight the credibility of the strategy and its contribution to the 160
  • 159. The Future of the Euro reduction of uncertainty, given that the forceful and voluminous interventions and the communication thereof have managed to modify agent expectation and to coordinate these towards balan- ces equilibria which are at some distance from more catastrophic scenarios. It has not been a magical solution for all problems, but they have managed to stabilize the operation of the financial sys- tem, to lend strength to the recovery of the economy and to crea- te conditions so that the correction of the structural problems of public and private indebtedness is carried out at a moderate cost. From the start, the Eurosystem elected to concentrate its uncon- ventional measures on the provision of funding to the banking sys- tem, in line with the financial structure of the area, particularly in terms of full allotprent and the performance of unusually long term operations. The purchase of assets has been more modest in relative terms and has now become sterilised. In December 2011 this stra- tegy was reaffirmed, by deciding to enter into two special financing operations for a three-year term, along with other credit support measures designed to favour bank lending and the money markets in the region. The demand for liquidity of both operations was very high, with a very high participation of entities compared to the average num- ber of previous long term financing operations. The total amount granted was 1.018 trillion euros. The distribution of liquidity follo- wed a concentrated geographical pattern reflecting the effect of funding restrictions on the banking system. The percentages of 161
  • 160. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity Graph 5 Balance fo the Central Banks during the crisis (in % of the GDP) Source: ECB, BoE, FED Spanish and Italian banks were much higher than their respective allocations in the ECB, whereas the banks from creditor countries were granted much lower percentages, and further increased their resources in the Deposit Facility. Following these two operations, the consolidated balance sheet of the Eurosystem reached 32% of the GDP for the region, excee- ding the percentages of the Fed and Bank of England. However, the impact of the unconventional strategy in the balance sheet of the central banks has been somewhat lower in the ECB that in the other two, due to the increase in total weight over the GDP, as well as having only used assets related to monetary policy, which account for a lesser percentage of the balance sheet in the European case. 162
  • 161. The Future of the Euro The immediate impact of the three year funding operations was very positive. The coverage for a three year period of the liquidity requirements of the banks considerably reduced the uncertainty which had frozen the workings of the banking system. The percep- tion of bank credit risk improved with significant drops in the pre- miums of credit derivatives and increases in the value of capital. The money markets and bank debt markets underwent a revitalisa- tion, with new flows of funds and the return of European and foreign institutional investors. At the same time, the public debt market spreads also experienced a significant narrowing down, returning in the case of the Spain and Italy to around 300 basis points. The disabling of the loop-shaped coordination failure bet- ween sovereign debt and bank risk also had some effect on the monetary and credit performance, as well as on the real economy. Towards the end of the first quarter, both the European Commission and the ECB stated that the M3 and private sector loans exhibited positive – albeit very low – expansion rates, where- as activity stabilised after the drop in the last quarter and first months of 2012. Beyond its short term efficacy as an insurance mechanism in the face of the systemic deterioration of the crisis, the full effect of the quantitative easing for banks only in the Eurosystem will only be assessable over time. Nevertheless, the strategy adopted has some weak points, among which we highlight the following: • It emphasises the Eurosystem’s tendency towards geographi- cal concentration of net funding. The net amount and the dis- 163
  • 162. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity persal of the net lending volumes by country and of intra-sys- tem balances have increased substantially. The Eurosystem has thus decided to carry on its clearing role for private funds move- ments, directly avoiding having to deal with the underlying causes of such movements in order to modify them. The side- effect is the increase in the risk volume of the Eurosystem and in its geographical concentration, assumed by member coun- tries in proportion to their share of the capital. • It fails to put an end to the fragility of the public debt markets in the face of dislocation, and might even increase it. According to BIS figures, Spanish Banks have increased their public debt holdings by over 40,000 million between December 2011 and January 2012, whereas the Italians did so at around 15,000 million euros. This evolution, which is due to the entities taking advantage of the possibility of generating margin by borro- wing from the Eurosystem and buying public debt, might end up being counter-productive for two reasons. In first place, because these are not resources geared towards credit for the non-financial private sector (which is the main objective behind it). And secondly, because it might even intensify the means of contagion towards the banking system if the public debt spreads widen once again. A demand has therefore been generated for the more casti- gated public debt securities, but nothing can guarantee that the market evolution will not suffer further dislocation episodes which will increase volatility once again and widen the gap bet- ween market prices and prices based on fundamental variables. • The SMP might be relegated an amortised instrument. It 164
  • 163. The Future of the Euro seems logical that the Programme activity was interrupted almost at the time when the positive impact of long term fun- ding operations became evident. The problem is that, within the Governing Council, the opposition to the reactivation of the SMP is likely to increase in the event of a new dislocation of the markets, arguing that both the levels of risk in the balance sheet and degree of geographical concentration are way too high. This eventually would be cause for grave concern, given that the SMP was the instrument which had succeeded in preventing a syste- mic collapse of the euro region both in May 2010 and in August- September 2011. There is an alternative, which the Eurosystem has ruled out, which might prove more effective as a contribution towards a defi- nitive solution to the crisis. It would involve directly tackling the source of the problem, which is the instability that the dislocation of some public debt markets have brought upon the core of the economy’s funding system. The aim would be to ensure that a limit is established on the deviation between the market prices and pri- ces adjusted to fundamental economic variables which must not be exceeded. Although there are various ways of implementing this type of measure, they all involve direct intervention in the market in a plausible way. Only the central bank, with its power to create unlimited money, will be able to successfully carry out such a task. A reasonable option would be to publicly commit to ensuring that the spread between short term sovereign debt in euro countries 165
  • 164. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity does not surpass a certain value threshold. Given the arbitrage rela- tionship between the various terms of a country’s public debt yield curve, the application of this stability limit on the shorter part of the curve (bills and bonds up to 2 years) would suffice, for this then to be applied to longer terms. In fact, the epicentre of the dislocation episodes in the public debt markets can be found in the shorter part of the curve, where volatility increases and exorbitant probabilities of default emerge, which in turn adversely affect the repo market, which is crucial for short term financing of the banking system. The stability limits should be defined for each country on the basis of its vulnerability and adapted as the case may be to take into account potential default in commitments of fiscal consolidation and structural reform. By way of illustration, for Spain and Italy the stability limits might be around 200 basis points: this level would be clearly above what can be considered a fair value spread. But what is important is not to compress the spreads as much to ensu- re the stability thereof to enable the transmission mechanism of the monetary policy to operate under relative normality. The Eurosystem should purchase public debt when the price rea- ches the stability limit. But if this proposal is viable, the volume of debt eventually purchased by the Eurosystem is likely to be more limi- ted than that already in place in the SMP. Moreover, the volume of purchase of public debt could be sterilised, as is already done now. The problem is less about amount of money, and more about price struc- ture and risk, as well as market operation. 166
  • 165. The Future of the Euro This type of initiative would enable to transform the perverse dynamics of debt into a virtuous circle. The recovery of monetary and financial stability in the more adversely affected countries would establish the conditions for fiscal consolidation and structu- ral reform measures to have the positive impact that they should have had on the confidence of agents and markets. It is not about the Eurosystem taking on a new role as lender of last resort to the States, which would be entirely inappropriate.9 The idea would be to preserve the good operation of the debt mar- kets as a key component in the transmission mechanism of mone- tary policy and funding of the economy. We are speaking of a public good of great economic value, the protection of which is an essential (albeit not explicit) task of any central bank. But as we recalled earlier, the Eurosystem is not a central bank like the rest. The rejection by the Governing Council of a plausible intervention in the public debt markets designed to limit the instability seems to be related to a number of economic and legal objections. It is argued that this type of action does not pertain to a central bank and that it carries inflationist risks in that it would be assuming a quasi-fiscal role, attempting to solve problems of lack of budgetary discipline and/or 9 De Grauwe (2011), after performing a thorough analysis of the crisis, uses the notion of lender of last resort for sovereign debt markets. Subsequently, this idea has been used by others to assimilate a plausible intervention in the debt markets with State funding via the central bank. 167
  • 166. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity competitiveness by means of creating money. It is also argued that it may violate section 123 of the Treaty, or at least the spirit thereof. Despite having the seal of respectability granted by the Bundesbank, such arguments are questionable. It is true that the Eurosystem should not intervene in public debt markets if the widening of the spreads is due to irresponsible fiscal policies or an impairment of fundamental variables (a drop in the GDP, an incre- ase in the external deficit). For this reason it is highly probable that a mistake was made when in May 2010 the Eurosystem purchased Greek public debt. But when the market dislocation begins via con- tagion and, furthermore, is endogenous and subject to feedback, if the central bank does not act, it is opening the door to monetary restriction which would endanger price stability not only of the country but of all the region. As for inflation, this type of uncon- ventional measure would carry lesser inflationist risk than the other two long term funding operations unanimously approved by the Governing Council. The argument to intervene becomes even stronger when the affected countries have reacted to contagion by accelerating their fiscal adjustment plans and implementing signi- ficant structural reforms. On the other hand, a more plausible and decisive intervention in debt markets would not only not violate what is set forth in sec- tion 123, but would in fact be fully coherent with the spirit there- of. The text of the section refers to the direct purchase of public debt securities in the primary market, excluding from the ban the 168
  • 167. The Future of the Euro purchase of bonds on the secondary market. The ban on monetary funding seeks to ensure the independence of monetary policy in regard to the needs imposed by the fiscal policy. The public indeb- tedness requirements (arising from treasury deficits, net asset varia- tion and the refinancing of debt maturities) must be covered by appealing to the market, without resorting to the expansion of the monetary base, which ends up generating an inflationist bias. However, compliance with this healthy principle requires the exis- tence and proper operation of a liquid and deep public debt mar- ket. A lack of action in the face of the dislocation of public debt markets means accepting the gradual destruction of one of the basic foundation stones of the separation between fiscal policy and monetary policy.10 In our opinion, the reason why the Eurosystem has not chosen this solution, more in line with the practice of other comparable central banks, is not economic but political. This is difficult to belie- ve, in that it is a fiercely independent institution managed by qua- lified professionals. But as was pointed out in the first sentence, the Monetary Union is a political construction; and the euro crisis carries, as is natural, a very influential political dimension. The governments and central bank authorities of Germany and all other 10 Within the monetary union, the loss of access to the market as a result of contagion does not mean resorting to monetary funding of public debt, but the use of official fun- ding on a temporary basis. However, this situation quickly leads to some to request to exit the euro and the recovery of monetary sovereignty as a means of escaping the per- verse dynamics of debt. 169
  • 168. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity countries benefiting from the positive contagion of the Greek crisis, have viewed the crisis as a vindication of their economic philosop- hies and an opportunity to reconsolidate the Monetary Union in accordance with their principles. And as part of this process, they understand that market pressure is an efficient discipline that must not be neutralised. In their opinion, the markets may exaggerate, but in the end they reflect the fundamental economic problems. In summary, the Eurosystem has proven to be essential in con- taining the crisis at the times of greater systemic danger, but it has not done what any national central bank would have done to tac- kle the perverse dynamics of debt which threaten the survival of the euro. In a way, it cannot be blamed. It has acted in accordance with its nature. 4. The definitive solution must begin in 2012 After the bad omens with which 2011 came to an end, the first few months of 2012 have seen the danger of a systemic collapse of the euro fade into the distance, and it even seems that certain sig- nificant steps have been taken towards a definitive solution to the crisis. The insurance provided by the Eurosystem has brought about time and tranquillity. But the situation is still critical, if we look beyond the financial tension gauges and we measure the situation of the real economy 170
  • 169. The Future of the Euro and political cohesion within the area. The deterioration of the cri- sis in the second half of 2011 has come at a very high cost in terms of a fall into recession for Spain and Italy and other member coun- tries, as well as the worsening outlook for countries with a pro- gramme. To the rise in unemployment we must add new fiscal adjustment measures, required to meet the targets in a context of lesser growth of tax bases and higher cyclical expenditure. At the same time, the detachment towards the Monetary Union is on the increase, both in countries punished by financial pressure as well as in creditor countries. Given such conditions, the definitive solution to the crisis, this being understood as the one allowing recovery of sustained growth throughout the region and a reduction and stabilisation of the credit risk spreads, cannot take as long as the refund of the money by the banks to the ECB. It is urgent and the effect of Eurosystem long term funding operations should be harnessed in order to implement it. In our opinion, the definitive solution is made up of 4 compo- nents. Two of them are already well on track. The third is the key: the one requiring greater effort due to its political and technical complexity. And the last is fundamental to prevent future crises and to encourage the stable operation of the Monetary Union; but this can be taken more slowly, as it is not a pressing need and will even- tually happen when the time is right. 171
  • 170. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity A SUITABLE HANDLING OF THE INSOLVENCY PROBLEM IN GREECE. Immediately after the approval by the States in the euro region of the Loan to Greece which gave rise to the first adjust- ment programme carried out jointly with the IMF in April 2010, the prevailing opinion in the financial markets was that Greece had a solvency problem which required debt restructuring. However, among the European authorities, including the ECB, the overriding idea was that any measure generating losses for inves- tors had to be avoided at all costs. It was believed that this appro- ach might exacerbate contagion to other public debt markets. But the delay in recognising this problem undoubtedly was very onerous. In the Deauville Declaration of October 2010, the leaders of France and Germany, guided by the healthy aim of involving private investors in the assumption of losses as a result of their decisions, extended the potential risk beyond Greece, moreover projecting it to the future. And in spring 2011, it became clear that the first Greek programme was not in line with the assumption of return to the market expected for 2012.11 Finally, the Heads of State and Government of the Eurozone countries decided in October 2011 that the restructuring of Greek debt had to allow suf- ficient reduction of its stock and that this solution was meant exclusively for the exceptional case of Greece. 11 The alarm bell was sounded by the IMF, given that the approval of program disbur- sements requires a reasonable guarantee that the financing needs of the country are 172
  • 171. The Future of the Euro A year and a half after the outbreak of the crisis, one of the most decisive conclusions was thus reached: the problem of Greece is special and requires special handling. And a series of questionable decisions that had amalgamated, consciously or unconsciously, the Greek situation with that of other vulnerable countries in the region, was thus left behind. Greece has continued to be a source of uncertainty which has affected the crisis dynamics. Its economic depression (a 13% drop in real GDP between 2009 and 2011, a 30% drop in deposits in the banking system during the same period) and the proof of its insti- tutional frailty have led to a situation of clear unsustainability of its public debt,12 calling into question the viability of its perma- nence in the euro. And the risk of Greece’s departure is a very dis- turbing scenario, as this is not contemplated in the Treaties and it is difficult to imagine the consequences it may lead to. The Private Sector Involvement (PSI) Operation in the reduction of debt, a prior condition for the approval of the second program- me by the Eurogroup and the IMF, was quite successfully executed throughout the month of March. The operation is a sophisticated met for the following year; and given the market situation, the IMF considered that Greece could not be expected to return to the market in 2012 as expected. 12 The deterioration of the sustainability analyses of the Troika since the start of the programme has been overwhelming. At the start of the program the public debt vs. GDP was expected to reach its peak in 2012 with 158% of GDP and no reduction. In autumn 2011, this peak was changed to 186%; finally, the sustainability analysis carried out after the PSI operation suggests a peak of 164% of the GDP. 173
  • 172. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity and European version of the Brady Plan,13 which has used bonds issued by the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) to soften the drop in present value of over 50% in exchange for new ultra long term bonds. The credible threat of a disordered bankruptcy and the retroactive introduction of Collective Action Clauses in the issues subject to Greek legislation managed to achieve a per- centage participation in the exchange above 95%. The operation has succeeded in reducing the debt load and Greek state’s refinan- cing needs very substantially. From a liquidity approach and at punitive rates at the start of 2010, reality has taken over through an operation in which priva- te investors rightly take on a part of the cost of bankruptcy pre- vention14 and Eurozone countries assume greater risks, for longer periods and in exchange for lower interest rates. Despite the magnitude of the debt reduction (100,000 million euros, which would allow it to reach a ratio over GDP of 116.5% in 2020, according to the sustainability analysis of the Troika), the 13 Name of the Plan used at the end of the 1980s to solve the foreign debt crisis of deve- loping countries, mainly Latin American. It consisted in exchanging outstanding bonds for new bonds with a lower present value and longer terms, guaranteed by US Treasury issued securities. 14 The policy of loss avoidance for investors led to a perverse dynamics whereby priva- te investors reduced their exposure, in many cases with substantial gains, thanks to the ever increasing involvement of official creditors. Taken to the extreme, this logic would have led to a process whereby private investors would not suffer any losses whereas the official lenders were left funding the entire Greek debt. 174
  • 173. The Future of the Euro prevailing opinion seems to emphasise the main risks facing the second Greek programme.15 After the last two years, any glimpse of a positive assessment in regard to what is going on in Greece seems completely off the wall. It is true that the sharp drop in the GDP, the fiscal adjustment and the reforms carried out have not achieved sufficient reduction in the primary budgetary balance or in the current deficit (which is still around 10% of GDP). However, in our opinion, the PSI operation and the approval of the new pro- gramme, which supports devaluation via the reduction of labour costs, the gradual continuation of the fiscal adjustment and the 50,000 million euros to ensure the solvency of the banking system, will be able to restore certain stability to the Greek economy. Taking into account the reduction in uncertainty, the moderate deflation of costs and the effort invested in structural reforms, there is a very clear potential for economic recovery. This stabiliza- tion would exert a positive impact on expectations, leading in turn to a virtuous circle. All this depends on the country being able to maintain a stable political leadership which is committed to com- pliance with the second programme. In any event, the value of the PSI operation and the second pro- gramme for the definitive solution of the euro crisis arises from the reduction in uncertainty. Despite the need to continue to adopt policies which require sacrifices on the part of the citizenship for 15 See for instance the IMF report on the request for a new program, which emphasizes the risk of new accidents and the importance of Euro members undertaking to continue to finance Greece in concessional terms whilst the appropriate policies are implemented. 175
  • 174. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity some time, the reduction of the debt and the funding of the long term needs of the State render the option of staying in the euro much more attractive than the option of departure (although the latter will continue to have its supporters both in and outside of Greece). A FISCAL PACT TO STRENGTHEN POLITICAL CONFIDENCE. The Greek experience clearly justifies a reinforcement of the fiscal regulations of the euro, so that these are more efficient during the expansive stages of the cycle, therefore obliging member states to internalise the external cost of unbalanced public finances. The European Union already approved in 2011 a substantial toughening of the Stability Pact and Growth, as part of the reform of the macro-economic governance known as Six Pack, which also broadens the multilateral supervision of macro-economic imbalan- ces of a non-fiscal nature. The preventive section includes the quan- titative definition of what is understood to be a substantial deviation from the Medium Term Objective of structural budgetary balance or from the path established to achieve it. The corrective section brings about the Excessive Deficit Procedure due to the non-fulfilment of the public debt criterion and introduces the reverse qualified majo- rity rule for decision-making, which will make it harder for member states to put a stop to a Commission proposal. Minimum require- ments are also established for the budgetary frameworks of the coun- tries, in terms of coverage of all administrations, multiannual natu- re and quality of the public accounting systems. 176
  • 175. The Future of the Euro This exhaustive reform of the fiscal rules culminated with the signature on 2 March 2012 of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance. This new Treaty: • Has been signed by 25 of the 27 EU member countries, alt- hough it will only be legally binding for euro members. • It shall come into force on 1 January 2013, provided it has been ratified by 12 euro member states, thus avoiding the uncer- tainty associated with the ratification process of a modification of EU Treaties. Even so, its content is expected to be added to community legislation within five years. • It introduces the rule of budget balancing. This will be unders- tood to be met when the structural deficit reaches its Medium Term Objective (MTO) with a maximum deficit of 0.5% (which can reach 1% if the debt is significantly below 60% and the sus- tainability risks are low). • Any significant deviation from MTO or from the path of adjust- ment towards the MTO that is observed will trigger an automa- tic correction mechanism, defined in the national legislation but inspired by the principles established by the Commission. The foregoing shall be of application unless in the event of exceptional circumstances.16 • Both the rule and the correction mechanism must be added to the national legislative systems, preferably at a constitutional level, within the year subsequent to the entry in force of the 16 This refers to i) An unusual event outside of the control of the country which has a large impact on the financial position of the public administrations or to ii) periods of 177
  • 176. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity Treaty. And the transposition shall be subject to verification by the EU Court of Justice, which shall be empowered to take dis- ciplinary action in the event of infringement. • The euro countries undertake to support Commission propo- sals within the framework of the excessive deficit procedure concerning any of them, except in the event of a qualified majority thereof against it. The new Treaty is consistent with the system of fiscal regula- tions established in the revised SGP and actually uses its basic com- ponents (the MTO, the significant deviation and the exceptional circumstances). What it does is to toughen these rules and increa- se the legal rank thereof within the internal legal system. The two most important items are the rule of budget balance and the auto- matic correction mechanism. In technical terms, the new framework of fiscal rules for the euro is reasonable from a medium to long term perspective, inso- far as: • It reinforces the discipline mechanism during the expansive phases of the cycle, which will oblige budgets to be kept in balance or with surplus. serious economic contraction as this is defined in the revised Stability and Growth Pact and, in both cases, provided the temporary deviation does not endanger medium term fiscal sustainability. 178
  • 177. The Future of the Euro • It increases control at a European level on the quality of the public accounts as a basis for multilateral supervision of the fis- cal policies. • It increases the credibility of the prevention and sanctioning mechanisms, assisting in non-discretional decision-making and toughening sanctions. • It obliges national legal systems to fully incorporate both the fiscal rules and the minimum requirements of quality and coor- dination of budgetary frameworks. In the medium to long term, the application of such rules, assu- ming a trend nominal growth of 3% per annum, would lead to a public debt stock of 17% of GDP (Whelan, 2012). The key for such rules to generate anti-cyclical fiscal policies is that they are able to impose tough discipline during the expansive phases, that the reliability of the fiscal information is assured and that the sanc- tions are applied in rigorous and equitable way for all. The use of a non-observable variable such as the structural balance in order to assess compliance with the deficit rule makes sense, but it complicates the practical application thereof due to uncertainty in regard to the correct estimate of potential GDP. The case of Spain during the phase prior to the crisis is paradigmatic: during the period 2005-2007, the Commission estimated the struc- tural budgetary balance to be very close to the nominal balance, given that the growth estimate for potential GDP was around 3%. The subsequent performance of the economy and of the public 179
  • 178. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity income and expenditure has shown that in the years previous to the crisis, Spain was growing over and above its potential and that the structural balance was much worse than that indicated by the nominal surplus. In reality, the value of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance is above all political, as it helps to bring about once again a new political understanding among the euro member countries. Several countries have interpreted the financial aid as a breach, at least in spirit, of the non-mutual guarantee clause in the Treaty. It was hard for Germany and other countries in the D-mark area to bring their monetary sovereignty in line with that of coun- tries with a lesser tradition of stability. And the non-guarantee clause was one of the essential conditions to do so. Part of the atti- tude of governments and central bank authorities in these coun- tries in the last two years could be explained by this feeling that rules have been broken. The new Treaty, with its reflection in the Constitutions of several countries, is one more step for countries in the north and centre to believe that the countries which are currently more vulnerable are adopting a longstanding commitment to fiscal discipline, beyond the adjustment forced upon them by the markets. And this confi- dence is essential to the creation of political conditions which will enable decisions to be taken with a view to solving the crisis. The Fiscal Pact is therefore a necessary condition, but in no way is it enough to make 2012 the year of the start of the end of the crisis. 180
  • 179. The Future of the Euro The Treaty will strengthen the policy of firm advancement in fis- cal consolidation in the most vulnerable countries, which has been applied for the last two years. But we are already aware that the per- verse dynamics can make a steadfast programme of fiscal adjustment which lacks a complement to help restore growth fail in its objecti- ve of stabilising public debt. Without nominal growth and financial stability, the efforts made in regard to deficit reduction not only fail to reduce the debt/GDP ratio, but actually increase it. THE GRADUAL AND FLEXIBLE CONSTRUCTION OF A SIN- GLE PUBLIC DEBT MARKET. The key to doing away with the per- verse dynamics of debt is to restore the good working order of the public debt markets, so that the spreads are more in line with eco- nomic fundamentals and more stable. This is an essential condition for relaxing financial terms in vulnerable countries and for allowing growth to benefit from the positive effects of the reforms adopted. We have already pointed out that there is no confidence that the Eurosystem will adopt the strategy required to achieve this objecti- ve. A second alternative on the table is the EFSF/ESM. In theory, the EFSF/ESM, with the set of intervention instruments which it currently contains, has the effective capacity to stabilise the public debt markets. However, in our opinion, financial aid is not an effi- cacious solution to the perverse dynamics of debt. Under current conditions, the preventive funding facilities would soon become ordinary adjustment programmes; the result would be the exten- sion of the loss of access to market funding and the escalation of the 181
  • 180. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity political tension arising from the concentration of funding in the area from only a few contributor countries. On the other hand, the design of the secondary market intervention instruments has too many political and operational limitations to even appear plausible. In our opinion, the most suitable way is the creation of a new public debt market with jointly and severally guaranteed securities. This is a very important and delicate political decision, as it involves the pooling together of sovereign risk, which is an essential part of fiscal sovereignty. Countries with higher credit rating have been hit- herto reluctant to share the issue of debt with those of a lower cre- dit quality. This attitude is fair and understandable; to ask Finland, Holland or Germany to pool together all the debt issued with more indebted and vulnerable countries is politically unrealistic. But given the current crossroads of the Monetary Union, this step must be taken, and the way to do it is to design it in such a way that it is politically feasible. This design should abide by the following principles: • The construction of a single public debt market in euros must be done gradually. The first stone must be solid but of a mode- rate size. The next stones shall be placed little by little and on the basis of experience. • At the first stage, the percentage of public debt pooled together must be limited. This requirement should be in line with the doctrine of the German Constitutional Court, which requires bonds issued by the State to have a clear quantitative limit. 182
  • 181. The Future of the Euro • The pooled debt must be senior to the national debt, in order to reduce the risk of the joint and several guarantee. • Incentives restricting moral hazard must be introduced, taking in account the strengthened governance framework of the Monetary Union. In the Eurobond debate, several specific formulae have been considered which are compatible with such principles. The pione- er was the blue bond/red bond proposal (Delpla & Weizsäcker, 2009), which suggested pooling together up to 60% of the public debt over the GDP (blue debt), leaving the rest as subordinate national debt (red debt). The Commission published a Green Paper containing various different options of Stability Bonds which aimed at feeding the debate. Lastly, the proposal of a European Debt Redemption Fund from the Group of German Economic Experts (2011), which advises the Federal Government, is also of great interest, in that it considers the pooling together of the sur- plus of the 60% of debt over GDP in exchange for real guarantees in order to overcome the crisis. 17 In our opinion, the most attractive alternative would be the Eurobills proposal made by Hellwig & Phillippon (2011) which would consist of: • The issue with a joint and several guarantee of all public debt securities with initial maturities of up to 1 year (Eurobills). 17 The formula of the surplus over and above the 60% does not seem fair, as it rewards the more indebted countries. 183
  • 182. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity • The participation of each member country would be limited to 10% of the GDP. The Eurobill market would therefore have a maximum size, based on the GDP for 2011, of 1 billion euros. • The Eurobills would be senior to all other longer term debt, as the short term debt is already de facto senior to medium and long term debt. • The loss of access to the Eurobills could be considered discipli- nary action within the framework of multilateral supervision of fiscal policies and macro-economic imbalances. The Eurobills are a simple formula with many advantages: • Efficacy. As we have already mentioned, the core of the dislo- cation in economy funding mechanisms lies with the shorter part of the debt markets and its connection to the money mar- kets. The Eurobills would manage to directly tackle the failure and the effect would be foreseeably transmitted throughout the yield curve. They would thus represent an alternative to stability limits. • Political feasibility. The high level of political and legal com- mitment to fiscal stability brought by the new Treaty should allow for the more solvent countries to accept the Eurobills. Given their term, the risk is limited; and in terms of cost if issue, the loss would be small or non-existent.18 • Operating facility. The EFSF/ESM already issues bills, so it could easily assumed the issue of Eurobills. A system would have to 18 The bills issued by the EFSF with proportional guarantees from euro member coun- tries have a small spread compared to German bills. Taking as a reference the issue of 184
  • 183. The Future of the Euro be established to consolidate the treasury needs for each State, as Bills play a certain role as treasury management instruments. • Additional benefits. Eurobills could be used to meet Basel III liquidity requirements and would attract a strong demand from institutional investors in and outside of the region. The construction of a single public debt market in euros will be a long and complicated process, likely to take decades. It is a basic ingredient in the path of the euro towards institutional maturity, which shall have to develop alongside advancements made in fis- cal integration. But it must commence now, as it is the key to over- come the crisis once and for all. THE FEDERALISATION OF BANKING SUPERVISION IN THE EUROSYSTEM AND THE CREATION OF A EUROPEAN DEPOSIT GUARANTEE FUND. In hindsight, one of the most serious flaws of the institutional framework of the first decade of the euro has to do with banking supervision and crisis management. In order to reach a definitive solution, this flaw must be corrected. Despite having harmonised prudential legislation from the start, the euro region has worked with banking systems which have continued to be governed by an essentially national approach. On March 6 month bills, the spread compared to the German bills is lower than 20 basis points. The cost of issue of the Eurobills would naturally be lower than that of the EFSF bills, thanks to the joint and several guarantees, closer to the levels at which bills are currently issued by Germany and by other countries with a higher credit rating. 185
  • 184. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity the other hand, despite the efforts begun following the Brouwer Report (2001) to build a crisis management plan within the EU, when the crisis was broke out weak in deposit guarantee and prac- tically non-existent in the intervention and liquidation of credit institutions. One of the most illustrative indicators of this persistence of the national approach in the realm of banking is that the integration has advanced more between euro countries and non-euro coun- tries than within the euro region itself. Among the problems asso- ciated with this situation, we shall highlight two: The absence of global overview of the funding structure of the area and its relation with monetary policy. The creation of the euro led to a strong expansion of gross and net flows within the area. In a way, this was the reallocation of capital towards those countries where it was scarce and could obtain better returns. But in some countries this process ended up by creating bubbles in the real estate sector, which reached hitherto unknown peaks partly due to belonging to the Monetary Union (low interest rates, very elastic supply of external funds). In light of the high short term economic benefits in terms of extraction of income, employment, fiscal activity and collection, the economic policy renders very dif- ficult, as we have seen, the adoption of domestic measures to burst the bubble. At the same time, given that monetary policy is exo- genous to the authorities of a country, the effect thereof is not internalised in regard to the creating or blowing up a bubble furt- her. But it is not only about bubbles. The global crisis showed up 186
  • 185. The Future of the Euro other weaknesses in the funding structure of the banks in the euro region, such as its dependence on the liquidity of the US money markets. The possibility that a banking crisis might bring down a country. National supervision goes hand in hand with the natio- nal responsibility for covering costs in the event of a crisis. As we have seen in Ireland, the bank solvency problems can overwhelm the fiscal capacity of the country. Moreover, and continuing with the Irish example, the potential effects of contagion within the Monetary Union limit the capacity of the affected country to solve the crisis by the assumption of losses by private creditors. Since the start of the crisis, considerable progress has been made in terms of coordination of bank supervision and crisis manage- ment in Europe. Nevertheless, the maturity of the Monetary Union still has a way to go. The essential public policies on the banking system must be common within the euro area, in accordance with a plan with two main cornerstones: • Federal banking supervision within the Eurosystem. The time has come to make use of a provision of the Treaty on the fede- ralization of banking supervision within the euro area. Given that only in 5 euro countries the banking supervisor is separate from the central bank, and that the ECB is the most powerful euro institution, the most natural approach to achieve this is by awarding competencies to the Eurosystem. And the competen- cies assumed must include micro-prudential regulation, macro- 187
  • 186. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity prudential regulation and part of the crisis prevention and management function. • A European Deposit Guarantee Fund (EDGF). The crisis has proven that the deposit guarantee systems are basic instruments in the prevention and management of banking crises. During the global crisis, the risk of having systems with insufficient coverage (eg. Northern Rock) or the chaos generated by unilate- ral decisions on levels of coverage within the euro (movements of deposits between countries at the end of 2008) became patently clear. With the generalized increase in coverage of deposits up to 100,000 euros (which increases the cost of the liquidation of the institutions), the guarantee funds, in princi- ple, assume a crucial responsibility. However, the models of deposit guarantee systems within the area as still quite different from one another. For this reason an obligatory adhesion fund should be created to assume the guarantee of all deposits in the banks of the euro area and their branches in the EU. The fund should be made up of the contributions from entities, determi- ned on the basis of credit and liquidity risk and have a system of governance similar to that of the Spanish guarantee funds, presided over by the ECB and with broad representation of the private sector in its Board of Governance. The functions of this EDGF should include the resolution of banking crises, assisting the mandate of the Eurosystem in early intervention and crisis resolution at the lowest cost for the public treasury. As an addi- tional and exceptional mechanism of funding, a system could be established whereby the ESM could lend funds to the EDGF. 188
  • 187. The Future of the Euro The improvement in the operation of the Monetary Union as a result of the federalisation of banking supervision and crisis mana- gement would be considerable in the medium and long term. The following are among the possible positive changes associated with this reform: • The monetary transmission mechanism would become more robust against national fiscal evolutions and the fluctuations of the financial markets. • A boost to cross-border integration and consolidation. The pro- tection of domestic industry would become more difficult, which would lead to benefits of risk diversification and econo- mies of scale. And competition would gradually become more intense, which is essential after the re-nationalisation of the banking markets and the strong public support provided to cri- sis- affected entities. • Support for incentives to implement measures to prevent the creation of speculative bubbles. • The internalisation of external effects and public service provi- sion problems associated with financial stability within the area. This would allow for the creation of a structure where the central bank and the Ministries (Eurogroup) work much more efficiently towards preserving financial stability. • It would support the introduction of measures to achieve grea- ter involvement of the private sector in the solution of future crises. 189
  • 188. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity 5. Conclusion The adolescent crisis of the euro is extremely serious. European and national authorities have taken courageous and significant decisions in recent months, in many cases having learned from previous mistakes. The restructuring of the debt and the new adjustment programme are an intelligent and well executed res- ponse to the serious solvency problem in Greece. Ireland and Portugal are applying their programmes with excellent assessments made by the troika. And an institutional framework is under way, which will render the generation of a crisis in the future a lot less likely. Much political and social capital has been spent on implemen- ting such measures. It is clear that the euro member countries are willing to make great sacrifices in order to preserve the project. But the truth is that the crisis has not yet been overcome, because the root causes of the uncertainty and the instability generated by the dislocation of the public debt markets have not been attacked. The economy within the euro area will foreseeably face a second recession three years after the sharp blow of 2009. Ireland and Portugal are watching their expectations of recovery fade as a result of lower foreign demand and maintenance of financial pres- sure. And there are questions as to the likelihood of its return to the markets within the timeframes set and even in regard to the Greece and no more commitment. Spain and Italy are implementing 190
  • 189. The Future of the Euro strong fiscal adjustments and deep structural reforms in an envi- ronment of recession and financial vulnerability. The euro cannot afford to undergo another episode like the one in August-September 2011. It is imperative that a measure is taken to protect us against that risk and removes, once and for all, the devastating coordination failure of the global crisis of 2009. Having assumed that the stabilisation of the debt markets cannot be pro- vided by the central bank as in other countries, we have to choose a new market. Eurobills are an efficient and balanced solution; 2012 should be their birth year. They will help reunify monetary policy, by first restoring stability and establishing the foundations for a solid economic recovery. These conditions are essential for the programmes to work, for the debt to stabilize and for the consoli- dation and reform policies to be effective and have continuity. There is no future without stability and growth. It is not necessary to search for great constructions or to come up with solutions for all the problems. The Eurozone shall never be an optimal monetary region. It does not need to be. For the time being, we must concentrate on a series of efficient and plausible fis- cal regulations, a single monetary policy based on debt markets which are operating fairly and a stable banking system capable of funding the economy. And to continue to learn and build an incre- asingly closer union. The countries that are currently suffering will learn from their mistake; one cannot prosper within the euro with the same institutional framework that one had out of the euro: 191
  • 190. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity foreign finances continue to be a restriction, the real exchange rate and the flexibility in real salaries and mark-ups are important, cre- dit excesses cost dearly… but we must allow some time for the les- sons learned to be put into practice and produce good results. 192
  • 191. The Future of the Euro Bibliography - Aizenman, J., Hutchison, M. and Jinjarak, Y. (2011) “What is the risk of European sovereign debt defaults? Fiscal Space, CDS Spreads and Market pricing of Risk”. NBER Working Paper 17407. - Barrios, S., Iversen, P., Lewandowska, M. and Setzer, R. (2009) “Determinants of intra-euro area government bond spreads during the financial crisis” Economic Papers 388. European Commission. - Bernanke, B. and Reinhart, V. (2004) “Conducting Monetary Policy at Very Low Short-Term Interest Rates” American Economic Review, 94(2): 85-90. - Bernanke, B., Reinhart, V. and Sack, B. (2004) “Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical Assessment” Staff Paper. US Federal Reserve - Bindseil, U. and König, J. (2011) “The Economics of TARGET2 balan- ces” SFB 649 Discussion Paper, Universidad Humboldt de Berlín. - Bornhorst, F. and Mody, A. (2012) “TARGET imbalances: Financing the capital-account reversal in Europe” VoxEU.org, 7 March. - Caballero, R. (2010) “Sudden Financial Arrest” Mundell-Fleming Lecture prepared for the IMF 10th Jacques Polack Annual Research Conference. IMF Economic Review, July 20, 2010. 193
  • 192. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity - CESifo (2011) “The Bobenberg Declaration: 16 theses on the situation of European Monetary Union”. December 2011. - Cooper, R and John, A. (1991) “Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models” in Mankiw, G. and Romer, D. eds “New Keynesian Economics” The MIT Press. - Delpla, J. and Weizsacker, J. (2010), “The Blue Bond Proposal”, Bruegel Policy Brief 420. - De Grauwe, P. and Ji. Y. (2012) “Mispricing of Sovereign Risk and Multiple Equilibria in the Eurozone”. Working Paper, mimeo www.econ.kuleuven.be/ew/academic/intecon/Degrauwe/ - Dombret, A. (2012) “New year, old problems – Europe’s sovereign debt crisis”, Speech of a member of the Executive Board of the Deutsche Bundesbank to the International Bankers’ Club in Luxembourg, 6 February 2012. - Economic and Financial Committee (2001) “Report on Financial Crisis Management/Brouwer Report” Council of the European Union. - EU Commission (2011), “Green Paper: Feasibility of Stability Bonds”, November. - German Council of Economic Experts (2011) “Assume Responsibility for Europe” First Chapter of the 2011/2012 Report. 194
  • 193. The Future of the Euro - Hellwig, T. and Philippon, T. (2011) “Eurobills, not Eurobonds”, VoxEU.org, 2 December 2011. - Jobst, C. (2011) “A balance sheet view on TARGET-and why restric- tions on TARGET would have hit Germany first” Vox 19 July 2011. - Joyce, M., Tong, M. and Woods, R. (2011) "The United Kingdom’s quantitative easing policy: design, operation and impact” Quarterly Bulletin 2011 Q3. Bank of England. - Meaning, J. and Zhu, F. (2011) “The impact of recent central bank asset purchase programmes” BIS Quarterly Review, December 2011. - Pisani Ferry, J. (2012) “The Euro crisis and the new impossible trinity” Bruegel Policy Contribution January 2012. - Pisany-Ferry, J. (2012) “Debate on Target 2: Don´t confuse symptom and disease!” Blog de Bruegel, 2 de marzo de 2012. - Sinn, H.W. (2011) “The ECB Stealth Bailout” VoxEU.org, 1 June. - Sinn, H.W. (2012) “Fed versus ECB: how Target debts can be repaid” VoxEU.org 10 March 2012. - Trichet, J.C. (2011) “The monetary policy of the ECB during the finan- cial crisis” Speech by the President of the ECB, Montreal, 6 June 2011. 195
  • 194. The turbulent adolescence of the euro and its path to maturity - Weidmann, J. (2012) “What is the origin and meaning of the Target2 balances?” Carta del Presidente del Bundesbank publicada en el Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung y el Het Financieele Dagblad el 13 de marzo de 2012. - Whelan, K. (2011) “Fiscal Rules: Stocks, Flows and All That” The Irish Economy Blog, December 9th, 2011. - Whitaker, J. (2011) “Intra-eurosystem debts” Monetary Research, Lancaster University Management School. 30 March 2011. - Whitaker, J. (2011) “Eurosystem debts, Greece and the role of bank- notes”. Monetary Research, Lancaster University Management School. 14 November 2011. 196
  • 195. /DANIEL GROS * / CINZIA ALCIDI**/ Breaking the common fate of banks and governments 1. Introducción; 2. Recent eurozone history: From bad to worse; 2.1. Recalling the building blocks of the EMU construction; 3. A false solution to the crisis: the fiscal compact; 4. Fiscal indiscipline versus financial regulation inconsistency; 5. A proposal for a new regulatory treatment of sovereign debt securities in the euro area; 6. Conclusions; Bibliography * Dr. Daniel Gros is the Director of the Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) since 2000. Among other current activities, he serves as adviser to the European Parliament and is a member of the Advisory Scientific Committee of the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB), the Bank Stakeholder Group (BSG) of the European Banking Authority (EBA) and the Euro 50 Group of eminent economists. He also acts as editor of Economie Internationale and International Finance. In the past, Daniel Gros worked at the IMF (1984-86), at the European Commission (1989-91), has been a member of high-level advisory bodies and provided strategic advice to numerous governments and central banks. Gros holds a PhD. in economics from the University of Chicago, has taught at prestigious universities throughout Europe and is the author of several books and nume- rous contributions to scientific journals and newspapers. Since 2005, he has been Vice- President of Eurizon Capital Asset Management. ** Dr. Cinzia Alcidi holds a Ph.D. degree in International Economics from the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, Geneva (Switzerland). She is 197
  • 196. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments 1. Introduction Since 2010 the news about Europe has gone from bad to worse. In early 2012, it still cannot be claimed that the eurozone crisis is solved, thought markets within the euro area seems to return (maybe only temporarily) to more normal conditions. Interestingly enough, the average of the fundamentals of the euro area looks actually relatively good: compared to the US, the eurozone as whole has a much lower fiscal deficit (4% of GDP in 2011 against almost 10% for the US) and unlike the US, it has no external deficit. Its current account is close to balance, which means that enough savings exist within the monetary union to finance the public deficits of all its member states. This implies, in turn, that potentially enough, domestic, euro zone’s resources exist to solve the debt problem, without recurring to external lenders. Whether these resources will be invested to finance eurozone governments is a different question. currently LUISS Research Fellow at Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) in Brussels where she is part of the Economic Policy Unit dealing mainly with issues rela- ted to monetary and fiscal policy in the European Union. Before joining CEPS in early 2009, she taught undergraduate courses at University of Perugia (Italy) and worked at International Labour Office in Geneva. Her research interest focuses on international economics and economic policy. Since her arrival at CEPS, she has worked extensively with Daniel Gros on the macroeconomic and financial aspects of crisis in Europe and at global level, as well on the policy response to it. She has published several articles on the topic and participates regularly in international conferences. 198
  • 197. The Future of the Euro In spite of this relative strength, eurozone policy-makers seem incapable to solve the debt crisis. Meeting after meeting, heads of state and Government or finance ministers have failed to convince markets of the validity of their strategy, which has focused almost exclusively on fiscal discipline and has repeatedly advocated the need of financial help from outside investors, e.g. IMF and Asian investors, regardless of whether resources exist within the eurozo- ne. This approach has been both misguided and unconvincing. Against this background, the paper emphasizes that while the political agenda is almost obsessively focused on fiscal issues, the euro zone crisis does not have a mere fiscal nature neither a simple fiscal solution. It involves different dimensions running from current account and external debt problems to the weak state of the banking sector, which is still largely undercapitalized. This paper will focus on the last element, the state of the banking system and attempts at highlighting how features of the existing financial mar- ket regulation framework which are inconsistent with main buil- ding blocks of the monetary union have affected the course of the crisis. We will argue that this inconsistency has crucially contribu- ted to eurozone crisis and still remains unaddressed. The paper also expresses concern about the misleading, prevailing view that the just signed fiscal compact will work as crucial ingredient in the reci- pe to overcome the eurozone crisis, while the banking sector remains highly leveraged and exposed to the fortune and misfortu- ne of sovereign governments. On this ground, the paper puts for- ward some ideas about how to break the tight linkage between 199
  • 198. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments governments and banks. This is at the root of their common fate and represents a decisive obstacle to overcome the eurozone crisis. 2. Recent eurozone history: From bad to worse To understand why the euro crisis has gone from bad to worse, one needs to develop a better understanding of the inconsistencies in the setup of European Monetary Union (EMU) that caused the problem in the first place. The official reading is that this is not a crisis of the euro, but of the public debt of some profligate euro area member countries. Therefore, tackling the causes of this crisis and averting future ones requires only a new, tighter framework for fiscal policy – which will be delivered by the new ‘fiscal compact’. Yet, financial markets do not seem much impressed by a further strengthening of fiscal rules: Portugal and other countries still have to pay high risk premia while Greece has defaulted on its debt and still teeters on the brink of a total collapse. This suggests that the official approach captures only part of the problem and still misses the full picture. It is not only fiscal indiscipline in the periphery which turned the public debt problems of a small country like Greece into a cri- sis of the entire euro area banking system. The euro zone crisis is the result of a constellation of vulnerabilities within the eurozone. They include balance of payments problems, foreign debt, sudden- 200
  • 199. The Future of the Euro stops of crosser-border financing running from North to South combined with a generalized undercapitalization of the banking system. This financial fragility has been the result of inconsistencies in the setup of the EMU as well as a fundamental inconsistency in financial market regulation that has yet to be addressed. 2.1. Recalling the building blocks of the EMU construction The original design of EMU, as established by the Maastricht Treaty in 1992, contained three key elements: i) An independent central bank, the ECB, devoted only to price stability. ii) Limits on fiscal deficits enforced via the excessive deficit pro- cedure (Treaty based) and the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP, essentially an intergovernmental agreement, although still within the EU’s legal framework). iii) The ‘no bail-out’, or rather ‘no co-responsibility’ clause (art. 125 of the TFEU). The treaty also contained other elements of economic gover- nance,1 but this remained mostly declamatory as in reality 1 For instance, Article 121 of the TFEU contains the provision that member states should regard economic policies as a matter of common concern and shall coordinate them within the Council. 201
  • 200. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments Member States did not see any need to coordinate economic poli- cies; at least, not before the crisis. The first key element of the Maastricht Treaty, i.e. the very strong independence of the ECB, was based on a large consensus among both economists and policy makers that the task of a cen- tral bank should mainly be to maintain price stability. The con- sensus was based on a common reading of the experience of the previous decades that higher inflation did not buy more growth and independent central banks (with the Bundesbank as the most prominent example) are best placed to achieve and maintain price stability.2 Some academic economists and some observers at international financial institutions worried already in the 1990s about financial instability and advocate a clear role of the EBC in safeguarding financial stability.3 Some also emphasized that a common currency area also requires a common system of supervision of financial markets.4 But the issue of financial stability did not attract the attention of policy makers mainly for two main reasons. The first one is theoretical: most prominent economic models before 2007 suggested that price stability delivers financial stability as by-pro- 2 A prominent paper of the period when plans for EMU were taking shape encapsula- ted this insight in the title ‘The advantage of tying one’s hands’ (see Giavazzi and Pagano (1988). 3 See for instance Garber (1992). 4 Among others Tommaso Padoa Schioppa (1994). 202
  • 201. The Future of the Euro duct, with no need to add another tool to achieve it. The second one is much less sophisticated and relates to the fact that the two key member states driving EMU, France and Germany, had not experienced a systemic financial crisis for decades. The second element of the Maastricht Treaty, namely the limits on fiscal policy, did not enjoy the same consensus in the academic profession (nor among policy makers) as central bank indepen- dence. During the 1990s a wide ranging debate took place about the sense or non-sense of the Maastricht ‘reference’ values of 3% of GDP for the deficit and 60% for the debt level. Apparently the advantage of tying one’s hands was much less recognized in the field of fiscal policy. However, this debate did not need to be resolved as long as benign financial market conditions prevailed and even the core countries conspired to weaken the limits on deficits set by the SGP in 2003. The third element was only in the background and remained untested until recently. Contrary to a widespread misconception, Article 125 of the TFEU does not prohibit bail outs. It merely asserts that the EU does not guarantee the debt of its member sta- tes and that member states do not guarantee each other’s obliga- tions. Germany had insisted on the no bail-out clause when the Maastricht Treaty was negotiated about 20 years ago. Today, it is clear that this clause does not provide the kind of protection that was sought and widespread financial market turbulences threaten to engulf Germany to agree to huge bail-out packages which would 203
  • 202. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments have been unthinkable only recently. However, instead of working on averting the repeat of this situation in the future, German policy makers are focusing exclusively on the need to ensure lower fiscal deficits. This is the purpose of the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union also called the ‘fiscal compact’ under which euro area member countries agree to adopt strict rules, ‘at the constitutional or equivalent level’, limi- ting the cyclically adjusted deficit of the government to less than 0.5% of GDP. Will this fiscal compact work where the Stability Pact failed? The ‘original’ SGP already contained the engagement by mem- ber states to balance their budget over the cycle. If implemented since the onset of the monetary union, the rule would have led to a continuous reduction of the debt-to-GDP ratio towards the 60% target. But this did not happen. The promise or rather exhortation contained in the SGP to balance budgets over the cycle was widely ignored, given that the rule was not binding and financial markets remained in a ‘permissive’ mood. All of the larger euro area mem- bers ran budget deficits in excess of 3% of GDP threshold for the first 4-5 years of the euro’s existence. Even Germany ran deficits above 3% of GDP from 2001 to 2005. In 2003 a proposal put for- ward by the Commission to ratchet up the excessive deficit proce- dure to the point where fines might have been imposed on France and Germany was defeated in the Council (of finance ministers, ECOFIN). In the crucial vote the large countries (most of which had excessive deficits, except Spain) colluded to water down the 204
  • 203. The Future of the Euro proposal and won the opposition of the smaller countries. The ’band of three large sinners’ (Germany, France and Italy) even managed to put together a qualified majority to ‘hold the proce- dure in abeyance’.5 This narrative is interesting in the light of the new ‘fiscal com- pact’ which is supposed to radically strengthen the enforcement of the fiscal rules by the application of the ‘reverse qualified majo- rity’. Under this principle, an excessive deficit procedure launched by the Commission is taken to be approved unless it is opposed by a qualified majority. As past experience shows, despite the new sys- tem makes the opposition harder, it does not ensure enforcement. In 2005, following the 2003 episode, the SGP was changed. The official justification was the need to improve its economic rational and thus ownership,6 but it clear that it was necessary to avoid the repeat of the embarrassing situation in which a literal application of the rules would have led to sanctions for Germany and France among others. The reaction in academia and among policy makers was mixed: the SGP was ‘softened’ according to some, but ‘impro- ved’ according to others. The very fact that professional opinion on the merits of ’binding rules for fiscal policy’ was divided from the start certainly facilitated the change in the SGP when it beca- me politically opportune. 5 See Gros et al. (2004). 3 See for instance Garber (1992). 6 Annex to the 2005 Council conclusions (http://register.consilium.europa.eu/pdf/en/05/st07/st07619-re01.en05.pdf). 205
  • 204. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments As matter of facts, shortly after the SGP was made less stringent, the upturn of the business cycle allowed most governments to reduce their deficits to below 3% seemingly vindicating the official position that the ‘improved’ Stability Pact had led to a more res- ponsible fiscal policy. But structural deficits (i.e. adjusted for the cycle) actually improved very little even at time the boom reached the peak in 2006-7 and, when the crisis hit, any remaining caution was thrown overboard as deficits were allowed to increase again. The euro area countries thus never lived up to the rules they gave themselves. But even so, on average they remained relatively con- servative in fiscal terms. In 2009, the average deficit peaked at 6.5% of GDP, its highest level, whereas both the UK and the US went above 11% during that year. Moreover, while the eurozone deficit has brought back to 4% of GDP in 2011, it has remained at double digits levels in both the UK and the US. In this limited sense, one could argue that the Maastricht provisions against ‘excessive’ defi- cits did have some influence after all, at least on average. While the average deficits for the euro area appear today ‘modest’ by the standard of other large developed countries, one euro area country, Greece, clearly violated all rules for years. But mounting evidence that the Greek fiscal numbers did not add up was never acted upon until it was too late. As long as financial mar- kets provided financing at favorable rates any action was politically inconvenient and was avoided. 206
  • 205. The Future of the Euro When the euro debt crisis started in early 2010 following the discovery that Greece was running a deficit of 15% of GDP (and that previous deficits had been misreported), some policymakers, German in particular, started to call for tighter fiscal rules as essen- tial to the survival of the euro.Despite Greece was an extreme case, the case of Italy is widely seen as providing another justification for tighter fiscal rules. However, the country seems to stand for complacency rather than fiscal profligacy. Over the last ten years the deficits of Italy have on average been lower than those for France and even today its deficit is below the euro area average (and declining rapidly).Yet, the incapacity of the country to redu- ce its very high debt-to-GDP ratio has made it vulnerable to a loss of investor’s confidence. 3. A false solution to the crisis: the fiscal compact The new Treaty that was agreed upon in March 2012 has a long title, Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union, but upon closer examination it is long on good intentions and rather short on substance in terms of binding provisions. The core of the new ‘fiscal compact’ is an obligation to enshrine in national constitutions the commitment not to allow cyclically adjus- ted deficits to exceed about ½ of 1% of GDP, which is roughly equi- valent to balancing the budget over the cycle as in the original SGP. 207
  • 206. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments This should be done ‘preferable at the constitutional level’. The European Court of Justice (of the EU) can be asked to pass a judg- ment on these national rules, but the maximum fine that could be assessed is capped at 0.1% of GDP – hardly a strong deterrent by itself. This Treaty concerns only the framework for fiscal policy, i.e. the rules setting up national ‘debt brakes’, not their implementa- tion. This Treaty thus does not give any new powers to the Court of Justice (neither to the Commission) to interfere with the actual conduct of national fiscal policy. None of the provisions on eco- nomic policy coordination are binding. Essentially they reiterate the already often repeated statements of good intentions on struc- tural reforms. Among the provisions, the specification on governance institu- tes regular meetings, at least twice a year, of the heads of state and government of the euro area. However, since these meetings will remain informal, in truth, there was no need for an international treaty to establish them. As far as the non-euro EU member states who signed the Treaty are concerned, there is no obligation for them to do anything, but the signature constitutes a political statement which gives them a partial ‘seat at the table’ of the eurozone meetings, allowing them to participate in most of the euro area summits. From a purely legal point of view, this Treaty contains an inhe- rent contradiction: it implies that its signatory countries agree on 208
  • 207. The Future of the Euro binding constraints for their constitutional order via an ordinary international treaty. In most countries the national constitution is of a higher in legal hierarchy than international treaties. This means that even the provisions on the ‘fiscal compact’ constitute essentially a political statement, unless the treaty is ratified with a constitutional majority, as will be done in Germany. The main value of this political statement coming from all euro area member states is of course that it provides political cover for the German government in its efforts to sell the euro rescue ope- rations to a sceptical domestic audience. However, it is doubtful that the ‘fiscal compact’ was really needed for this purpose. Data on German support of the euro show that public opinion remains much more constructive on the euro than widely assumed (see Gros and Roth, 2011). Moreover even before the fiscal compact existed, all votes in the Bundestag have resulted in very large majo- rities in favour of the euro area rescue operations, even when they contained large fiscal risks for Germany. In judging the value of this Treaty one should also keep in mind that, of the four large euro area countries, three have already natio- nal debt brakes at the constitutional level: in Germany it is already operational, in Spain has been adopted recently and in Italy is in course of adoption. In the fourth country, France, it is already clear that the Treaty will be implemented, if at all given the negative attitude of the current opposition, via a so-called ‘loi organique’ and that the French constitution will not be changed. 209
  • 208. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments All in all, the fiscal compact is probably useful in the long run and may contribute to avert a future crisis. It forces Member States to adopt stronger national fiscal frameworks at home. Some, per- haps most, would have done so anyway under the pressure of the markets, but it is unlikely that the new Treaty will make a signifi- cant difference. The main danger is that that it has been oversold. It is likely that the ratification process (e.g. the referendum in Ireland) and then the implementation process in some difficult countries (e.g. France) will receive a lot of attention and create a distorted impression of the importance of the Fiscal Compact. However, the initial excitement will be over once the national fiscal rules have been put into place and this Treaty will quietly be forgotten. Its only remaining impact will consist in the meetings of the euro area heads of state which are likely to produce the regular conclusions that ‘Member States commit’ to everything desirable (structural reforms, etc.). Conclusions which become irrelevant once the heads of state return to their capitals and their domestic political realities. The experience with the SGP suggests that how this new ‘fiscal compact’ will be applied in future will depend on the degree of con- sensus on the need to balance the budget over the cycle. If anything, political will to follow this balanced budget rule will be even more important for the new ‘fiscal compact’ since it will take the form of an intergovernmental Treaty outside the legal framework of the EU. 210
  • 209. The Future of the Euro Today the consensus that only balancing budgets can solve this crisis and allow the euro to survive seems strong and the position of the German government seems particularly tough. This is cer- tainly desirable to prevent future public debt problems but it neglects the crucial role financial market fragility has played in this crisis. The case of Greece is emblematic in this sense: despite Greece accounts for less than 3% of the euro area’s GDP, the pros- pect of the Greek government becoming bankrupt caused Europe’s financial markets to go into a tailspin. The reason behind it was the fragility of banks due to their undercapitalization and their large holdings of government debt. In this perspective, while for a creditor country like Germany it might be important that other member states are forced to copy its balanced budget rules, it should be even more important to ensu- re that financial regulation helps to provide additional incentives for good fiscal policy and that financial markets become more robust and able to withstand a sovereign insolvency. This is what would reduce the need for future bail outs by the German govern- ment. German savers have over the last decade of current account surpluses accumulated about one trillion euro worth of claims on other euro area countries. Safeguarding the value of these claims (which amount to about 50% of GDP) and ensuring the future German savings surpluses are invested with minimal risk should thus be a key policy goal for German policy makers. 211
  • 210. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments 4. Fiscal indiscipline versus financial regulation inconsistency The key insight that has been overlooked in the official circles dominating EU policy making today is that today’s crisis is largely due to an inconsistency in the original design of EMU, not in the area of fiscal policy, but in the area of financial market regulation. Even after the start of the EMU, financial regulation in general, and banking regulation in particular, continued to be based on the assumption that in the euro area all government debt is riskless. This was from the start logically incompatible with the no-bail out clause in the Maastricht Treaty, which implies that a euro area member country can become insolvent, and the institution of an independent central bank which cannot monetize government debt. But it was adopted anyway, maybe because of the perception, expressed recently in a spectacularly mis-timed paper from the IMF, which proclaimed: “Default in Today's Advanced Economies: Unnecessary, Undesirable, and Unlikely”.7 In the much more forgiving environment of the turn of the cen- tury, it was quite natural for policy makers to ignore the logical inconsistency between the no bail-out clause and maintaining the assumption that government was really risk less. Yet this contra- diction had two important consequences. First, banks did not (and still do not) have to hold any capital against their sovereign expo- 7 Cottarelli, C., L. Forni, J. Gottschalk, and P. Mauro (2010) Staff Position Note No. 2010/12. 212
  • 211. The Future of the Euro sure. Second, it was also deemed unnecessary to impose any con- centration limit on the claims any bank can hold on any one sove- reign. This lack of a concentration limit for sovereign debt is in clear contrast to the general rule that banks must keep their expo- sure to any single name below 25% of their capital. This exception would make sense only if government debt is really totally riskless. The main result of this special treatment reserved to govern- ment debt securities on banks’ balance sheets has been that about one third of all public debt of the eurozone is held by eurozone financial institutions, which also tend to privilege the financing of their own government. The fate of governments and banks is thus tightly linked. To the inconsistency of financial market regulation it must be added that the ECB failed to apply differentiated haircuts to government debt it accepted as collateral. Debt securities issued by euro area governments ware accepted in indiscriminate fashion provided that the country was rated at investment grade. This was the case for all euro area member countries, of Greece as Germany. When the Stability Pact was weakened by Germany and France in 2005, the ECB took member countries to court, but it did not change its collateral policy. By doing so it would have given a con- crete signal that it was worried about the long run sustainability of fiscal policy and its consequences for the future of the single currency. Alas, it did not do so, not even during the crisis, after it was clear that it was changing its policy stance. Only now, the ECB 213
  • 212. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments applies a sliding scale of graduated haircuts which makes it less attractive for banks to hold lower rated government debt. The idea that governments provide the only safe assets even in a monetary union where a no bail-out clause exists was also the main reason for another omission: a common euro area (or EU) deposit insurance scheme was never seriously considered. At EU level, deposit insurance is regulated by the 1994 Directive on depo- sit guarantee schemes, but the minimum harmonization approach adopted at that time has proven largely insufficient and the ulti- mate back up for all national schemes remains the national govern- ment. A common European deposit insurance modeled on the US approach of a fund financed ex-ante by risk based contributions from banks like the Federal Deposit Insurance Company – FDIC- would have had obvious advantages in terms of risk diversification. But the preference for national solutions (based on the fear that a European equivalent to the FDIC would lead to large transfers across countries) and the bureaucratic interests of the existing national deposit guarantee schemes ensured that such ideas do not get a hearing even today. The experience with Greece should have served to rest the idea that government debt in the euro area is riskless. But so far no cri- sis summit has drawn the conclusion from this experience for ban- king regulation. Of course, it is true that once the crisis has hit it is no longer possible to tighten the rules on government debt becau- se this is pro-cyclical as the mayhem which followed the only 214
  • 213. The Future of the Euro attempt to shore up the banking system in the context of the recent EBA stress tests on government debt has shown. However in order to illustrate the importance of thinking about the larger benefits from a different kind of banking regulation it is still worthwhile speculating what would have been different if banking regulation had been ‘Maastricht’ conform, i.e. if it had recognized that belonging to the European Monetary Union implies that national government debt is no longer riskless. One could thus consider how the crisis would have played out if the following rules had applied since 1999: i) Forcing banks to have capital against their holdings of euro area government debt. ii) Applying the normal concentration limits also to government exposure. iii) A different collateral policy of the ECB, for example with a sli- ding scale of increasing haircuts on government debt in func- tion of the country’s deficit and debt and its position in the excessive deficit procedure. One can only speculate what would have been different if this kind of regulation had been in place during the boom years. But a few conclusions seem certain. 215
  • 214. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments Greece would certainly have encountered much more difficul- ties selling its bonds to banks which would have had to hold capi- tal against it would be less able to use them to access ECB funds. The same applies to Italy, whose rating went already in 2006 below the threshold at which under normal banking rules higher capital requirements kick in. Both these countries would thus have seen gradually increasing market signals, which would have most pro- bably led to a more prudent fiscal policy. Moreover, their problems would today have been much easier to deal with because banks would have more capital and the con- centration limit would have prevented Greek banks to accumulate Greek government debt worth several times their capital. The resources necessary to prevent the collapse of the Greek banking system has increased considerably (by about 40 to 50 billion euro) the size of the financial support Greece needed so far. The negative feedback loop between the drop in the value of banks and in the yields on government bonds which destabilized the entire European banking system so much during the summer and fall of 2011 would also have been very much mitigated if the concentra- tion limit had been observed. Italian banks would have accumulated less Italian debt and would have been able to offset some of the mark to market losses on the Italian debt with their gains on German debt holdings which they would have had to hold as well. 216
  • 215. The Future of the Euro Common euro area wide deposit insurance would have contri- buted in several ways to deal with the financial crisis from the beginning. First of all, in 2008 it would have obviated the percei- ved need for the competitive rush to provide national guarantees for bank deposits. The Irish government would thus probably not have had felt the need to provide the blanket guarantee for all lia- bilities of its local banks which proved fatal once the extent of the losses was revealed. Ireland would still have suffered from a massive real estate bust with all the consequences in terms of unemployment, but the Irish government would not have been bankrupted by its own banks. Paul Krugman has drawn attention to the parallels in terms of eco- nomic fundamentals between Nevada and Ireland8 arguing that explicit fiscal transfers and higher labour mobility within the US constitute the main differences. However, Ireland has actually experienced a degree of labour mobility which is quite similar to that among US states like Nevada. During the boom it had immi- gration running at over 1% of its population, which after the bust turned into emigration of a similar order of magnitude. The wides- pread held opinion that the euro could never work because there is not enough labour mobility in Europe is not entirely correct. In the case of Ireland the key issue was not one of a lack of labor mobility, but of the absence of a common safety net for banks. A 8 See http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/12/29/ireland-nevada/. 217
  • 216. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments European deposit insurance would have provided stability to the deposit base. It is also likely that the European Deposit insurance would have been less complacent and less beholden to the inte- rests of Irish banks and would thus have started to increase its risk premium when the signs of a local real estate bubble were clear to almost everybody outside the country. Greece, where the national deposit guarantee scheme is now practically worthless because it is backed up only by the Greek government, which has just defaulted on its debt, provides anot- her example of the potential importance of stabilizing the banking system. With a European deposit guarantee scheme there would have been no deposit flight, which has amounted so far to about 50 billion, or over 25% of GDP. There would have thus been much less need for the ECB to refinance the Greek banking system, lowe- ring again the cost of the Greek bail out. The next crisis will be different from the current crisis, but it is clear that different rules for the banking system could bring two advantages: they would provide graduated market based signals against excessive deficits and debts. Moreover, a better capitalized banking system with less concentrated risks would be much better able to absorb a sovereign insolvency, thus reducing the need for future bail outs. Acting on this front seems a much more promi- sing route to reduce the likelihood for future crises and minimize the cost should they occur anyway. 218
  • 217. The Future of the Euro Perceptions matter. Europe’s policy makers seem to be driven by the perception that this crisis was caused by excessively lax fiscal policy in some countries. In reality, however, the public debt pro- blems of some countries have become a systemic, area wide, finan- cial crisis because of the fragility of the European banking system. The ‘euro’ crisis is likely to fester until this fundamental problem has been tackled decisively. 5. A proposal for a new regulatory treatment of sovereign debt securities in the euro area The purpose of this section is to sketch a simple proposal for a new regulatory treatment of sovereign debt securities in the euro area which follows the arguments illustrated in the previous sec- tions. 1. Any risk weights to be introduced after the crisis might better be based on ‘objective’ criteria, rather than ratings. 2. Diversification of banks’ exposure; this is even more important than risk weighting for sovereign exposure. A simple way to attach a risk weight on government debt secu- rities of a given country would be to make the weight function of objective factors like the debt and deficit of the country. For exam- ple, one could imagine that the risk weight could remain at zero if both government debt and fiscal deficit relative to GDP remain below 60% and 3% respectively. If the deficit and/or the debt ratio 219
  • 218. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments exceed the ‘reference’ values of the Treaty, the risk weight would increase by certain percentage points in a proportional or progres- sive fashion. In addition the risk weights should be linked to the stages of the excessive deficit procedure (EDP). When the procedu- re is launched, the risk weight is increased and at each additional stage of the EDP the risk weighting would be increased further. This would provide the EDP with real incentives even without the need to impose fines. Introducing positive risk weights for government debt will not be enough to prevent crisis because of the ‘lumpiness’ of sovereign risk. Experience has shown that sovereign defaults are rare events; but the losses are typically very large (above 50%) when default does materialize. Even with a risk weight of 100% banks would have capital only to cover losses of 8%. Risk weights would thus have to become extremely high before they could protect banks against realistic loss given default scenarios. This suggests that the more important aspect is diversification. All regulated investors, i.e. banks, insurance companies, invest- ment funds, pension funds, have rules which limit their exposure vis-à-vis a given counterpart to a fraction of their total investment or capital (for banks). However, this limit does not apply to sove- reign debt, especially within the eurozone for banks. The result of this lack of exposure limits has been that, in the periphery, banks have too much debt of their own government on their balance sheet which has led to the deadly feedback loop between sovereign 220
  • 219. The Future of the Euro and banks. In Northern Europe, investors, such as investment funds and life insurance companies, which typically cannot avoid government debt have also concentrated their holdings nationally. This has led to a significant fall and in some cases even to negati- ve value of government bond yields, not only in Germany but throughout Northern Europe. From the point of view of core Europe investors, today this might appear as being a prudent stra- tegy, but this concentration increases the vulnerability of the sys- tem to any reversal of fortunes. Moreover, if Northern investors were required to diversify their holdings there would be a natural demand for Southern European bonds, which would bring some oxygen to those governments which have experienced a dramatic surge in their borrowing cost. Introducing exposure limits during a crisis period would be much less pro-cyclical than introducing capital requirements. In practical terms, the simplest approach would be to grandfather the existing stocks, but apply exposure limits to new investments. 6. Conclusions This paper has emphasized that while the political agenda has been obsessively focusing on fiscal issues since the early onset of the euro zone crisis; this crisis has neither a mere fiscal nature nor an exclusively fiscal solution. Despite the Greek episode seemed to point only to fiscal indiscipline, the reasons why the crisis did not 221
  • 220. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments confined itself to Greece but spread out to the entire euro area assu- ming a systemic nature should be sought in the state of the euro area banking sector. European banks were, and still are, largely undercapitalized and too tightly linked to the fortune and the mis- fortune of governments. The paper spots three contradictory building blocks of the EMU construction: the no bail-out rule in the Stability and Growth Pact, the independence of the European central bank and the provision in the financial market regulation framework that government bonds are considered as risk free assets. The combination of the no- bail clause with the institution of an independent central bank implies that fiscally undisciplined countries may have to face default as no other country, nor the EU can take on its debt and the central bank cannot monetize it. This definitely collides with the principle that banks are not required to hold any capital against government debt securities as it assumed that they do not carry any default risk. In fact, Greece has proved this assumption wrong. This contradiction was completely overlooked during the good years in the turn of the new century and the politically more con- venient approach suggested by financial regulation became the dominant. The ‘risk free treatment’ of public debt securities has clearly worked as incentive for banks to finance profitable government spending and accumulate large amounts of government bonds. 222
  • 221. The Future of the Euro This is at the root of the common fate of euro area banks and governments. Alas, the crisis has made that fate an evil one. Though these contradictory elements have now emerged clearly, the issue has not been addressed and the regulator treatment of the government bonds has not changed yet. On this ground, the paper puts forward some concrete ideas about how to break the tight linkage between governments and banks, which represents a decisive obstacle to overcome of the euro zone crisis. We argue that positive risk weights for government debt securi- ties must be introduced in the banks’ balance sheet, but alone this measure will not be enough to prevent a new crisis. A clear pres- cription to reduce concentration of the risk and impose diversifi- cation is at least equally important and complementary to the risk weighting. While developing the arguments for the regulatory changes, the paper expresses skepticism about the official, widespread view that the just signed fiscal compact will have a crucial role in overco- ming the eurozone crisis. As far as the banking sector remains weak and highly exposed to governments, and the common fate of government and banks is not broken, the crisis will be hard to die. 223
  • 222. Breaking the common fate of banks and governments Bibliography - Cottarelli C., L. Forni, J. Gottschalk and P. Mauro (2010), “Default in Today's Advanced Economies: Unnecessary, Undesirable, and Unlikely”, IMF Staff Position Note No. 2010/12. - Graber M. And D. Folkerts-Landa (1992) The European Central Bank: A bank of a Monetary Policy Rule, NBER Working Paper N.4016. - Giavazzi, F. and M. Pagano (1988), “The advantage of tying one's hands: EMS discipline and Central Bank credibility”, European Economic Review, Vol. 32, No. 5, June, pp 1055-1075 (http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0014292188900657). - Gros, D., T. Mayer and A. Ubide (2004), The Nine Lives of the Stability Pact, Special Report of the CEPS Macroeconomic Policy Group, CEPS, Brussels, February (http://www.ceps.eu/book/nine- lives-stability-pact). - Gros D. and F. Roth (2011) Do Germans support the euro? CEPS Working Paper Document No. 359, December 2011. - Gros D. (2012), The misdiagnosed debt crisis, Current History, Vol.111, Issue 773 p.83. 224
  • 223. The Future of the Euro - Gros D. (2012), The Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union (aka Fiscal Compact), CEPS Commentary, March 2012. - Padoa Schipppa T. (1994), The Road to the Monetary Union: The Emperor, the King and Genies, Clarendon Press. Place of Publication: Oxford. 225
  • 224. 226
  • 225. /RICARDO MARTÍNEZ RICO * / The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain 1. Introduction; 2. Evolution of the fiscal policies in Europe and Spain; 3. Analysis of the relationship between fiscal rigour, macroeconomic sta- bility and growth; 4. Next steps in the Fiscal Institution of the Economic and Monetary Union: the necessary contribution of Spain; 5. Conclusion 1. Introduction The current financial crisis in the European Union (EU) has highlighted the importance of establishing a common framework * Public Sector economist, on leave, and Founding Partner, President and CEO of Equipo Económico, S.L. He has held office as Deputy Finance Minister Working inside the team of the Deputy Prime Minister, Rodrigo Rato, and Finance Minister, Cristóbal Montoro. Graduate cum laude in Business Administration at the University of Zaragoza, he stu- dies in the Deutsche Schule of Bilbao and Valencia. He has attended postgraduate cour- ses at the London School of Economics, Kennedy School at Harvard University and Wharton Business School. 227
  • 226. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain which enables the economic agents to act in a macroeconomic sce- nario of stability and confidence in the coming years. In this crisis situation, once again the discussion has sparked the debate in Europe of whether the necessary fiscal stability, which will demand the rationalisation of public spending in the member states, will be achieved at the expense of prolonging the crisis and limiting economic growth possibilities. However, there should be no dilemma between sustainability of public accounts and medium term economic growth. The crisis of the European sovereign debt is a consequence of overspending and debt which the markets are not prepared to fund. In this regard, the only recourse is a fiscal policy designed to mitigate the harsh effects of the crisis and boost economic growth within the framework of macroeconomic stability, continuous supervision over the sustai- nability of public sector accounts and economic reforms. Spain must cease to be a burden for Europe and once again become a driver of growth. Compliance with a route of plausible cuts in public spending in all Public Administrations is a necessary condition to do so, though not the only. As previously shown, in the case of the Spanish economy, stability and reforms make up the formula required to revitalize investment, consumption and job creation. Thus, economic reforms and budgetary discipline are equally important. 228
  • 227. The Future of the Euro The Spanish case is a clear example of a solid and plausible bud- getary institution, where the principle of subsidiarity enables each government with sound finances to tackle its internal decisions in accordance with its economic and social reality (not only because of its significance from a regulatory perspective but also because of the parallels between the European scenario relative to the coun- tries and the Spanish scenario relative to the Autonomous Communities). At the same time, those who are forced to ask for help must abide by the ensuing conditionality. In Europe, likewise, the need for greater economic and mone- tary integration must take us along the path of clear fiscal rules. But it must also do so to encouraging income transmission mechanisms between countries and regions, availability of financial resources and support by way of providing the necessary liquidity to face emergency situations and the pooling of risks, always in exchange for strong sets of conditions to prevent moral hazard. Moreover, within the monetary and economic union the imbalances must be addressed, not only of highly indebted countries, but also those with surplus balances. In some way, it must be recovered an incen- tive system to ensure political commitment and compliance with goals set. Nowadays, the fiscal institution1 is a basic component of European and Spanish economic policy. 1 González Páramo defines it as "the rules which govern the preparation of the budgets, their debate and approval in parliament, execution and subsequent control”. "Costs and benefits of fis- cal discipline: the Law of Fiscal Stability in perspective” (Costes y beneficios de la disciplina fis- cal: la Ley de Estabilidad presupuestaria en perspectiva), J.M. González-Páramo, 2001. 229
  • 228. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain Throughout this work we shall examine, in first place, how the sustainability of the public finances requires a solid fiscal institu- tion and a firm political commitment by the different European governments. Only on the basis of the conviction of the benefits of this statement can one contribute towards the construction of a stronger Europe. Then we shall go on to examine the close relationship between fiscal rigour, macroeconomic stability and growth, arriving at the conclusion that the establishment of simple, transparent, automati- cally applied rules with preventive control mechanisms for all Public Administrations is essential for this ‘positive’ interrelation. All these components are basic for the design of a fiscal policy which helps to recover the credibility that Europe needs in its path towards greater integration to face the sovereign debt crisis. In the last chapter we shall examine the measures taken in Europe and in Spain since the start of the sovereign debt crisis, and we shall reflect on the following steps to be taken in support of the budgetary institution. Then close with the appropriate conclusions. 2. Evolution of fiscal policy in Europe and Spain The European political integration project came about in the post World War years, as an extension of the economic integration process. This was envisaged by one of the founding fathers of the 230
  • 229. The Future of the Euro current Union, Jean Monnet. In 1950, he proposed the creation of a space of peace and prosperity for Europe, via the formation of the European Coal and Steel Community, which became a reality a year later. His way of conceiving the European construction as a project made up of very specific steps – beginning with the eco- nomy – is the way to understand many of the milestones that Europe has achieved in the last sixty years. Examples of this have been the creation of the European Economic Communities, the launch of the European Monetary System, the creation of the sin- gle European market and the firm commitment that has led to the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). During the first decades of the European unification project, Spain was but a mere observer, although fully embraced the inte- gration process along the same lines and endorsed the way of tra- velling the path towards a united Europe. Thus, in the mid-1980s, Spain understood that the current EU offered a chance to take a decisive step in its integration into an international market which would bring gains in efficiency, reinforce macroeconomic stability and contribute to the increase of wealth and per capita income. That would lead to the development and modernisation of the country. And, indeed, this was the case in the first years, where eco- nomic growth rate of Spain was positive over that of the EU, by a maximum of 3pp in 1987 (see Chart 1). However, as of this time, macroeconomic instability driven by an expansive fiscal policy, became a burden for economic growth and job creation, and gene- rated a fast and continuous rise in public debt. The importance of 231
  • 230. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain having a solid fiscal institution in the economic development of the Spanish economy became patently clear. Chart 1 Year-on-year growth in real GDP in Spain and in the European Union Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with data from the International Monetary Fund After the repeated failures of the European Monetary System star- ted up in 1979, and the progress of the approval of the Single European Act (1986) in favour of an internal market, the EU mem- ber states took an additional step in Maastricht. EU member states support, via the adoption of the Treaty on the European Union (TEU) (1992), the creation of an Economic and Monetary Union, whose third phase would entail the launch of the single currency, the Euro. Title VIII of the Maastricht Treaty set three main axes around which the design of the EMU should be built around: sin- 232
  • 231. The Future of the Euro gle monetary policy, fiscal policies subject to common rules and coordination mechanisms for the remaining economic policies. A clear view of establishing nominal convergence mechanisms based on the fiscal institution was already existent at that stage, founded on the following common rules: absolute ban on monetary funding of public deficits, no liability held by the EU or by any other State in regard to debts acquired by another member state, and the set- ting of limits on deficit (3%) and public debt (60%). As of 1997, the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) introduce stricter rules with a defi- cit target of balance or surplus, supported by an early alert system and a disciplinary penalty structure designed to correct deviations. For Spain the commitment to meet the convergence criteria esta- blished in the TEU for eligibility for the third phase of the EMU demanded a radical change to be made in our fiscal policy. Europe then began to act as an anchor in Spanish budgetary policy. However, even when the worst of the recession was over for Spain, governments continued to face enormous difficulties in balancing the budget in the pursuit of macroeconomic stability. It would not be until the political change of 1996, and with the reference and encouragement arising from the creation of the sin- gle currency, when the necessary fiscal consolidation was finally tackled, that macroeconomic stability was achieved and the bases for a new economic growth phase were put in place. The starting point was poor, in 1995 with a deficit around 7% of the GDP and a growing public indebtedness which reached 67% in 1996. 233
  • 232. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain Although the level of indebtedness was lower than the average for the EU, in the case of Spain the combination of the primary defi- cit, the high cost of financing of the debt and the recession had rendered unsustainable the growing public debt. As of that time there was a change in fiscal policy, which took on a markedly coun- ter-cyclical approach. As shown in chart 2, an ambitious fiscal con- solidation programme was implemented which allowed the annual budgets to close with primary surpluses from 1996 until the end of the period and to slow down the growth trend in public debt which, after peaking in 1996, dropped by more than 20pp of GDP until 2004. Chart 2 Evolution of income and expenditure of Public Administrations and of their budget balances Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with data from the Ministry of Finance and Public Administrations 234
  • 233. The Future of the Euro During the period, the fiscal consolidation drive contributed towards a strong growth in GDP (average rate of 3.6 between 1996 and 2004), which helped reducing debt stock via the positive spre- ad between the economic growth rates and interest rates. The suc- cess in the change of direction in fiscal policy was due to a firm political commitment, a well-designed fiscal consolidation pro- gramme and a substantial reform of the fiscal institution.2 For countries that, like Spain, managed to take part in its foun- dation and for others which joined subsequently – such as the case of Greece which, with the support of Germany and despite not meeting at the time the requirements established by the Maastricht Treaty, became part of the Eurozone two years later – the incorpo- ration to the euro meant the relinquishment of monetary policy in favour of the European Central Bank (ECB). And this total integra- tion in the establishment of monetary policy has fostered greater price stability during these years. On the other hand, this relin- quishment made budgetary policy, along with economic liberalisa- tion policies, into the main economic policy instruments in each of the Eurozone member countries. We must highlight that, once the objective of forming part of the euro was met in full, Spain took an additional step beyond what was required in Maastricht. And, in line with the principles agreed 2 “The Spanish fiscal institution: from the Stability Pact to the rules of fiscal stability” (La institución presupuestaria española: del Pacto de Estabilidad a las reglas de estabilidad pre¬supuestaria), R. Martínez Rico (2005). 235
  • 234. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain in the SGP, it rounded off the fiscal consolidation effort with a deep reform of the fiscal institution. As a result thereof, the approval of the fiscal stability laws (the General Law on Fiscal Stability and the Organic Law additional thereto) brought about a change in the budgeting process. This mainly consisted of: the definition of a fis- cal stability target (fiscal balance) in the medium term for all Public Administrations; for the State, a non-financial expenditure limit, the so-called expenditure ceiling, was applied following parliamen- tary approval during the first half of the year; as a novelty, the Contingency Fund was added into the State budget, as a flexibility component during the life of the budget which removes the need for making fiscal adjustments, equal to 2% of the non-financial expenditure ceiling approved by Parliament. The approval of the Fiscal Stability Laws was further completed with a new General Fiscal Law and a new General Subsidies Law. Specifically, the General Fiscal Law aimed at achieving greater rationalisation of the fiscal process, whereas the General Subsidies Law, on its part, aimed at transferring the governing principles of Fiscal Stability Laws (effi- ciency, transparency and multi-annual framework) to the expendi- ture on subsidies (which would mean 20% of expenditure budget). However, in 2005, the European process of integration and reform came to a halt. The solution provided to the reiterated vio- lations of the 3% limit on public deficit established at Maastricht – and following the pressure exerted by Germany and France in this regard, backed by the European Commission – was none other than the SGP, introducing greater discretionary power and taking a 236
  • 235. The Future of the Euro step back in the capacity of the fiscal institution to contribute to growth. Along the same lines, with a comfortable fiscal position and with the same philosophy as that of the reform of the SGP, Spain in 2006 approved a reform to render the fiscal and Territorial Administration funding processes more flexible, which is the sour- ce of our current fiscal crisis. The relaxation of fiscal stability led to a loss of transparency in its application as a result of the flexible new rules. With the outbreak of the international financial crisis as of 2008, the primary surplus of the first years of the period quickly ran out. Discretionary expenditure decisions, the impact of automatic sta- bilisers and the major errors in revenue estimates led to a deficit balance, which worsened over two years (from 2007 to 2009) by 13pp of GDP. This deterioration, which had also taken place in the rest of EU members, was more notable in Spain due to its speed and magnitude (see Chart 3), with few comparable examples within the scope of the OECD (except for the cases of Iceland or Ireland). The deficit fiscal position generated a fast increase in public debt, lea- ding to doubts about sustainability thereof, and translating into significant rises in the risk premium of the country. At the start of 2010, given the lack of confidence displayed by international markets, and in light of the fast deterioration of public finances, the previous Government was forced to implement 237
  • 236. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain Chart 3 Budget balance in 2006 and change in budget balance in 2007-2009 Source: Prepared by Equipo Económico with OECD data a radical change in its fiscal policy and announce a fiscal consoli- dation programme. The sovereign debt crisis, which especially affects several of the “peripheral” member states of the Eurozone (but which has also affect countries such as France and Austria), has highlighted the need to reinforce the budgetary coordination mechanisms within the EMU. In the face of the problems arising from the sovereign 238
  • 237. The Future of the Euro debt crisis and as a result of the fluctuations in the risk premiums of the Eurozone member states, a double reinforcement movement of the budgetary crisis has taken place from Brussels since the onset of the crisis. On the one hand, that implemented by the European Commission, the result of which is, for instance, the legislative pac- kage comprising five regulations and one directive designed to rein- force the preventive part and the disciplinary part of EC mecha- nisms. On the other, that of the member states which, via the European Council, have brought about agreements such as the Fiscal Pact, which seeks to guarantee that all countries will commit to fiscal stability under the highest level of regulation. The reform enacted last year of the Spanish Constitution must be understood within the framework of this new drive from Europe in support of the fiscal institution. The reform, as we shall discuss further in this paper, guarantees the principle of fiscal stability via the highest ran- king law. Despite efforts invested, and despite the positive effect of the liquidity injections made by the ECB, the current economic scena- rio in Europe continues to be marked by the risk premiums of EU peripheral countries, which continue to be too high. The questions as to the capacity of such countries to meet their debt commit- ments have burdened economic European Union results over the last two years. This has led the Commission to forecast a drop in GDP for all of the EU of -0.5% for this year, which sets it back in terms of the growth of the world economy. Although it must be said, that all countries are not behaving in the same way. Germany, 239
  • 238. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain for instance, closed last year with 3% growth, expecting to do so this year at 0.6%, whereas Italy will experience a drop of around - 1.3% of GDP. From a growth perspective, there is an important dif- ference between northern and southern European countries arising from the financial crisis. However, it is worth remembering the strong interdependence between all member states, including Germany (second country in the world in terms of export volume, of which 60% are directed to the EU). On its part, the Spanish economy is clearly included in the “slo- wer” group, at an extremely difficult time. In recent months, the return to recession, which accumulates after four years of crisis, the adverse effect on employment and on businesses, has led to a 24% unemployment rate. At the same time, there is high external debt, exceeding 160% of the GDP, with a high accumulation of public and private debt maturities this year. All these factors have led to a risk premium of around 340 basis points in the last few months and, more recently, well above 450 basis points, and to be closely watched by the markets, that is to say, our creditors. Given this scenario, in 2012, the Spanish economy faces challenges associated with its macroeconomic imbalances yet to be corrected, as well as the potential problems ari- sing from a new challenge from international financial markets. In this framework, we expect a drop in GDP during the first quarters, and although its performance will improve towards the end of the year, it will result in an overall drop in GDP of around -1.5% this year. Meanwhile, the reality experienced by the rest of the world is diffe- rent, with a world economy growth rate of around 3.5% of GDP. 240
  • 239. The Future of the Euro Undoubtedly, the unemployment rate is our main negative dif- ferentiating factor compared to all other EU members and the main concern for Spanish society. As a result of the economic crisis, no country in the OECD has experienced a downturn in the jobless rate as negative as ours. Our rate of unemployment has gone from 8.3% of active population in 2007 to almost 24% at the end of 2011. The crisis has highlighted the problem with our employment model, as our economy is adjusted by means of redundancies ins- tead of by adding greater flexibility to employment conditions. Despite the gradual correction of the external imbalance (the current account deficit has been reduced from 10% of GDP recor- ded for 2007 to less than 4% in 2011), Spain continues to be signi- ficantly reliant on foreign funding (around 40,000M€ per annum). The need for funds shown by the current account deficit, cannot in fact be met by attracting foreign investment to our country. Indeed, the opposite is the case, with recent years witnessing a divestment process, particularly of portfolio assets. The forecast drop in the GDP combined with the high level of debt, puts the sustainability of our funding at risk. Given such conditions, the cri- sis is requiring a must faster deleveraging process than that initially expected. Since the common denominator of the European sovereign debt crisis is insufficient GDP growth, only by articulating the reforms in Europe and in Spain in an expedient and firm manner can the current increasing loss of confidence by financial markets be sta- 241
  • 240. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain lled. In the case of the Spanish economy, this is a path which we travelled successfully in the second half of the nineties, when Spain took part in the foundation of the euro and then went on to lead the fiscal consolidation process in Europe. The new govern- ment seems to have understood this, having begun reforms in three main areas: sustainability of the public finances and moder- nisation of the public sector, the restructuring and reorganization of the financial sector and the reform of the labour market. In the coming years, political commitment to fiscal rigour, macroecono- mic stability and growth must go hand in hand in Spain and Europe, and happen in parallel. 3. Analysis of the relationship between fiscal rigour, macroe- conomic stability and growth In the context described in the previous section, fiscal consolida- tion within the EMU is a fundamental tool for recovering macroeco- nomic stability, the confidence of economic players and the path to growth, leading in turn to job creation. Moreover, the balance in public finances provides the econo- mies participating in the monetary union, which therefore cannot resort to instruments such as currency rates, with greater leeway to deal with external shocks, enabling the implementation of anti- cyclical policies and of automatic stabilisers. 242
  • 241. The Future of the Euro At the same time, as has been amply studied in the literature,3 fiscal balance fosters a macroeconomic stability scenario which pro- vides a more efficient framework for the development of economic activity. The reduction in the deficit increases the confidence of savers and investors. This translates into a stimulus for investment and job creation, as well as allowing households and businesses to plan the purchase of durable goods in the long term, thus leading to sustained consumption, which is a key factor of economic growth. One of the most relevant aspects is the stronger credibility of the economic policy and the improvement in the funding terms of the economies in the international markets, thanks to the reduction of the risk premium, which in turn leads to a drop in financial costs, as shown in Chart 4 in the case of Spain as of 1996. The subjection of European monetary and fiscal policies to certain rules, and the assumption thereof by Spain as a participant in the foundation of the Euro, helped to provide additional credibility to the govern- ment’s fiscal consolidation strategy. This strategy was strengthened by the regulatory reforms introduced by said government as we dis- cussed in the previous section. This positive impact4 on the expec- tations and on the confidence of economic agents explains the sharp drop in long term interest rates, compared to the 10 year German bond. The spread in the Spanish risk premium was actually zeroed as of 2003. 3 “Fiscal policy and long-run growth”, V. Tanzi and H. Zee, 1997. 4 “The Spanish economic model 1996-2004” (El modelo económico español 1996-2004), L. Bernaldo de Quirós and R. Martínez Rico, 2005. 243
  • 242. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain However, since 2008, with the arrival of the international finan- cial crisis, the macroeconomic imbalances accumulated by the Spanish economy led to the opposite effect. Furthermore, as a result of the degradation of Spanish public finances between 2003 and 2009, as shown in the aforementioned graph 3, and the doubts in regard to the sustainability of the Spanish public debt, the risk premium increased once again in a significant way as of 2010, now reaching the 450 base point mark. The significance of fiscal consolidation as a tool for the recovery of stability and long term growth has also been proven in practice in many successful fiscal adjustment processes implemented in the last decades in certain European countries, such as Spain (1996- 2004), Ireland (1982-1989) or Sweden and Finland (1993-2000), some of which have been studied in depth in the literature.5 The most successful process was the one implemented in Finland between 1993 and 2000, which managed to reduce pri- mary expenditure by 14pp of GDP. This was mainly based on per- sonnel cost containment, reduction in transfers from the Central Administration to Local Corporations and the pursuit of efficiency in social expenditure, particularly in health services, education and pensions. Moreover, the fiscal institution underwent a reform with the introduction of expenditure ceilings, which proved to be a key 5 "Fiscal expansions and adjustments in OECD countries", A. Alesina y R. Perotti, 1995. “An Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Adjustments", C. McDermott & R. Wescott, 1996. 244
  • 243. The Future of the Euro tool for cost containment. At the same time, the pension system, the labour market and the financial system underwent a structural reform. The only expenditure programme that was deliberately maintained, thus keeping its 1% share of the GDP, was that of Research and Development. The Swedish experience between 1993 and 2000 obtained similar results in terms of a reduction in primary expenditure (14% GDP), which led to the attainment of fiscal balance in 1997, having closed financial year 1993 with a deficit of 12.9%. In contrast with Finland, Chart 4 Evolution of risk premium Source: Financial Times 245
  • 244. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain in Sweden the fiscal consolidation took place due to both the cut in expenditure and the increase in revenue through a tax rise, while also implementing simultaneous structural reforms such as the pri- vatisation of public corporations and the liberalisation of the labour market. Public spending was reduced by 16pp of GDP over a seven year period, mainly through a reduction of the expenses in transfers and benefits (including unemployment benefits) and a reduction in personnel and current costs of all public administrations. The intro- duction of three-year expenditure ceilings and annual productivity targets must be added to such measures. The starting point of all the above was the strict cut in primary expenditure, as the basis for the adjustment process, mainly cen- tred on personnel costs, transfers and health services. Undoubtedly, a key factor in all such measures is that they were done hand in hand with important structural reforms, particularly those implemented in the labour market, the fiscal system and the privatisations. Those allowed the adjustment process consolidation and the increase in potential growth, on the basis of a firm politi- cal commitment. Furthermore, it helped proved that fiscal consoli- dation strategies based on spending cuts are more enduring and promote a better economic performance than those based on reve- nue increase. Experience has likewise proven that fiscal consolidation cannot be maintained in the medium term without a proper fiscal institu- tion articulation. As shown in the previous section, from the start, 246
  • 245. The Future of the Euro the construction of Europe has been evolving towards a greater relinquishment of national policies in favour of European ones. It is a slow and complicated process in which political divergences often prevail over the overall view of what this process means. This relinquishment has meant the need for greater autonomy in the establishment of rules and objectives, as has been the case, for ins- tance, with monetary policy. Aside from the current supervision problems, it is clear that the role of the ECB in regard to price con- trol has been a success. This example should be transferred to the fiscal policy as a source of inspiration to maintain the necessary political commitment and thus achieve effective fiscal coordina- tion in the Eurozone. We live in an open economy, where freedom of movement of persons, goods, capital, information and technology are necessary conditions for improvement of competitiveness and economic development. A globalised market, with a high level of competi- tion, but also great opportunities, requires a disciplined, foreseea- ble and transparent behaviour by the countries, designed to gene- rate confidence among economic agents. The EMU was born out of this perspective although there have been mechanisms, or even relevant design components, which have failed. In general, The European construction has been preceded by the establishment of rules seeking to limit the risks of integration. The problem has arisen from the lack of rigour in compliance with such rules, probably as result of the insufficient clarity of the rules and 247
  • 246. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain of political leadership committed to integration. When this hap- pens, it is easier to interpret the situation in one’s own favour, par- ticularly when high political power is held. Therefore, it is impor- tant to have clear and simple rules, in order to reduce the possibili- ties of interpretation and to help control subsequent compliance. At the same time, the establishment of preventing rules to ena- ble the anticipation of sharp increases in public deficit, should be articulated via a greater participation by the EU in the preparation of national budgets, in line with the latest legislative proposals of the European Commission on the matter. Preliminary control is a guarantee of compliance and greater co-responsibility with Brussels, which should in turn lead to better access to European funding. According to economic literature,6 those countries exerting con- siderable effort to achieve fiscal consolidation amid a context of economic uncertainty, should design and announce the establish- ment of a fiscal rule within a reasonable period of time designed to improve credibility. In the case of Spain, this step has been taken by way of the reform of section 135 of the Constitution, a historical event of special political relevance. In our case, constitutional reform has managed to raise to the level of fundamental Law – a relevant issue in our highly decentra- lised State – the commitment of all the Administrations to fiscal 6 “Fiscal Rules – anchoring expectations for sustainable public finances”, FMI, 2009. 248
  • 247. The Future of the Euro sustainability. The approval of this reform has meant the recogni- tion of the benefits of fiscal discipline, having assumed the flaws in the relaxation of the Stability Laws in 2006 as well as the need to provide a new common legal framework for all of the public sector. Except for force majeure cases (natural disasters or emergency situations), compliance with the limits on public debt and fiscal balance set by the EU are guaranteed. Likewise, priority is given to servicing the debt in the budget, a condition which helps build the necessary confidence in lenders, and is an appropriate antidote for preventing the loss of confidence in Eurozone countries. The reform also established the need for articulation in a new organic Law, designed, on the one hand, to regulate the distribu- tion of deficit and debt limits between the various Administrations, the exceptional cases of surpluses therein, and the means and terms for correction of any deviations in one or the other that might take place. On the other hand, it had to establish the methodology and procedure for calculation of structural defi- cit. It is important that the calculation methodology respects the procedure used in the EU, to provide discipline and transparency to the fiscal process and help in the statement of accounts. The cal- culation rule must be clear, and serve to consolidate fiscal discipli- ne, as a permanent long term commitment. Lastly, it must esta- blish the responsibility of the Administrations in the event of fai- lure to achieve fiscal stability targets. In this regard, the credibility of the reform will depend on the existence of efficient systems which encourage the Administrations to meet the fiscal targets. As 249
  • 248. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain we shall mention in the next section, such principles have been included in the Law on Fiscal Stability and Financial Sustainability of Public Administrations. 4. Next steps in the Fiscal Institution of the Economic and Monetary Union: the necessary contribution of Spain The European debate on sustainability of public finances and the future of the Euro is set at a time in which, following the con- version of the international crisis into the crisis of the sovereign debt of several Eurozone countries, we have witnessed myriad European summits, each of which seeming to be the last chance to tackle the doubts of the markets in relation to the viability of the debt, in the first place, of Greece, Portugal and Ireland, and more recently, of Italy and Spain. It is true that the crisis is far from being resolved. The EU has not always shown a capacity to react with the speed required by econo- mic relations nowadays – until the tensions reached non peripheral economies such as Austria or France, the pace in reaching consen- sus had been much slower than necessary. Moreover, during the cri- sis, it has become obvious that the institutional design of the Monetary Union was incomplete and, above all, as we have men- tioned in this paper, that there has been insufficient political com- mitment to the application of the existing mechanisms of fiscal coordination. But it is also true that in the last four years, a consi- 250
  • 249. The Future of the Euro derable path has been travelled towards European construction, towards an improvement in economic governance, so that in addi- tion to a single monetary policy, Europe is also able to benefit from greater integration of fiscal policies. As such, it is worth highlighting the agreements reached, either via the community procedure or via inter-governmental agree- ments, in terms of strengthening coordination, supervision and policing mechanisms of fiscal and macroeconomic policies. In the first place, the European Semester establishes a new sche- dule whereby, on the basis of the macroeconomic situation of each member state and its growth forecast, the budgets and economic policies required to meet the commitments undertaken in the Euro Plus Pact and the 2020 Growth Strategy are discussed during the first six months of the year in a coordinated fashion and in accor- dance with common rules. In the second place, the adoption of the so-called Six-pack (one directive and five regulations) constitutes the greatest reform of the SGP and of economic Governance since the Maastricht Treaty which created the EMU. As of the adoption of the new legislation, the European Commission may establish automatic penalties (of up 0.2% of GDP) for those countries with excessive deficits which do not follow the recommendations for correction. At the same time, the public debt control mechanism and the required reduc- tion are reinforced in the event of exceeding the 60% GDP level 251
  • 250. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain assumed. It also introduces a mechanism designed to prevent excessive imbalances such as unsustainable current account defi- cits, loss of competitiveness and other macroeconomic imbalances. Lastly, the signature of the new Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Growth (by all member states of the EU except for the United Kingdom and the Czech Republic) brings changes at the highest legislative level to fiscal stability regulation. This must be translated in each country in that the structural deficit of the public sector may not exceed 0.5 GDP per annum, subject to auto- matic penalties. These steps will be followed in the months to come by impro- vements seeking to fine-tune the mechanisms of economic con- vergence, via two legislative proposals7 of the European Commission, by establishing a clearer and more demanding sche- dule for fiscal coordination in Europe and implementing fiscal control and monitoring mechanisms in countries facing serious difficulties in regard to their financial stability within the Eurozone. All these measures help towards the consolidation of economic governance, and establish the bases to enable progress to be made 7 "Proposal for a regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on common provi¬sions for monitoring and assessing draft budgetary plans and ensuring the correction of exces¬sive deficit of the Member States in the euro area" and "Proposal for a regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on the strengthening of economic and budgetary sur- 252
  • 251. The Future of the Euro via other instruments, in order to provide funding and liquidity to handle emergency situations, to the extent of including euro- bonds, if necessary, as well as helping the ECB to have greater lee- way when acting in the markets in pursuit of economic stability. Without doubt, greater fiscal coordination broadens the funding margin of these countries. But we must be clear that access to fun- ding requires preliminary fiscal control, and not the reverse. Conditionality in all these mechanisms is an essential requirement when seeking to limit risk. Any funding requires certain minimum guarantees of repayment of the loan, and this translates into adjustments and reforms. This is nothing new, but something that has cropped up on many occasions in IMF interventions. Eurobonds might get to play a key role, but cannot be the only item to support the fiscal union, which will drive the Eurozone towards optimum monetary union, and for which to date there is no more than a highly experimental road map. Within this working programme so badly needed in Europe, and supported by conditionality, greater mechanisms for EU income transmission should be created to help countries facing serious pro- blems – such as that of the sovereign debt crisis – in order to imple- ment the structural reforms required by their economies, with the support of Europe in driving growth. This can be done via the encouragement of youth employment and entrepreneur program- veillance of Member States experiencing or threatened with serious difficulties with respect to their finan¬cial stability in the euro area", European Commission, November 2011 253
  • 252. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain mes, the reinforcement of resources available, among other uses, for structural funds or for the activity of the European Investment Bank. On their part, the Eurozone member states can and must con- tribute to guarantee the future of the single currency, and to the generation of the economic growth required to clear any doubts as to the sustainability of sovereign debt, either via their contribu- tions towards the establishment of common rules so that the EMU becomes an optimum monetary zone, or via the reforms on a national scale which constitute an example for all the others. There is also a high degree of parallelism between the rules required and which must be institutionalized in the Monetary Union at a European level, and the process which must be follo- wed in Spain in regard to responsibility, conditionality and subsi- diarity of regional and local Public Administrations. In both cases, the need for a political will capable of applying clear and straight- forward rules, with prevention mechanisms, supported by coordi- nation, monitoring and automatic sanction systems for those who fail to comply with the targets undertaken, has become clearly evi- dent. In this sense, the fact that the new fiscal pact at a European level and the recent legislative changes in Spain seem to be going in the same direction is a positive factor. The case of Spain, where we have a very high degree of decentra- lisation and where the Autonomous Communities and Local 254
  • 253. The Future of the Euro Corporations manage approximately 50% of the public expenditure, is a clear example of the need for coordination of fiscal policies to ensure that the right signals are sent to markets and investors in regard to the orientation of the fiscal policy. The consolidation efforts made by some countries and regions are useless if there are others which do not honour their commitments and destabilise the zone, region or country. Europe and, of course, Spain have their own iden- tity, and this applies to act as a unique body in order to establish the aims. The scope of action of each government to achieve fiscal targets undertaken, via the instruments deemed appropriate, is a different thing altogether. The principle of subsidiarity must be respected pro- vided that the principle of fiscal balance is observed. Each country must have autonomy to define and design its fiscal structure so long as the limits set for deficit, debt and growth in expenditure are respected. Fiscal competition allows for improvement in revenue collection efficiency and greater rigour in expenditure control, and thus the greater fiscal coordination in Europe must not be envisaged as a single fiscal policy. However, one of the main instruments at the disposal of the governments when coordinating fiscal policies is con- ditionality. In any regional funding system there are income transmis- sion mechanisms and penalties aiming to fulfil the set fiscal targets. Therefore, in the event that fiscal stability criteria are not met, be it at a national level within the Eurozone or at a regional level within Spain, the aid provided, as the case may be via special liquidity facili- ties and even, if necessary, by way of eurobonds or hispanobonds, or by way of larger revenue transmissions at a European level, cannot take place without the acceptance of the conditionality it carries. 255
  • 254. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain Spain has understood the need to contribute to the stability in Europe and is leading, for the second time, a solid process of reforms towards fiscal balance. Following the general elections of November 2011, the new government and a reinforced political capital constitute the main assets to bring about the necessary reforms. The proof thereof is evident in the fiscal reforms: the Royal Decree of non-availability, the reform of the Law on Stability, the new system for payment to suppliers, the new bill on Transparency or the bill of General State Budgets for 2012 (which establishes an adjustment of 27,300 million euros to be made bet- ween cost control and revenue increase). The modification of section 135 of the Spanish Constitution assumed its inclusion in a subsequent organic Law (the Law of Budgetary Stability and Financial Sustainability of the Public Administrations, recently presented), which specifies changes in the preparation, execution and control of the Spanish fiscal insti- tution. The recent approval of this bill means a return to the com- mitment to the control of public finances and, more importantly, it adds all of the Public Administrations to its scope of application, which the previous Stability Law failed to do. The three main objectives of this bill are to guarantee the fiscal sustainability of all Public Administrations, to strengthen econo- mic confidence and to reinforce the commits of Spain with the European Union. 256
  • 255. The Future of the Euro All Public Administrations must present a balance or a surplus calculated according to EAS terms and none may incur in structural deficit. However, there are two exceptions in the case of structural reforms with long term fiscal effects (a structural deficit of 0.4% of the GDP may be achieved) and in the event of natural disasters, eco- nomic recession and extraordinary economic emergency. In establishing the objectives of stability and public debt, the recommendations of the EU in regard to the Stability Programme must be taken into account, and all Public Administrations must approve an expenditure ceiling in line with the stability target and the expenditure rule. One of the most important aspects, in accor- dance with European regulations, restricts the growth in expendi- ture by the Public Administrations, as this may not exceed the GDP growth rate. Failure to comply with the targets shall require the presenta- tion of an economic and financial plan to allow the correction of the deviation for a period of one year. This plan must explain the causes underlying the deviation and the measures which will bring it back within the limit. In the event of non-compliance with the plan, the responsible Administration must automatically approve the non-availability of loans to guarantee compliance with the set target and the meeting of the targets shall be taken into account when authorising debt issues, granting subsidies and signing agreements. 257
  • 256. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain The Law, on the other hand, strengthens the preventive and monitoring systems of stability and debt objectives. Therefore, a debt threshold of a preventive nature is established, beyond which the only debt operations allowed will be cash transactions. In order to render all Public Administrations jointly responsible, the penalties imposed in Spain in matters of stability shall be assu- med by the responsible administration. In the event of failure to produce an economic-financial plan, the administration in breach must put of a deposit of 0.2% of its nominal GDP, which after six months may be converted into a penalty in the event that the vio- lations should continue. After nine months, the Ministry of Finance and Public Administrations may send a delegation to assess the economic and budgetary situation of the delinquent Administration. In order to strengthen the principle of transparency, each Public Administration must establish the equivalence between the budget and the national accounts. Prior to approval, each Public Administration must provide information on its main budget guidelines, in order to comply with European regulatory requirements. As was set forth in the new draft of section 135 of the Constitution, the Law establishes a temporary period until 2020 for gradual compliance, until public debt is 60% of GDP. In order to ensure compliance with this scenario, public debt must be redu- 258
  • 257. The Future of the Euro ced whenever the economy experiences positive real growth. Upon reaching a growth rate of 2% or net yearly employment is genera- ted, the debt ratio shall be reduced each year at least by two GDP points. On its part, the global structural deficit must be reduced by 0.8% of the annual average GDP. Beyond the institutional importance of the reform, it is worth considering the political capital that is allowing the deficit problem to be addressed in an integral way and with long term vision. Doubts as to possible deficit deviations in the current and following finan- cial years should not lead us to lose perspective of the importance of the reform. This reform set a trend designed to transform public bud- gets into a reliable institution, with a simple structure, with no room for interpretation, equal for all and with an automatic application which allows it to be protected from temptations from other govern- ments. In this regard, we also view the provisions included in the Bill for the Transparency Law, which, undoubtedly, shall contribute towards generating better knowledge of public finances. The fiscal systems being approved in Spain matched with the European model. There is a strong parallelism between the two, and the construction errors of the European design and of the fis- cal institution in Spain must be corrected by means of a coordina- tion of fiscal policies in which the principles of regulatory equity, subsidiarity, conditionality and sustainability should prevail above all others. 259
  • 258. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain Without doubt, the future of the euro requires more Europe. The construction of Europe needs rules, adjustments and reforms. Without growth the European model is doomed for failure. The current crisis is but a result of the structural deficiencies of our eco- nomy, of our excess indebtedness, of our lack of flexibility and our lack of competitiveness in some aspects. Once again, Spain, on its part, must become a role model of the fiscal institution in Europe, and of the benefits which macroeco- nomic stability brings to the economies, in terms of higher growth, more wealth and greater employment. This is unquestionably the best way to redistribute income. This is the only way we will mana- ge to get Europe and Spain out of the sovereign debt crisis they face, ensuring a solid future for the process of European construc- tion, which is the greatest milestone in the search for peace and prosperity in Europe. 5. Conclusion Following the same pattern set since the inception of the European integration project after the World War, the EMU came about in 1999 as a result of the political aspiration of increasing integration and as a European response to the globalisation pro- cess. In reality, the integration via the monetary union which makes up the Eurozone was not an objective in and of itself, but rather a means to improve competitiveness and efficiency among 260
  • 259. The Future of the Euro member countries. The ultimate goal, therefore, was growth, job creation and the improvement of social welfare, while at the same time making inroads in terms of political integration. At that time the countries were aware of the need to set fiscal dis- cipline targets as stability factors for Europe. However, those impor- tant advances in the European construction process became diluted over the years with the introduction of components carrying greater flexibility and discretionality in the fiscal institution. The best exam- ple is that the solution provided in 2005 to the violation of the SGP by Germany and France was none other than the reform thereof which included greater ambiguity in the search for fiscal stability, for which they gained the support of the European Commission. The diminishing political commitment with the fiscal institution and its fragility in the face of the vicissitudes of the different governments and ideologies became clear at that time. Therefore, with an institu- tional design which was incomplete, and gradually declining over the years, the EMU was far from representing an optimal monetary area, and therefore the imbalances of the Eurozone economies incre- ased, instead of decreasing, placing Europe in a difficult situation in the face of the global financial crisis. In this context, the current European debt crisis has highlighted the urgent need for better coordination of the fiscal policies in Europe. At the same time and particularly during the crisis, the experience since the foundation of the euro has shown the impor- tance of political commitment with the fiscal institution and the 261
  • 260. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain need for preventive rules instead of penalties which are difficult to apply. It is essential to ensure that the accumulation of excessive deficits does not lead to unsustainable situations which call into question traditional European security and seriously complicate the capacity for funding growth and job creation. Rules are a necessary condition to ensure compliance with fiscal targets. But these rules must be of straightforward and automatic application. Despite the difficulties, the present economic time obliges Europe and Spain to make fast and efficient decisions in order to straighten out the situation. It is important to take advantage of current circumstances to tackle ambitious reforms designed to correct some of the structural flaws of the Eurozone and of our eco- nomy. It is important to face the current problems from a long term outlook and to establish the rules of a fiscal institution which ensure the viability of the European project. The future and survival of the euro rests on all member states being able to implement domestic reforms seriously, thus genera- ting a sign of confidence for international investors and which shall also serve, again in our case, as a calling card for our busines- ses abroad. In Spain, one of the countries which has sustained the most damage from the sharp budgetary deviations of recent years, regional configuration shows evident parallelisms with Europe, both in terms of the need to establish common objectives, and in terms of the control systems or the transmission and penalty mechanisms. 262
  • 261. The Future of the Euro Spain, as a country which has already proven its ability to take on this role at the end of the 1990s in the foundation of the Euro, once again has an important role to play. In this regard, it is worth mentioning that, thanks to the latest reforms implemented in sup- port of the fiscal institution, Spain is once again contributing to the European debate in pursuit of macroeconomic stability in the Eurozone and its recovery. The challenge to be addressed, by means of a change in the economic policy, is to recover confidence and credibility of our economy, to enable businesses and consumers to concentrate efforts in business, labour or consumer decisions, and that macroeconomic issues, such as the risk premium, cease to be cause for concern. Only in this way may Spain avoid lagging behind like a second rate club, to which we have already said no a few years back. In order to move forward in building a fiscal union in Europe, which succeeds in turning the EMU into an optimal monetary area and ensures the good health of the euro and of the European eco- nomy, the necessary mechanisms of income transmission, ensure the availability of financial resources and required liquidity, to the extent, if necessary, of creating risk pooling instruments, such as eurobonds and, in parallel, the hispanobonds in the case of Spain. These require, however, the establishment of prerequisites, that is, economic adjustments and reforms to be implemented by the countries facing the most difficulties. The rules are very important, but without reforms it is impossible to grow, and without growth, budgets become unsustainable. A different issue is, provided agre- 263
  • 262. The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution of Spain ed commitments are met, the respect for the autonomy of each country to decide on its income and expenditure structure. Subsidiarity must govern in Europe for those who are taking the necessary steps, as is being done in Spain, in order to adapt the budgets to the economic and social reality of each country. The European construction has taken important steps since the start of the crisis, but it needs to continue to progress via an incen- tive system to ensure the political commitment with the fiscal ins- titution in the medium and long term. The objectives of peace and prosperity established by the founding fathers of the European construction, on a long term horizon, once again depend on our capacity to recover the growth and competitiveness of the eco- nomy, and hence employment and the European welfare model. 264
  • 263. /JAIME REQUEIJO * / The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis 1. Introduction; 2. The Euro: a Badly Constructed Building; 3. The fiscal Spillover; 4. The Consequences of the Doubtful Debt; 5. Contributing Factors; 6. Main Measures Adopted to Solve the Monetary Union Crisis; 7. Outcome of the Measures Adopted so far; 8. Consequences of the Breakup of the Euro; 9. The Missing Link * Ph.D in Economics, BA in Law, Former Civil Servant attached to the Ministry of Commerce, Emeritus Professor of Applied Economics (UNED and IEB).Former positions include : General Director for Imports and Tariff Policy at the Ministry of Commerce, Chief Executive Officer of Caja Postal de Ahorros, Member of the Board of Banco Zaragozano, Director of the School of Financial Studies (UCM) and Member of the Board of Banco de España. His fields of research focus on monetary and financial matters, international economics and the Spanish economy. He has written seven books and published more then seventy papers in Spanish economic reviews.. 265
  • 264. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis 1. Introduction The constant financial trepidation afflicting different countries of the Eurozone, and which threatens the survival of the single currency, is not the result of random events. In our view, they can be put down to four fundamental reasons. First, the Monetary Union is a badly constructed building as political urgency prevai- led over economic prudence. Second, there is the fiscal irresponsi- bility of many member state governments, an irresponsibility that has materialized as hefty public debts. Thirdly, the doubts being generated among the debt holders, mainly institutional investors and banks, and which has led to significant fluctuations in the interest rates of those assets and, in general, to a cost hike for the issuers. Four, what we could call the contributing aspects: the spi- llover and contagion effects that batter the financial markets, effects linked to the opinions of the rating agencies and, on occa- sions, to the worst-case scenarios of the International Monetary Fund regarding the medium-term performance of the European Union economies and, particularly important, those of the Monetary Union. Faced with that panorama, and given the absence of clear solu- tions, there are three questions raised by many observers of the cri- sis. The first question is what the measures are that have been adopted so far to try and avoid the recurring disruption. The second question is whether those measures, or further ones currently under debate, will be sufficient to solve the problem or, 266
  • 265. The Future of the Euro on the other hand, will the fate of the Monetary Union be to totally or partially break up? The third question is if the Monetary Union proves to be totally unviable and the national currencies have to be re-introduced, what will the consequences be of the failure of the euro? This paper seeks to provide a reasoned explanation of the cau- ses underpinning the current major upheaval and it also aims to answer the aforementioned three questions regarding the measu- res, their outcome and impact of a possible breakup of the euro. The paper ends with a short section considering the solution that should be adopted to keep the Monetary Union in place. 2. The Euro: a Badly Constructed Building Even though the dream of the single currency had been always present since the Treaty of Rome, the definitive decision, contained in the Maastricht Treaty, is the outcome of the political desires of France and Germany. Of France as French governments believed that having a single European currency would avoid the constant pressures on the franc, pressures that usually led to the devaluation of its currency. Of Germany as accepting the single currency meant highlighting the European vocation of the most important European economy after reunification in 1990, a process that ope- ned up many raw wounds – particularly in France. Driven by those dual interests, the currency unification project prospered, not wit- 267
  • 266. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis hout significant frictions, until it became reality in 1999, the year when eleven countries, including Spain, ceded their monetary autonomy to the European System of Central Banks; Greece would join in 2001, followed by other countries until it reached the current seventeen members.1 Joining the Eurozone required the countries to meet the so- called Maastricht convergence criteria, those rules aimed at ensu- ring that the different economies had a certain nominal similarity. During the year prior to the Compatibility Test, the inflation rate could not be more than 1.5 points over the average of the three most stable candidate countries; as the end of that year, the public sector deficit could not exceed 3% of the Gross Domestic Product or the debt be greater than 60% of that figure; the candidate country had to have been part of the European Monetary System during the two years prior to the test and without its currency having experienced significant fluctuations; and, during the pre- vious year, the long-term nominal interest rate had not exceeded the average of the three most stable countries by more than 2 points.2 After the failure of the European Monetary System in 1993, only the other three criteria were required to determine which countries could join the euro, and those criteria have conti- 1 Note that the countries that initially joined the Monetary Union were Germany, Austria, Belgium, Spain, Finland, France, the Netherlands, Italy, Luxembourg and Portugal. Greece joined later and, successively, followed by Slovenia, Cyprus, Malta, Slovakia and Estonia. 2 Article 121 of the 1992 Maastricht Treaty. 268
  • 267. The Future of the Euro nued to be applied to accept the application for entry of the suc- cessive candidates. Please note that those criteria were only required at the time of joi- ning. The subsequent restrictions were laid down by the 1997 Stability and Growth Pact, aimed at maintaining budgetary stability within the Union. Thus, the country could not exceed the annual limit of the deficit and the debt: 3% and 60% of the GDP respectively. Exceeding those limits meant that the European Commission would implement the excessive deficit procedure, which would result in the country in question having to face certain penalties. Subsequently, in 2005, the rules were reformed so that the deficits tested were not the nominal but rather the structural ones. Therefore, not only the current deficit, but also the sustainability of the long-term public debt was taken into account in the supervision and monitoring process entrusted to the European Commission.3 In short, and right from the outset, the nominal similarities that a series of economies with clear real differences had to offer were what seemed to matter to European leaders. And, proof of that difference could be seen when, in 2002 – Greece had already joined – the typical deviation of labour producti- vity per hour worked, calculated as CWA was 29.46;4 which clearly showed the different competitive capacity of the different countries, right from the start. Those differences were a hint of the future sym- 3 See “The Stability and Growth Pact: Public Finances in the Euro Zone” of the Sub- Directorate General for Financial and Economic Affairs of the European Union, SCI Economic Gazette No. 2906, 16-28 October 2007. 4 Prepared using the Eurostat data for the twelve member countries. 269
  • 268. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis metric upheavals to come in the zone, and that group of countries, for different reasons, did not constitute – or constitutes – an optimum monetary zone. And thus, the European Monetary Union was built on quicksand, quicksand that would begin to overwhelm it as soon as the fiscal irresponsibility of some of the governments made a sig- nificant dent in the building overall. 3. The Fiscal Spillover Can governments of countries with weak currencies issue debt in their currency and ensure that attracts foreign investors? The like- lihood is minimum as the potential investor will think that, at some point, the currency will depreciate substantially, leading to a loss. Can countries with a strong currency do so? They can because the investors will not fear the losses following on from devalua- tion. And proof of this is that institutional or private investors, resi- dent in a wide variety of countries, have traditionally kept debts in dollars, marks, Swiss francs or yens in their portfolios. The euro sought to be a strong currency right from the outset. This strength was based on the monetary policy of the European Central Bank, whose primary objective would be to keep prices sta- ble.5 And which, furthermore, represented a series of important 5 Art. 2 of the Statues of the European System of Central Banks and the European Central Banks. 270
  • 269. The Future of the Euro economies, with Germany at the head. Moreover, the exchange rate risk disappeared for member countries and it therefore facilita- ted the setting up of a large financial market in euro. The appearance of the euro, therefore, meant the disappearance of the original sin experienced by countries with weak currencies: the difficultly of leverage in other currencies, which meant that they were at huge risk of financial fragility.6 The way was therefore left clear for governments of euro countries that had found it diffi- cult to finance themselves in other currencies prior to joining the single currency, to easily raise leverage in the powerful financial market of the euro. The only thing missing was the imperative need to do so. And that imperative need arrived with the economic crisis, which began in 2007, and with the general downturn in the rates of growth, a fall that is reflected in the following table. It should be noted that even through the downturn in growth was widespread, the countries with the sharpest recession were Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain within the initial group of twelve countries. When the growth rate shrank, which was greatest in those cases with the sharpest change in cycle, the budgetary revenue fell and 6 See Eichengreen, B. & Haussmann, R. “Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility”, NBER WP 7418, 1999. 271
  • 270. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis Table No. 1. Average Growth of the Eurozone (17 countries) Average Average Country 2004-2006 2 0 0 7 -2 0 1 1 Germany 1.87 1.20 Austria 2.90 1.30 Belgium 2.57 1.12 Cyprus 4.07 1.68 Slovenia 4.73 0.74 Slovakia 6.70 3.80 Spain 3.67 0.26 Estonia 8.43 -0.14 Finland 3.70 0.80 France 2.20 0.52 Greece 4.07 -1.90 The Netherlands 2.53 1.14 Ireland 5.03 -0.82 Italy 1.27 0.52 Luxembourg 4.93 1.28 Malta 2.33 2.20 Portugal 1.27 -0.20 Source: Own preparation, using Eurostat data (Europe in figures, 2012) the deficits appeared or increased and grew even further if the bud- gets included automatic stabilisers, by virtue of which the fiscal policy became expansive in periods of recession, and even more expansive if the governments relied on additional fiscal stimulus to overcome the economic crisis. All of these are reasons have been given to explain the rapid increase in the public sector debt, as can be seen in Table No. 2. Given that panorama of slow growth, or decline, and of growing public debts, it comes of no surprise that debt holders would soon have greater misgivings – misgivings that particularly affected those 272
  • 271. The Future of the Euro Table No. 2. Evolution of the public debt of the eurozone (% GDP) Country 2007 2011 Growth Germany 65.2 81.8 25% Austria 60.2 72.2 20% Belgium 84.1 97.2 16% Cyprus 58.8 64.9 10% Slovenia 23.1 45.5 97% Slovakia 29.6 44.5 50% Spain 36.2 69.6 92% Estonia 3.7 5.8 57% Finland 35.2 49.1 38% France 64.2 85.4 33% Greece 107.4 162.8 52% The Netherlands 45.3 64.3 42% Ireland 24.9 108.1 334% Italy 103.1 120.5 17% Luxembourg 6.7 19.5 191% Malta 62.4 69.6 12% Portugal 68.3 101.6 49% Eurozone 66.3 88 33% Source: Own preparation, with data from the Statistical Annex of European Economy, autumn 2011. The data refer to the gross debt as they are the liabilities that the govern- ment must face. countries where the recession was combined with spiralling debt and the few prospects for recovery. It was, therefore, foreseeable that any event that affected the debt of a country would lead to a chain reac- tion that would challenge the financial stability of the Eurozone. That event was Greece going into virtual receivership on 23 April 2010: on that date the Greek government asked the International Monetary Fund and the European Union for a 45,000 million euro loan to meet their financial obligations, four months after Fitch, the rating agency, had downgraded its debt. 273
  • 272. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis 4. The Consequences of the Doubtful Debt From then onwards, there were constant indications of concern in different channels about the sovereign debts with a question mark over them. First of all, the increase of the risk premiums of certain securities; secondly, the increase in the cost of the credit insurance for the same securities; third, the greater occasional cost of the new issues by the countries under suspicion, the so-called peripheral countries: Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Italy and Spain. The three aforementioned reactions clearly moved in the same direction. As is known, hikes in risk premiums on the secondary mar- kets consist of discounts on the value of the securities, discounts that are equivalent to an increase in the relevant interests and which are compared to the interests of the benchmark debt, the German one, for the same market. In its simplest version, credit insurance (Credit Default Swaps) are contracts by virtue of which, and by means of paying a premium, the bondholder is guaranteed the collection of the nominal amount. And in increase of the risk premiums and the price of the swaps affect, by definition, the cost of the new issues: the more expensive the premiums and swaps become, the higher the interest that the new issues should offer and the greater the cost for the relevant governments. All of which tends to worsen the financial situation of the governments, a situation that will enter a downward spiral if the average interest rate of the outstanding debt is greater than the growth rate of its economy. 274
  • 273. The Future of the Euro 5. Contributing Factors Current financial markets are markets of news and rumour mills.7 The first report on how the turbulence develop and reflect veri- fiable facts: the initial request for help by the Greek government; the successive austerity measures demanded by the European aut- horities and the International Monetary Fund for the bailout to be granted; the social response to the austerity plans in different countries or the downgrading of the sovereign debts of different countries of the Eurozone, including France. All of the events show the constant severity of an ongoing crisis. The second are, in general, interpretations, opinions that are usually transmitted through the different media, whether they are journals, the daily press, television and radio programmes or news spread online. Some are reasonably based opinions that are trying to consider the difficult situation of the Monetary Union and to offer some type of solution.8 Others are purely and simply seeking to be alarmist, to the point of suggesting to their readers that they 7 An extensive study into the subject of rumours is by Mark Schindler: “Rumors in Financial Markets”, Wiley&Sons, UK, 2007. 8 Examples of opinions of this type are “Beware of fallen masonry”, The Economist, 26/11/2011, and those expressed by K. Rogoff in the interview published by Spiegel on 27/2/2012, entitled “Germany Has Been the Winner in the Globalization Process”. 275
  • 274. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis should stock up on food to survive the chaos that will reign, on the world scale, when the euro implodes and triggers a financial tsu- nami that will spread over the five continents.9 Furthermore, there are the constant threats of downgrading the sovereign debt by the three major US agencies – Standard & Poors, Moody’s and Fitch –, the three who were so optimistic when it came to US mortgage junk bonds,10 and the doubts expressed, from time to time, by the International Monetary Fund regarding the future of the euro zone. There is also the risk that the whole set of views, from the most founded to the most alarmist, will awaken many fears and the prophecy will become self-fulfilling: the disaster will occur because the avalanche of negative opinions will set it in motion. 6. Main Measures Adopted to solve the Monetary Union Crisis At the time of writing (April 2012), these measures have invol- ved setting up general bailout funds, the approval of a Greek Loan 9 Read “Will Greek Sovereign Debt Default on March 23” by Patrik Heller, Coinweck, 22/2/2012 (online). 10 In the opinion of John Kiff, from the International Monetary Fund, the opinion of the agencies increases the uncertainties on the sovereign debt markets, due to the importance that the participants on those markets seem to attribute to them. See his article “Reducing Role of Credit Ratings Would Aid Markets” IMF Survey Magazine, 29/9/2010. Also Arezki et al: “Sovereign Rating News and Financial Markets Spillovers”, IMF, WP/11/68. 276
  • 275. The Future of the Euro Facility, the interventions of the European Central Bank and the fine tuning of a new Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance of the Monetary and Economic Union. In 2010, the European Financial Stability Fund was set up, whose aim is to facilitate resources to euro countries in financial difficulties. It is a company whose headquarters are in Luxembourg and its loan capacity is to the tune of 440,000 million euros.11 To grant a loan to a Euro country, the government of the country has to request it and sign an austerity programme. Part of the loans to Ireland and Portugal were arranged through that Fund. In 2011, the European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism was created for a similar purpose. It is an institution, supervised by the European Commission, which obtains its resources from the capi- tal markets by means of issuing bonds underwritten by the European Union budget. It may provide aid to members of the European Union, whether or not they are members of the Eurozone, is compatible with aid provided by other channels and also requires the prior approval of an austerity package. Loans have also been granted through this programme to Ireland and Portugal. The two aforementioned funds would duly be subsumed in the European Stability Mechanism), agreed by the Eurozone countries 11 All the data referring to the bailout fund and to the Greek Loan Facility are taken from European Commission official documents. 277
  • 276. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis in February 2012 and which should begin to function in July of that year. Its aid will not be limited to granting loans, but it will likewise be able to acquire bonds issued by the member countries, either on the primary or on the secondary markets, and facilitate resources aimed at recapitalising financial institutions. In princi- ple, it would have 80,000 million euros of capital and an initial cre- dit capacity of 500,000 million euros. In May 2010, the members of the Eurozone bilaterally decided to lend Greece 80,000 million euros that, in addition to the 30,000 million from the International Monetary Fund, meant that the first Greek bailout totalled 110,000 million euros. At the end of 2011, and 73,000 million euros had been paid out from that fund, a payment that required an austerity undertaking. On 14 March 2012, a new bai- lout programme was approved, with substantial write offs for the creditors and austerity obligations for the Greek Government, to the tune of 130,000 million euros, an amount which includes the International Monetary Fund contribution of 28,000 million euros. The purpose of that financial support, which will last until 2014, is to bring the Greek public deficit under the 117% of its Gross Domestic Product by 2020. Part of that bailout will be chan- nelled through the European Financial Stability Fund. A crisis intervention of particular importance is by the European Central Bank, an intervention channelled in two lines. In a non-recurrent way, the Bank acquires debt on the secondary market, which reduces the risk premium and means that the issues of new securities are at a lower cost. On the other hand, it lends 278
  • 277. The Future of the Euro resources at a very low interest rate to financial brokers – its basic rate has remained at 1% for some time – which means that the banks of the worst hit countries acquire part of the new issues. They, therefore, facilitate the placement of securities, securities that are profitable for the financial institutions and less costly for the issuers. On 2 March 2012 and after many debates in the European Council, the representatives of twenty-five countries of the European Union – as neither the United Kingdom nor in the Czech Republic wanted to sign up – signed the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union. Even though the new Treaty was signed by members of the European Union that are not part of the Monetary Union, its fun- damental proposal is to force the euro countries to ensure that their public finances are balanced. Further proof of that purpose is that the Treaty will come into force when it has been ratified by at least twelve euro countries. A key aspect of the agreement is the so-called Budgetary Agreement that forces those countries to tighten their budgetary discipline and which introduces the balanced budget rule, a rule that must be included in national legislation and, preferentially, in the Constitution. The structural deficit must not exceed a specific limit and cycle deficits are accepted, resulting from substantial downturns in the economic activity, provided that they do not alter the balanced budget rule in the medium term. And, in the 279
  • 278. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis case that the deficit exceeds the permitted limit, a series of auto- matic penalties are envisaged.12 7. Outcome of the Measures Adopted so far Judging by the data that appeared in early April 2012, recovery from the downturn has not yet started, in particular, as far as the peripheral countries are concerned: volatility remains high both on the sovereign debt markets and on the variable income ones – in the case of the latter, the downward trend is reflected by the drop in share prices of the most exposed banks to the sovereign debt of those countries – and the doubts persist regarding the capa- city of several of them to meet their obligations. Which is not at all strange for several reasons. The required restructuring to bring the debt back to more bea- rable levels would hinder, in the short term, the growth capacity of the five countries, as economic recovery would be further compli- cated by the shrink in their tax revenue. And all of this would occur in a climate of recession and economic stagnation that appe- ars to have taken hold of the European Union, over all, and the Monetary Union, in particular.13 12 The full text of the Treaty can be seen at the European Council website. 13 The forecasts can be seen at the European Economic Forecast, Autumn 2011 (online). 280
  • 279. The Future of the Euro The situation of Greece is at the forefront of all the economic analysis of the euro zone as very few believe so far that the recently approved second bailout will result in the country solving pro- blems and many believe that a third bailout will soon be on the cards. And those doubts regarding the future of the Greek economy are spreading to the rest of the peripheral countries and, to a great extent, to the very future of the Monetary Union. Despite the measures approved so far, the decision processes have dragged on as an agreement needs to be reached by country repre- sentatives, who are very aware of the opinion of their citizens, and by representatives of community institutions. Long processes, where multiple opinions, sometimes discrepancies, are mixed, that increa- se the uncertainties regarding the future of the euro, even though the disappearance of the single currency could raise much more wide-ranging problems than the current ones trying to be solved. 8. Consequences of the Breakup of the Euro The breakup of the Monetary Union could occur should one or more member states decided to leave the single currency and rein- troduce their own currency. That split could either be due to the departure of one or more weak-economies or to one or more strong-economies breaking. In either of the two cases, the Union would be broken. 281
  • 280. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis From the legal perspective, such a possibility does not currently exist as the Maastricht Treaty does not include any clause that opens up the way; only the 200714 Lisbon Treaty accepts the voluntary withdrawal of a member state from the European Union, but says nothing about the Monetary Union. This may be because the architects of the common currency always thought that, given that the single currency was an extremely important step in the political and economic construction of Europe, the decision of each country should be irrevocable. Yet, leaving the legal aspect on one side, despite its importance, the collapse of the Eurozone would lead to a series of disastrous con- sequences for the country or countries that had left the euro, for the Eurozone overall and for the world economy. Let us first consider the departure of a weak economy. The mere presumption by its citizens of leaving would result in a large-scale transference of deposits from its banks towards other banks located outside the country, given that nobody would want to see their euro assets converted into balances in the devalued currency; the Government in question would be forced to impose, as a preventive measure and prior to the decision to abandon the euro, a limit on withdrawing deposits and a strict exchange rate control. As it is to be supposed that part of the private debt of the country would be held by foreign institutions, individuals and companies would find them- selves in the worrying situation of having to face such debts with a 14 Art. 50 of the Treaty regarding the voluntary withdrawal for a member country. 282
  • 281. The Future of the Euro national currency of a lower value. With respect to the sovereign debt, the problem would be the same: the Government would be compelled to honour it at a higher cost. And the internal economic adjustments would be of such a magnitude that the main purpose sought by returning to the national currency – regaining the exchan- ge rate policy and, thus, making the exportable goods more compe- titive – would take many years to occur. Without even going into the social and legal conflicts that would occur, in that country, as a seve- re recession for an unforeseeable length would occur. If the country decided to abandon the euro were a very strong economy, would there be more advantages than disadvantages? It is not easy to answer that question, for two reasons. First of all, becau- se the foreseeable outcome is that its currency would appreciate, which, even though it would mean an initial advantage, would also raise problems. For example, and from that moment onwards, its banks would have deposits in the new currency, but it is to be sup- posed that part of its assets would be for operations with residents in the euro zone and, therefore, the financial brokers would have to face losses through that channel, and would moreover have to face its fiscal obligations in the new currency. Second, and this is the more important aspect, the appreciation of its currency would affect its competitiveness in the remaining euro countries – the main mar- ket of all the countries of the Monetary Union – which, undoub- tedly, would hit its growth capacity for many years to come.15 15 On these aspects, see “Euro break-up: the consequences” of UBS Investment Research, 6/9/2011 (online). Also the opinions of Eric Dior: “Leaving the euro zone: a 283
  • 282. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis The departure from the Eurozone of any country, or several countries, would break up the Monetary Union in both political and economic terms. In economic terms, because the growing dis- trust of all its citizens would lead to substantial capital flights and, probably, to the collapse of different financial systems, which would cloud the very limited economic perspectives of the zone and would lead to a long recession. In political terms as its inter- national clout would be considerably reduced, based on a situa- tion, the current one, which is not particularly brilliant: its lack of political unity and its indecisiveness, which characterises it as a soft power area clearly reduce the international presence of a zone that, we should not forget, is, taken overall, the second economy and the second market of the world.16 Its breakup and the ensuing recession would cloud the international presence of that group of countries to unimaginable limits. And without taking into account the likely decline of the European Union. It is interesting to observe the distancing that many non- European analysts show when considering the spasms of the Monetary Union. Which is the equivalent, in many cases, to con- sidering them as a local problem: the Eurozone is having to bear great tensions, arising from the sovereign debt crisis, and there is a question mark over its survival. And they go no further. They forget that, in a world of fully integrated financial markets, the user’s guide”. IESEG School of Management (Lille Catholic University), October 2011 (online). 16 With World Bank and World Trade Organisation data for 2010. 284
  • 283. The Future of the Euro Eurozone crisis would have a global impact. For two reasons. First of all, because a good part of the sovereign debt is in bank port- folios; secondly, because the credit insurances (CDS) are, pos- sibly, held by financial institutions around the world. In December 2011, 513,000 million euros of public debt of the five peripheral countries (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain) appeared in the portfolios of European banks.17 If we take into account that the financial institutions around the world are linked by a series of international transactions, it is not difficult to con- clude that the breakup of the euro would have global repercussions. In the March 2011, the CDS linked to European sovereign debt stood at 145,000 million dollars.18 Neither of these two figures are high but they are sufficiently important for the upheavals of the euro zone, following on from the breakup of the currency, to be transferred to other regions of the world with substantial multiplying effects. It therefore can be supposed that the Monetary Union will manage to overcome this crisis. Yet, from our point of view, the current firewalls – the bailout funds, however they are called – and the budgetary obligations, included in the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance, will not be enough to overcome 17 Jenkins, P. y Stabe, M: “EU banks slash sovereign holdings”. With European Bank Association data (online). 18 ISDA: “The Impact of Derivative Collateral Policies of European Sovereigns and Resulting Basel III Capital Issues”, 19/12/2011 (online). 285
  • 284. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis the current problems and ensure that the Monetary Union is the threshold to what, when all said and done, has been what they wanted to achieve through the single currency: a certain degree of Political Union. An additional link is therefore now needed. 9. The Missing Link The endeavours aimed at solving the crisis have so far been along two paths: creating financial instruments to avoid the bankruptcy of some governments – the most worrying case is Greece – and strengthe- ning the obligation of member countries to reach and maintain a rea- sonable budgetary balance. Important steps, but which have not mana- ged to eliminate the continuous tension that has been observed in the financial markets, tension that the interventions of the European Central Bank have only managed to soften. Soften, not eliminate. Note that all the actions undertaken so far – bailout and rules – do not imply any joint liability. It involves combining financial aid and remembering that fiscal policy in a single currency arena must be very similar and very prudent in all member countries. The lia- bility therefore falls on the Government of each country. Yet these measures will not be sufficient if the aim is to shore up the badly constructed building of the Eurozone. It would be neces- sary to show that the members of the Monetary Union are capable of jointly and severally assuming liability of the problems of all its 286
  • 285. The Future of the Euro members. And what is necessary, to affirm that joint liability, is to issue the so-called Eurobonds or Stability Bonds; in other words, bonds jointly issued that will replace, totally or partly, the current sovereign debt. That measure, that would be a highly important step forward in the construction of the common building that is based on the single currency, would result in three far-reaching consequences: the sovereign debt crisis of some countries would be rapidly alleviated; the cost of future issues would be reduce as a consequence of the overall solvency; and the financial system of the Eurozone would be more resistant to any future upheaval, and the overall financial stability would therefore be strengthened. This decision necessarily implies the setting up of a common trea- sury and likewise the application of a fiscal policy. Clearly, that decision would entail many economic difficulties and highly complex political problems, as the citizens of the most prosperous and stable countries of the Union will be not very willing to accept that type of shared liability which they would see as the financial problems of others being placed on their shoul- ders. Yet we should not forget that that possibility has already been raised by the European Commission itself, precisely to attain those objectives.19 And we should not forget, above all, that, as I have attempted to explain in this paper, the end of the Monetary Union is not a zero-sum game, where there are winners and losers; it is a negative sum game, where everyone loses. 19 See European Commission: “Green Paper on the feasibility of introducing Stability Bonds”, 23/11/2011.COM (2011) 818 final (online). 287
  • 286. The European Monetary Union: the Never-Ending Crisis 288
  • 287. A. JESÚS SÁNCHEZ FUENTES * /SEBASTIAN HAUPTMEIER ** / /LUDGER SCHUKNECHT *** / Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?1 1. Introduction; 2. Long-term public expenditure in industrialised coun- tries; 3. The first decade of EMU period: a missed opportunity?; 3.1. A disaggregated assessment of past expenditure policies; 3.2. Determinants of the expenditure stance; 3.3. Implications for public debt; 4. Looking backward to the past, lessons for the future? an episodes based approach; 5. The need for prudent expenditure rules; 6. Concluding remarks; Bibliography *He currently works as Ph. D Assistant professor at Complutense University of Madrid. Before he worked as external consultant at European Central Bank, as (Ph. D) Assistant professor at Pablo de Olavide University (Seville, Spain) and as research assistant at Foundation centrA. He holds a Ph.D in Economics from Pablo de Olavide University (with distinctions) and a Bachelor in Mathematics from University of Seville. His rese- arch areas are mainly public economics and computational economics. ** He currently works as an Economist at the German Ministry of Finance. He was also an Economist in the Fiscal Policies Division of the European Central Bank and worked as a research assistant at the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW). He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from Munich University (LMU). His research focuses on empiri- cal public finance and fiscal policy. ***Is heading the Directorate General Fiscal Policy and International Financial and Monetary Policy at the German Ministry of Finance. Previously, he worked at the European Central Bank, the World Trade Organisation and the International Monetary Fund. His recent research mainly focuses on public expenditure policies and reform and the analysis of economic boom-bust episodes. 289
  • 288. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? 1. Introduction The outlook for public finances in the advanced economies for the second decade of the 21st century is extremely challenging, not least due to the substantial fiscal expansion that took place in the context of the financial and economic crisis. Public deficits in 2010 averaged around 6% of GDP in the euro area and exceeded 10% of GDP in the US and the UK (Chart 1, panels a, and b). At the same time, public debt in advanced economies has increased signifi- cantly between 2007 and 2010: by some 20pp of GDP to around 86% in the euro area and so far by 30pp or more in the UK (to 80%) and in the US (to over 90% of GDP). When including Japan, public debt in the G7 countries already averaged over 100% of GDP in 2010. A closer look suggests that most of the deficit increase since the start of the crisis in 2007 was due to an increase in public expendi- ture ratios which have reached or approached historical highs. By contrast, revenue ratio declines have been rather limited (panels c and d). It is, therefore, logical to look at public expenditure when striving to correct fiscal imbalances in industrialised countries. This approach is in fact pursued already by a number of countries with fiscal difficulties. It was also the approach used—successfully—by 1 The views expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the authors’ employers. Correspondence to: A. Jesús Sánchez-Fuentes. Universidad Complutense de Madrid. Campus de Somosaguas, 28223, Madrid (Spain). Tel: +34 913942542, Fax: +34 913942431. Email: [email protected]. 290
  • 289. The Future of the Euro Chart 1. Developments in public finances, 1990-2011 a) Fiscal balance b) Public debt Source: Ameco. 291
  • 290. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 1. (cont.) Developments in public finances, 1990-2011 c) Total public expenditure d) Total revenue Source: Ameco. 292
  • 291. The Future of the Euro many advanced economies in the 1980s to return to sound public finances and at the same time reinvigorate the economy. The case of the euro area is of special relevance for a number of reasons. While the crisis-related deterioration of public finances in the euro area as a whole has not been as pronounced as for example in the US or Japan (see Chart 1), heterogeneity at the Member State level is substantial. A number of countries, in particular Greece, Ireland and Portugal, recorded double-digit deficit ratios and expe- rienced significant increases in government debt as a ratio to GDP. Unsustainable fiscal positions coupled with structural economic weaknesses and competitiveness deficiencies, in turn, fuelled market tensions which - due to strong financial interlinkages – undermine financial stability in the monetary union as a whole. Therefore, at the time of writing, there is a particular urgency for euro area coun- tries to regain market confidence through a swift return to sound public finances. At the same time, euro area membership tends to exacerbate adjustment efforts since the exchange rate mechanism is not available, preventing an external devaluation. Therefore, fiscal consolidation and the restoration of external competitiveness need to strongly rely on internal adjustment processes. Against the background, this study assesses expected public expenditure developments of selected euro area countries for the coming years. Based on the experience with expenditure reform in the 1980s and 1990s, we argue that ambitious and high quality expenditure reform as part of comprehensive economic reform pro- 293
  • 292. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? grammes have the best chance of success. Furthermore, the role of a prudent expenditure rule and the relevance of having a suitable institutional framework are discussed. Section 2 reviews public expenditure trends over the past 30 years. Section 3 reports on the main findings of earlier studies on public expenditure policies during the first decade of EMU. Section 4 looks backward to the past to extract important conclusions on the successful strategy exit of current crisis. Section 5 provides an illustration on the preventive role of prudent expenditure rules before section 6 concludes and draws some policy lessons. 2. Long-term public expenditure in industrialised countries With a view to assessing recent developments in a broader his- toric perspective, it is worth briefly taking stock of trends in public expenditure and the size of the state over the past 30 years (Table 1).2 After a strong increase in the size of government in industria- lised countries in the 1960s and 1970s, the average total public expenditure ratio across OECD, G7 or euro area was broadly unchanged in 2007 -just before the financial crisis- from 2000, 1990 and 1980. The average spending ratio for the euro area remained around 45% of GDP and that of OECD and G7 around 40%. 2 See also Tanzi and Schuknecht (2000) for more details on historic expenditure deve- lopments. 294
  • 293. The Future of the Euro Table1. Total expenditure developments Maximum Change value 1980 maxi- % of GDP 1990 2000 2007 2010 or nearest mum Year Ratio to 2010 Austria 50,0 51,5 52,3 48,6 52,5 1995 56,4 -3,9 Belgium 54,9 52,3 49,1 48,3 52,9 1983 62,2 -9,2 Finland 40,1 48,1 48,3 47,2 55,1 1993 64,7 -9,6 France 46,0 49,6 51,7 52,6 56,6 2010 56,7 -0,1 Germany 47,4 44,2 47,6 43,5 48,1 1995 54,8 -6,7 Greece 27,0 45,2 47,1 47,6 50,2 2009 53,8 -3,6 Ireland 50,1 42,8 31,2 36,6 46,8 1982 54,2 -7,3 Italy 40,8 52,9 47,0 47,6 50,3 1993 56,3 -6,0 Luxembourg 48,4 37,7 37,6 36,3 42,5 1981 51,7 -9,2 Netherlands 55,2 54,9 44,8 45,3 51,2 1983 59,1 -7,9 Portugal 32,4 38,5 41,4 44,4 51,3 2010 51,3 0,0 Spain 31,1 42,1 39,3 39,2 45,6 1993 47,1 -1,4 Euro area (15) 4 5 ,4 4 7 ,9 4 6 ,2 4 6 ,0 51,0 1 9 9 5 5 3 ,1 - 2 ,1 Australia 32,5 35,4 35,5 33,4 38,5 1985 38,5 0,0 Canada 41,6 48,8 41,1 39,4 44,1 1992 53,3 -9,2 Denmark 52,7 55,4 53,7 50,8 58,5 1993 60,2 -1,7 Japan 33,0 31,6 39,0 35,9 41,1 1998 42,5 -1,4 Sweden 62,9 61,3 55,1 51,0 52,9 1993 71,7 -18,8 Switzerland 32,8 30,3 35,1 32,3 34,2 2003 36,4 -2,2 United 47,6 41,1 36,8 43,9 50,6 2009 51,5 -0,9 Kingdom United States 34,2 37,2 33,9 36,8 42,5 2010 42,7 -0,2 G7 3 8 ,3 3 9 ,8 3 8 ,5 3 9 ,9 45,0 2 0 0 9 4 5 ,5 - 0 ,5 OECD 3 9 ,1 4 0 ,2 3 8 ,8 3 9 ,8 44,6 2 0 0 9 4 5 ,2 - 0 ,6 Source: Ameco, OECD. 295
  • 294. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? However, this masks significant differences across countries. The countries that undertook ambitious reforms in the 1980s and 1990s typically had much lower spending ratios in 2007 than in 1980 or at least than at their peak. A few countries, however, inclu- ding many of those that we will refer to in the next sections (US, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Greece, Ireland, UK) had significantly incre- ased the size of government between 1980 and 2007 or least in the 2000-2007 period.3 This occurred notwithstanding an extended economic boom in most of these when expenditure ratios should have gone down. With the start of the financial crisis, public expenditure ratios went up everywhere by on average 5pp of GDP. This brought the total expenditure ratio to about 50% in the euro area and 45% in the OECD/G7 in 2010. For the euro area, the increase still consti- tutes a decline in overall spending since the previous peak in 1995 but this was due to a lower interest bill. On the whole and for many countries, public expenditure ratios are now at or near his- torical peaks. This includes the European crisis countries, Portugal and Greece and the UK and US. These developments show that the challenge of containing the size of the state is more present than ever. And together with deficit and debt figures, the close link between rising public spending, defi- 3 See also Hauptmeier et al, 2011 for an assessment of the expenditure stance in euro area countries since the start of EMU. 296
  • 295. The Future of the Euro cit and debt figures is also obvious. But a number of countries mas- tered the challenge of very large expenditure ratios with ambitious reform programmes in the 1980s and 1990s. This experience will be re-called in the next sections. These countries were typically not the same that face such challenges now—except Ireland and the UK. 3. The first decade of EMU period: a missed opportunity? In this section, we examine expenditure developments and plans of a number of euro area economies, notably Greece, Ireland and Portugal (programme countries), Germany, France, Italy and Spain (large euro area countries) in comparison to the UK and US. The common feature of most of these countries (except Germany and Italy) for the period up to 2007 was a drawn out economic boom characterised by significantly positive output gaps. In principle, this should have allowed bringing down public expenditure ratios signi- ficantly, firstly, due to the impact of automatic stabilisers and, secondly, in some cases also due to lower interest spending thanks to the euro. However, this is not what happened. All countries pursued an expansionary expenditure stance, of the order of 1-5pp of GDP except for Germany (Hauptmeier et al, 2011).4 This basically “ate 4 One of analysing the expenditure stance of a country is to compare it with the expen- diture levels that should have occurred if a country had followed certain fiscal rules. 297
  • 296. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? up” the interest savings from introducing the euro. As a conse- quence, total public expenditure only went down significantly in Germany and even increased strongly in the three crisis countries and the UK between 1999 and 2007 (Table 2). In the US, total spen- ding grew by around 2pp of GDP between 2001 and 2006 but the ratio remained well below 40% of GDP. Together with the US, Ireland and Spain maintained the lowest spending ratios (below 40% of GDP), France’s public expenditure was the highest, at 52.4% in 2007. The increase in public expenditure becomes even more pronounced when looking at primary spending. For the crisis coun- tries and the UK this went up by 3 to almost 6% of GDP between 1999 and 2007. As a result, most of the sample countries still had significant deficits in 2007 while the debt ratio had hardly declined or even increased between 1999 and 2007 (Schuknecht, 2009). Expansionary expenditure policies during good times left most of the countries “unprepared” when the crisis hit. As a consequen- ce of the output fall and further expansionary programmes, public expenditure ratios increased strongly between 2007 and 2009/2010. Increases ranged from around 4pp of GDP in Italy and Germany, to 6-7½ pp in the UK and US to over 10pp in Ireland. The expenditu- re increase was particularly strong in the countries where a credit- fed real estate and financial sector boom had “artificially” inflated Such an exercise was conducted by us last year (Hauptmeier et al, 2011). The study found that most euro area countries had pursued expenditure policies that were more expansionary than a reasonable expenditure rule would have proposed. 298
  • 297. The Future of the Euro Table 2: Recent total expenditure developments % of G DP 1999 2007 2009 2010 Change Memoradum: deficit 1999-2007 2007-2010 2007 2010 Programme countries Greece 44,8 47,6 53,8 50,2 2,8 2,6 -6,8 -10,8 Ireland 33,9 36,6 48,9 46,8 2,7 10,2 0,1 -11,3 Portugal 41,0 44,4 49,9 51,3 3,4 7,0 -3,2 -9,8 Large euro area countries Germany 48,2 43,5 48,1 48,1 -4,7 4,5 0,2 -4,1 France 52,6 52,6 56,7 56,6 0,0 4,0 -2,8 -7,1 Italy 48,1 47,6 51,6 50,3 -0,5 2,6 -1,6 -4,5 Spain 39,9 39,2 46,3 45,6 -0,7 6,4 1,9 -9,3 Large non-euro area countries United States 34,2 36,8 42,7 42,5 2,7 5,6 -2,8 -10,6 United Kingdom 38,9 43,9 51,5 50,6 5,0 6,7 -2,7 -10,3 Table 2: Recent expenditure developments for selected countries % of GDP 1999 2007 2009 2010 Change 1999-2007 2007-2010 Programme countries Greece 37,3 42,8 48,7 44,4 5,5 1,6 Ireland 31,5 35,6 46,9 43,7 4,1 8,1 Portugal 38,1 41,4 47,0 48,3 3,3 7,0 Large euro area countries Germany 45,1 40,7 45,4 45,4 -4,4 4,7 France 49,6 49,9 54,3 54,2 0,3 4,3 Italy 41,5 42,7 47,1 45,9 1,2 3,2 Spain 36,4 37,6 44,5 43,7 1,2 6,1 Large non-euro area countries United States 30,4 34,0 40,2 39,8 3,5 5,9 United Kingdom 36,0 41,7 49,6 47,7 5,6 6,0 Source: Ameco 299
  • 298. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Table 2: Recent cyclically adjusted primary expenditure developments % of GDP 1999 2007 2009 2010 Change 1999-2007 2007-2010 Programme countries Greece 37,3 42,9 48,6 44,4 5,5 1,5 Ireland 31,7 35,8 46,6 43,5 4,0 7,7 Portugal 38,2 41,4 46,9 48,3 3,2 6,9 Large euro area countries Germany 45,1 40,9 45,0 45,2 -4,1 4,3 France 49,7 50,1 54,1 54,0 0,4 4,0 Italy 41,5 42,7 47,0 45,8 1,2 3,1 Spain 36,5 37,7 44,3 43,4 1,2 5,7 Large non-euro area countries United States 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 United Kingdom 36,1 41,7 49,5 47,6 5,7 5,9 Source: Ameco GDP. When this reversed over the crisis, both higher spending and lower GDP drove up the expenditure ratio. Virtually all of the expenditure ratio increase was on public consumption and transfers and subsidies; public investment went up only slightly in a few countries. Greece, Ireland and Spain also reported higher interest expenditure as the rapidly rising debt ratio and higher interest rates started to affect public budgets. Where did countries stand in the third year of the crisis, 2010? None of our sample countries still featured a relatively small public 300
  • 299. The Future of the Euro sector of below 40% of GDP (as defined by Tanzi and Schuknecht, 2000). Even the US, at 41.3% of GDP, featured a public sector that was not much smaller than the euro area average before the crisis. Greece, Portugal, France, Italy and the UK reported public spending ratios of around to significantly above 50%. It has been argued that the increase in expenditure ratios is not very relevant as it presumably reflects almost solely the crisis and should, thus, reverse itself over time as the economy normalises. This reasoning implicitly assumes that output levels and growth rates will more or less return to pre-crisis levels. As a large output gap would be closed, public commitments should decline relative to GDP. However, if the pre-crisis GDP was artificially inflated by boo- ming sectors which have to shrink then both GDP level and growth rates may be significantly lower post-crises. If the 2010 output gap was only small, 2010 deficits and expenditure ratios would in fact represent structural features of the examined economies. In any case, significant fiscal adjustment is needed which in some cases exceeds 10 pp of GDP in the coming years (IMF, 2011). 3.1. A disaggregated assessment of past expenditure policies To assess in more detail what drove expenditure developments since the start of EMU, this section provides an analysis the public expenditure stance across the three main expenditure components that governments can influence in the short term: government consumption, transfers and subsidies and public investment. We 301
  • 300. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? apply the same methodology as in Hauptmeier et al (2011): given the existing levels at the start of the EMU (1999), actual public expenditure developments are assessed against an expenditure path that should have been taken if countries had followed a neu- tral expenditure stance, i.e. if governments had aligned expenditu- re growth to that of potential GDP. The latter is measured on the basis of two expenditure rules: (a) nominal potential GDP growth (NPG rule) and (b) real potential GDP growth plus the growth rate of the GDP deflator capped at the ECB’s price stability objective of below but close to 2% (RPECB) based either on real time or ex post data. This counter factual analysis provides four measures of the expenditure stance.5 Deviations are analysed by looking at margi- nal (annual) and/or cumulative (total period) deviations (expressed as percentage of GDP). According to this procedure, on the one hand, marginal deviations help to identify the year(s) in which expansionary/restrictive policies were implemented. On the other hand, cumulative deviations measure the degree of expansio- nary/restrictive policies in percentage points (pp) of GDP accumu- lated over the period (1999-2010). Firstly, to provide a general perspective, we focus on cumulati- ve effects for the aggregate euro area (Chart 2), comparing actual and rule-based expenditure developments (expressed as percentage of GDP). 5 The earlier study applied six measures but the two additional ones did not provide much additional insights. 302
  • 301. The Future of the Euro Chart 2: Euro Area (12). Expenditures ratios as implied by a neutral expenditure stance, across rules. Primary expenditures Public consumption 303
  • 302. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 2: (cont.) Euro Area (12). Expenditures ratios as implied by a neutral expen- diture stance, across rules. Public investment 304
  • 303. The Future of the Euro Looking at the primary expenditures stance - panel a - suggests a co-movement with the NPG rules which indicates the absence of a prudence margin to operate when difficulties appear. Looking at the disaggregated developments, i.e. the main expenditure compo- nents, gives a different picture: First, the results for public con- sumption show an expansionary expenditure stance on this cate- gory adding up to 0.5-2pp of GDP, depending on the respective expenditure rule. Second, for the transfers and subsidies compo- nent, a strong counter-cyclical behaviour is observed, as one would expect. However, the decreases in economic good times were much less significant than the increases during the crisis. Finally, the pat- tern for public investment is clearly pro-cyclical. At the same time, the adjustments carried out by some countries during 2010 can be already observed (returning to 2004 levels). To complement this general view, we briefly describe the country pattern for the main expenditure components.6 As in Hauptmeier et al. (2011), for primary expenditures, we observe a restrictive expenditure stance for Germany whereas all other coun- tries show an expansionary policy stance over the 1999-2010 periods, notably as regards public consumption as well as transfers and subsidies. However, the degree of expansion is different among components. On the one hand, in the case of public consumption, the magnitude of cumulative expansion ranged from near zero for 6 For the sake of brevity, related country-specific results are not included in the main text. They are available from the authors upon request. 305
  • 304. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? France to up to 5pp of GDP for Ireland. On the other hand, for transfers and subsidies, Germany is highly restrictive by 2-3 pp, and the rest is expansionary by 1-7pp depending on the rule and country. Finally, for public investment, the development of the cumula- tive expenditure stance is quite interesting: restrictive for Germany and Portugal, neutral for Italy and expansionary for all other coun- tries with a tendency of neutralisation in 2010. However, overall magnitudes are small. In a second step, we repeat this same exercise component by component, in order to decompose the cumulative deviation observed. This analysis provides a view of the respective stance of each expenditure component. The list of indicators included is in line with those presented so far; i.e. (i) public consumption, (ii) transfers and subsidies, (iii) public investment, and (iv) other expenditures. Moreover, we split our sample period into sub- periods to show the role of (i)-(iv) before (1999-2007) and during the crisis (2008 – 2009, 2009-2010). First, looking at the expenditures stance, Chart 3 presents the decomposition of cumulative effects observed for ex-post and real- time rules. When compared real-time and ex-post rules behaviour both similarities and differences are found. While on the one hand the dynamics are very similar, quantitative differences emerge especially during sub-period (II), i.e. 2007-2009. 306
  • 305. The Future of the Euro Chart 3: Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending ratios compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods (I) Real-time NPG rule. 1999-2007 %GDP (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 1999-2007 %GDP 307
  • 306. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 3. (cont.) Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending ratios compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods (I) Real-time NPG rule. 2007-2009 %GDP (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 2007-2009 %GDP 308
  • 307. The Future of the Euro Chart 3. (cont.) Decomposition of cumulative changes to public primary spending ratios compared to a neutral expenditure stance for selected periods (I) Real-time NPG rule. 2009-2010 %GDP (II) Ex-post NPG rule. 2009-2010 %GDP 309
  • 308. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? An alternative way to look at these figures is going through the different sub-periods. First, deviations in the pre-crisis period are clearly dominated by public consumption. Moreover, if we leave out Germany as the only restrictive country over this period, two different country patterns can be observed: major deviations from trend as regards public consumption in Italy, Spain and Ireland while Greece and Portugal show strongly expansionary trends in transfers and subsidies. Second, deviations from trend in transfers become relatively more important with the start of the financial and economic crisis. 3.2. Determinants of the expenditure stance An empirical analysis of factors that influence countries’ expen- diture stances can provide further information on the determinants of expansionary expenditure policies in the past. Hauptmeier et al. (2011) therefore applied standard fixed-effects panel estimation techniques on a sample of 12 euro area countries for the 2000-2009 period using the measure for the expenditure stance described above, i.e. the (marginal) deviations of actual spending growth from rule-based or neutral spending (under the NPG and the RPECB rule in ex-post terms), as the dependent variable. The aim of this empirical exercise was to explain the govern- ments’ expenditure stance on the basis of fiscal and macroecono- mic factors, relevant institutional characteristics as well as political 310
  • 309. The Future of the Euro economy variables. The results of the analysis are presented in Table 3. As one would expect, the macroeconomic environment measu- red by the output gap (in % of potential GDP) constitutes an important determinant of the expenditure stance. We find robust support for a positive correlation between the output gap and the expenditure stance across rules and estimations, suggesting a pro- cyclical spending behaviour. As regards fiscal factors, surprisingly the level of public indeb- tedness does not seem to significantly affect our measure of the expenditure stance. We also do not find robust evidence for an effect of revenue windfalls that arguably could increase spending profligacy. We capture such windfalls by including the excess reve- nue growth in a given year relative to previous year’s Autumn fore- cast by the European Commission. However, while we see the expected positive sign the effect is not significant. We find empirical support for the importance of political eco- nomy factors. In particular, parliamentary elections at the national level (Electoral cycle 1) tend to significantly increase the deviation of actual from rule-based primary spending. The opposite holds true for a second election-related variable (Electoral cycle 2) which cap- tures the years left in the current election term. The negative sign on this variable suggests that the incentives for fiscal discipline can be expected to be higher at the beginning of the legislative period. We 311
  • 310. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Table 3: Determinants of expenditure stance Dependent variable: Deviation of primary spending growth from rule-based growth rate Panel A: Ex-post Nominal Potential GDP (NPG) rule (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V ) (VI) (VII) Output gap (based on Potential GDP) 0,525 0,476 0,401 0,463 0,274 0,374 0,476 [3.78]*** [3.01]** [2.50]** [3.04]** [1.65] [2.22]* [3.00]** Public debt ratio (t-1) 0,054 0,056 0,035 0,071 0,042 0,033 0,057 [0.96] [1.04] [0.62] [1.20] [0.83] [0.67] [1.03] Crisis dummy 3,946 3,649 4,028 3,138 2,241 2,34 3,341 [2.17]* [1.74] [1.64] [1.75] [1.08] [1.13] [1.22] Strenght of expenditure framework * Output Gap -0,262 -0,262 [2.09]* [2.08]* Surprises in Revenues growth 0,09 [0.46] Strenght of expenditure framework * Surprises in revenues growth -0,08 [0.86] Electoral cycle 1 2,204 [3.64]*** Electoral cycle 2 -0,812 [3.66]*** Government Stability -2,699 [3.26]*** EDP 0,308 [0.16] Constant -2,941 -2,998 -1,47 -4,148 -0,006 -0,512 -3,079 [0.72] [0.77] [0.39] [0.97] [0.00] [0.13] [0.78] Observations 108 108 108 108 90 90 108 Number of countries 12 12 12 12 10 10 12 R-squared 0,1 0,11 0,11 0,14 0,13 0,11 0,11 corr u_i and Xb -0,76 -0,76 -0,57 -0,79 -0,52 -0,47 -0,77 adjusted R-squared 0 0,01 -0,01 0,05 0,01 -0,02 0 R-squared overall model 0,02 0,02 0,05 0,03 0,07 0,06 0,02 R-squared within model 0,1 0,11 0,11 0,14 0,13 0,11 0,11 R-squared between model 0,56 0,53 0,58 0,57 0,49 0,38 0,53 standard deviation of epsilon_it 4,52 4,51 4,54 4,42 4,15 4,2 4,53 panel-level standard deviation 2 2,13 1,43 2,55 1,24 1,05 2,17 fraction of variance due to u_i 0,16 0,18 0,09 0,25 0,08 0,06 0,19 312
  • 311. The Future of the Euro Table 3. (cont) Panel B: Ex-Post Real Potential GDP +ECB price stability objective (RPECB) rule (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) Output gap (based on Potential GDP) 0,469 0,429 0,299 0,419 0,277 0,377 0,429 [3.92]*** [2.74]** [2.39]** [3.20]*** [1.94]* [2.58]** [2.72]** Public debt ratio (t-1) 0,057 0,059 0,031 0,071 0,053 0,044 0,058 [1.19] [1.33] [0.64] [1.40] [1.18] [0.98] [1.33] Crisis dummy 2,882 2,634 3,267 2,223 1,685 1,793 2,654 [1.56] [1.26] [1.26] [1.22] [0.74] [0.78] [0.90] Strenght of expenditure framework * Output Gap -0,219 -0,219 [1.75] [1.74] Surprises in Revenues growth 0,172 [0.91] Strenght of expenditure framework * Surprises in revenues growth -0,044 [0.59] Electoral cycle 1 1,798 [3.40]*** Electoral cycle 2 -0,798 [4.17]*** Government Stability -2,544 [3.48]*** EDP -0,02 [0.01] Constant -2,808 -2,855 -0,747 -3,792 -0,392 -0,879 -2,85 [0.75] [0.82] [0.22] [0.97] [0.10] [0.23] [0.83] Observations 108 108 108 108 90 90 108 Number of countries 12 12 12 12 10 10 12 R-squared 0,08 0,09 0,09 0,11 0,14 0,11 0,09 corr u_i and Xb -0,82 -0,82 -0,55 -0,83 -0,61 -0,58 -0,82 adjusted R-squared -0,02 -0,02 -0,02 0,01 0,01 -0,01 -0,03 R-squared overall model 0,01 0,01 0,04 0,01 0,07 0,06 0,01 R-squared within model 0,08 0,09 0,09 0,11 0,14 0,11 0,09 R-squared between model 0,61 0,61 0,58 0,62 0,4 0,37 0,61 standard deviation of epsilon_it 4,34 4,34 4,35 4,28 4,09 4,15 4,36 panel-level standard deviation 2,04 2,16 1,24 2,49 1,36 1,18 2,16 fraction of variance due to u_i 0,18 0,2 0,07 0,25 0,1 0,07 0,2 Notes: Baseline (I), Baseline + Institutional framework (II and III), Baseline + electoral cycle and government stability , (IV - VI) and Baseline + European Institutions(VII). Source: Hauptmeier, S., Sánchez-Fuentes, A.J. & Schuknecht, L. (2011) 313
  • 312. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? also control for government stability as measured by the respective index of the World Bank and find that the policy stance on the spen- ding side is less expansionary if a government scores a higher value. Most interestingly from a policy perspective, our results suggest that the country-specific institutional framework exerts a significant effect on the expenditure stance. In particular, we control for the extent to which national expenditure policy faces domestic institu- tional constraints using the expenditure rules index as developed by Debrun et al. (2008).7 We interact this index with the output gap to analyse to what extent strong institutions reduce spending profli- gacy and find that, indeed, the strength of the national institutional framework on the expenditure side significantly reduces the pro- cyclicality of the expenditure stance. This finding is along the lines of Holm-Hadulla et al (2010), Turini (2008) and Wierts (2008). At the same time, the EDP dummy which is included to capture whether a country is facing an excessive deficit procedure (EDP) due to deficits above the 3% of GDP reference value of the Stability and Growth Pact, does not turn up significantly in our regressions. The results on the impact of fiscal institutions may be put into the perspective of the recent efforts to strengthen the European fis- cal framework. One of the lessons from past fiscal developments in 7 For a definition and a detailed description of the computation of this index see European Commission (2006) and Debrun et al. (2008). The index takes into account the share of public spending covered by the rule and qualitative features such as the type of enforcement mechanisms and media visibility. 314
  • 313. The Future of the Euro euro area countries is that the implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact has not been effective in delivering sound and sustai- nable fiscal positions in Member States. While one has to be care- ful when interpreting the non-significance of the effect of the EDP procedure dummy, the result is in line with this perception. Moreover, the empirical analysis suggests that national budgetary rules if well-designed can help to effectively reduce spending pro- fligacy and therefore serve as important tools to promote sound and sustainable public finances in line with the European fiscal fra- mework. This reinforces the need for enhancing national fiscal rules and frameworks as had been proposed by the European Commission in the autumn of 2010. 3.3. Implications for public debt Based on the analysis presented in Section 3.1, it is possible to compute to what extent deviations of expenditure growth from trend led to increases in government debt. Chart 4 shows alterna- tive debt paths for the sample economies and across expenditure rules. Consistent with the previous results, real time rules typically lead to higher debt paths than ex-post rules. In the case of France, for example, following a neutral expenditure path since 2000 would have resulted in a significantly lower debt ratio in 2010, i.e. between 70% and 75% of GDP. If Italy had followed a neutral spen- ding path, public debt would now stand roughly between 80% and 100% of GDP in 2010, rather than at around 120% of GDP. 315
  • 314. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? For a second group of countries (Spain, Greece, Ireland and Portugal), the difference becomes even more drastic. Neutral spen- ding policies in Portugal would have led to debt ratios of 40-60% of GDP in 2010 rather than over 80% of GDP in reality. Spanish debt would have been at a trough of 10-40% in 2007-08 and would have remained well below the reference value in 2009 under all rules. Ireland would have just about eliminated all its debt in good times and thus created significant room for the subsequent rise. Under all rules, debt would have remained below 60% of GDP in 2010. Finally, Greek public debt would have fallen to 60-80% of GDP (rat- her than remain broadly constant around 100% of GDP until the start of the crisis) and increased much more slowly in the crisis. All in all, public debt positions in the euro area would have been much sounder at the start of the crisis and in 2010, if euro area countries had pursued at least a neutral expenditure stance on average during EMU. Public debt could have been well around or below the reference value in the euro area in most of its members by 2010 and nowhere above 100% of GDP. 4. Looking backward to the past, lessons for the future? an episodes based approach In an earlier study, Hauptmeier, Heipertz and Schuknecht (2007) looked at the experience with public expenditure reform in the 1980s and 1990s. They found that there were basically two 316
  • 315. The Future of the Euro Chart 4: Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based Euro area (12) Germany 317
  • 316. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 4: (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based France Italy 318
  • 317. The Future of the Euro Chart 4. (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based Spain Greece 319
  • 318. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 4: (cont.) Public debt ratios - actual vs. rule-based Ireland Portugal 320
  • 319. The Future of the Euro reform waves in industrialised countries. Moreover, they found that there were three groups of countries: (i) ambitious, (ii) timid and (iii) non-reformers. Ambitious reformers were those that managed to reduce public primary (non interest) expenditure by more than 5pp of GDP from their peak within 7 years. Timid refor- mers were those that cut primary spending between 0 and 5pp and non-reformers never undertook much of a cut at all. These coun- tries and country groups, the time and size of the maximum expen- diture ratio and the change in the expenditure ratio within years (T7) as reported in Hauptmeier et al. (2007) are depicted in Table 4. The study argued that conceptually, reforms needed to be ambi- tious in order to make a significant difference for the resulting public deficits and adverse debt dynamics. The more ambitious they were the more they would even allow tax cuts. Already in the 1980s, Ireland, Belgium, the UK, Luxembourg and the Netherlands had sig- nificantly reduced their public expenditure ratio. The UK, Ireland and the Netherlands did so again in the 1990s plus a number of other countries: Finland, Sweden, Canada and Spain. Four countries reduced public primary expenditure by more than 10% of GDP. During this period, 10 countries undertook timid expenditure reforms (amongst them the US, France, Germany and Italy at which we will look again later). The three non-reformers included Australia, which had always maintained a rather small government sector, and Portugal and Greece. 321
  • 320. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Table 4: Expenditure reform phases 1980s and 1990s Max. primary expenditure Change maximum in year to T7 Ambitious' reformers Finland 1993 -14,0 Sweden 1993 -14,0 Ireland (Phase 1) 1982 -12,4 Belgium (Phase 1) 1983 -12,3 Canada 1992 -9,5 United Kingdom (Phase 1) 1981 -8,2 Netherlands (Phase 2) 1993 -7,5 United Kingdom (Phase 2) 1992 -7,2 Spain 1993 -6,4 Ireland (Phase 2) 1992 -6,2 Luxembourg 1981 -5,7 Netherlands (Phase 1) 1983 -5,1 Timid' reformers Austria 1993 -4,3 Denmark 1993 -3,9 New Zealand 1985 -3,8 United States 1992 -3,4 Italy 1993 -3,0 Japan 1998 -2,7 Belgium (Phase 2) 1993 -2,1 Germany 1996 -0,6 France 1996 -0,5 Switzerland 1998 -0,3 Non' reformers Portugal 2004 0,0 Greece 2000 0,4 Australia 1985 0,4 It is, however, not just the magnitude of spending and reform that is important but also the composition. The literature (e.g., Alesina and Perotti, 1995 and 1997) argues that reductions in public consumption/wages and transfers and subsidies are particu- larly “high quality”. They increase the chance of success of reform by providing a strong signal of “willingness” and cuts tend to focus on unproductive expenditure. 322
  • 321. The Future of the Euro Table 5 illustrates that much of the expenditure cuts of ambitious reformers came from transfers and subsidies and also from government consumption. About two-thirds of the reduc- tion in the total expenditure ratio and over 80 per cent of the decline in the primary expenditure ratio occurred in these two categories. Nine out of 11 reform episodes reported a decline in public consumption by more than 2 per cent of GDP and eight out of 11 featured a fall in transfers and subsidies by over 3 per cent of GDP. At the same time, in most cases, government investment and public education expenditure did not decline disproportionately or in some cases even increased as a share of GDP. Timid reformers did not report much of a decrease in public transfers and subsidies and focussed on public invest- ment in some cases and on public consumption including edu- cation in others. The study by Hauptmeier et al. (2007) also argued that public expenditure reform needed to be part of a comprehensive overall structural reform strategy. It was argued on the basis of the litera- ture that this would allow the improvement in public finances not only via less spending but also via better growth prospects. An overview of the reforms undertaken by ambitious countries is reported in Table 6. Most of the ambitious reformers undertook major reforms that were complementary to expenditure retrench- ment. Most countries strengthened their national fiscal institu- tions. This not only facilitated fiscal retrenchment but also tended 323
  • 322. 324 Table 5: Composition of expenditure reform Transfers Total Interest Primary Government Government Change T0-T7 and Health Education Pensions expenditure Spending expenditure consumption investment Subsidies Ambitious' reformers Finland -15,7 -1,6 -14,0 -3,8 -0,3 -9,4 -1,3 -1,8 -1,5 Sweden -15,7 -1,8 -14,0 -2,8 -0,9 -8,0 -0,4 0,2 -1,7 Ireland (Phase 1) -13,3 -1,0 -12,4 -5,2 -3,2 -2,2 -1,7 -0,9 -0,7 Belgium (Phase 1) -10,9 -4,8 -6,2 -3,9 1,0 -4,7 -0,5 -0,9 -1,6 Canada -11,4 -1,7 -9,5 -5,3 -0,5 -3,3 -1,1 -1,9 -0,2 United Kingdom (Phase 1) -10,5 -2,3 -8,2 -2,5 -0,3 -2,0 -0,3 -0,8 -0,5 Netherlands (Phase 2) -9,8 -2,3 -7,5 -1,9 0,1 -6,5 -0,8 -0,4 -1,2 United Kingdom (Phase 2) -7,1 0,1 -7,2 -2,7 -1,1 -2,6 -0,1 -0,8 -0,4 Spain -8,2 -1,8 -6,4 -1,5 -1,0 -4,1 -0,4 0,0 0,2 Ireland (Phase 2) -10,9 -4,8 -6,2 -3,9 1,0 -4,7 -0,5 -0,9 -1,6 Luxembourg -5,9 -0,4 -5,7 -1,4 -2,1 0,0 0,1 -1,6 -0,8 Netherlands (Phase 1) -5,0 0,2 -5,1 -2,0 -0,2 -2,2 -0,1 -1,1 0,4 Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future?
  • 323. The Future of the Euro to make future budgetary control and thus the avoidance of fiscal problems more likely.8 A number of countries devalued their currencies. All ambitious reformers initiated significant labour market reforms that improved work incentives. All but one country reformed the tax system. And most countries reduced the Table 6: Summary findings for ambitious reform episodes Expenditure reform Structural reform Institutional Other macroeco- Labour Public Transfers & reform nomic reform market consumption Taxation Privatisation subsidies 1/ incenti- 1/ ves Ireland 1 XX XX X X X X X Ireland 2 X XX X X X X Sweden X XX X X X X X Canada XX XX X X X X Finland XX XX X X X X X Belgium XX XX X X Netherlands 1 X X X X X X Netherlands 2 ~ XX X X X X Spain ~ XX X X X X UK 1 X X X X X X X UK 2 X X X X X All 9 11 10 6 11 10 8 8 For the importance of fiscal rules and institutions, see, e.g., Poterba and Von Hagen (1999). Debrun et al. (2008) and Holm-Hadulla et al (2011) focus on the numerical fis- cal rules in EU countries. 325
  • 324. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? role of the state in the economy via privatisation. Based on the fact that the reforming countries fulfilled the con- jectures of ambition, high quality and comprehensive reforms it is not surprising that the impact on public finances and the economy were quite positive, compared to timid reformers (Chart 5). Panel a) shows that ambitious reformers (here differentiating early and late reformers) brought the public expenditure ratio down signifi- cantly to levels similar or lower than those of timid reformers. This was mainly achieved through cuts in public consumption and transfers and subsidies while public investment did not change much, at least for late ambitious reformers (see panels b)-d)). Panel e) illustrates that public deficits were brought down very substan- tially by ambitious reformers. The group of late reformers even rea- ched sizable surpluses. As regards public debt developments (panel f)), timid reformers did not achieve any significant reversal in debt dynamics. Ambitious reformers, by contrast, managed to bring debt down once fiscal balances had been sound enough. Contrary to the concerns of vocal special interests and politi- cians, ambitious expenditure reforms had very little (if any) adver- se growth impact even in the very short run while the medium to long term impact was very positive. Ambitious reformers experien- ced a significant increase in trend growth by 1-2 percentage points (panel g). By contrast, timid reformers experienced no such incre- ase. Real private consumption started to recover as of the first year of public expenditure reduction and accelerated more strongly where ambitious reforms were undertaken (panel g). Private invest- 326
  • 325. The Future of the Euro Chart 5: Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s. a) Total public expenditures b) Public consumption 327
  • 326. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s. c) Transfers and subsidies d) Public investment 328
  • 327. The Future of the Euro Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s. e) Fiscal balance f) Public debt 329
  • 328. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s. g) Trend growth h) Real private consumption 330
  • 329. The Future of the Euro Chart 5: (cont.) Ambitious vs. timid reforms, 1980s and 1990s. i) Private investment Source: Hauptmeier, S., Heipertz, M. & Schuknecht, L. (2007) ment initially declined or was flat and showed a relatively less favourable trend than for timid reformers but this reversed in the medium term. In the seventh reform year, the private investment ratio of timid reformers had increased by 1pp of GDP while that of ambitious reformers had increased by 2-3pp (panel i). In a next step we assess recent and projected fiscal develop- ments for 2012 and 2013 in selected euro area countries as well as the UK and the US in the light of the evidence from past expendi- ture reform periods described above. We do this on the basis of the latest European Commission forecast (Autumn 2011) (see Table 7). For the US we consider the latest IMF World Economic Outlook 331
  • 330. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? projections. For all sample countries, the projections point to sig- nificant primary expenditure reductions for the period up to 2013 (with the exception of France). This ranges from about 3-4pp of GDP for Germany, Italy and the US to over 5pp in the UK and Spain and to 7 to 10pp in the EU/IMF programme countries. Expenditure reductions show a more or less linear pattern in most countries. In the case of the US, the primary expenditure ratio went down quite strongly in 2010. However, it is expected to decli- ne only by another 1pp of GDP over 2011-13. Table 7: Expenditure plans % of GDP Primary expenditure Actual Forecast 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2013 to max(0910) Programme countries Greece 48,7 44,4 43,6 42,4 41,7 -6,9 Ireland 46,9 43,7 42,1 39,6 37,0 -9,9 Portugal 46,9 48,3 44,9 42,0 39,9 -8,4 Large euro area countries Germany 45,4 45,4 43,3 43,2 42,8 -2,6 France 53,8 54,2 54,0 54,3 53,9 -0,3 Italy 47,1 45,9 44,8 43,8 43,0 -4,1 Spain 44,5 43,7 40,8 39,8 39,3 -5,2 Large non-euro area countries United States 42,1 39,3 39,6 39,0 38,5 -3,7 UK 49,6 47,7 46,8 45,3 43,9 -5,6 Sources: Actual and forecasts: EU Commission (Ameco), IMF for the US. 332
  • 331. The Future of the Euro If projected spending developments materialise, primary expen- diture ratios would decline to around 40% of GDP in most coun- tries. The main exception is France where the ratio would remain significantly above 50%. Projected spending developments should also be assessed from a longer term perspective. When comparing the 2013 figures to the 1999 primary expenditure ratios it is noteworthy that spending would still be 1-7pp of GDP higher in 2013 than in 1999 for 8 out of 9 countries. This relative increase would be particularly sizeable for Ireland, the US and the UK and appears unwarranted in view of the expected ageing-related increases in social security outlays in the medium and long-term. Only Germany would post a signifi- cantly lower primary expenditure ratio than at the start of EMU. Coming back to the adjustment effort in countries’ expenditure plans, it is noteworthy that five countries (Ireland, Greece, Portugal, Spain and the UK) would meet the criteria of ambitious reformers as applied in the earlier study by Hauptmeier et al. (2007) whereas a second group of countries could be classified as “timid” reformers (Germany, USA, and Italy). 5.The need for prudent expenditure rules The evidence presented in this study supports the view that public spending has been a major determinant of unsound public 333
  • 332. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? finance developments in the past. Looking forward, it therefore seems plausible to address this fact through the implementation of prudent expenditure rules. Indeed, empirical studies suggest that well-designed expenditure rules tend to limit the pro-cyclicality of public spending (see, e.g. Holm-Hadulla et al (2010)). Recent policy action in Europe goes in this direction. Notably, the EU fiscal sur- veillance framework has been extended by a so called “expenditu- re benchmark” which restricts the growth rate of public spending net of discretionary tax measures to that of potential growth. However, this new rule does not take into account some of the pro- blems we identified in Section 3.1. Most notably, an effective rule- based restriction of spending policies in real-time requires the maintenance of a margin of prudence. This is necessary to account for the tendency of overestimating potential GDP growth in real- time. Given the past experience of systematic and persistent down- ward revisions in potential growth, a margin of prudence of ½ pp in expenditure growth per annum appears warranted. In addition, excessive price developments should not automatically feed into higher expenditure growth as expansionary fiscal policies may accelerate an economic overheating. Therefore, the nominal com- ponent of an effective expenditure growth rule should be capped, e.g. at the ECB’s price stability objective (“close to but below 2%”). Chart 6 shows that the application of such prudent expenditu- re growth rules during EMU would have resulted in much safer fis- cal positions. Primary expenditure ratios would have reached much lower levels in 2009. As a result, also public debt ratios in 334
  • 333. The Future of the Euro Chart 6: Actual ratios versus neutral expenditure policies-based ratios (based on NPG – ½ pp and RPECB – ½ pp rules), 2009 Panel A: Primary expenditure ratios Panel B: Public Debt ratios Note: Includes GDP multiplier and compound interest effects. 335
  • 334. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? 2009 would have generally been much closer to 60% of GDP with the highest ratio of around 90% in Italy. It is important to note, however, that the proposed expenditure rules are intended to pro- vide guidance for an appropriate, i.e. neutral, policy stance in the absence of fiscal imbalances. Any fiscal adjustment, e.g. to regain sound fiscal positions in the aftermath of the crisis, would of cour- se require a restrictive policy stance, i.e. spending growth rates below potential GDP growth. 6. Concluding remarks What are the main findings of this study and what policy lessons can be drawn? Public finances in advanced economies are at a cross- roads. In the fifth year of the crisis, fiscal deficits remain high and public debt has reached unprecedented peace-time levels in most industrialised countries. Public primary expenditure stands at or near historical peaks in many countries and therefore constitutes an important determinant of the fiscal imbalances. It therefore seems straight forward to focus on expenditure restraint when striving to regain sound fiscal positions in the aftermath of the crisis. In the 1980s and 1990s a number of countries undertook ambi- tious expenditure reforms. Their experience, which was briefly reviewed here, has been very positive. Within a few years from the start of expenditure reform, public expenditure ratios went down significantly, fiscal deficits largely or fully disappeared, public debt 336
  • 335. The Future of the Euro was brought on a downward path, and economic growth and pri- vate consumption resumed swiftly. We argue that this was because ambitious expenditure reform was conducted in a growth-friendly manner as part of comprehensive adjustment programmes. Our study emphasises the key role of expenditure policies in explaining fiscal developments during EMU in the euro area. It finds that, almost all euro area countries (with the notable exception of Germany) applied expansionary expenditure policies already before the crisis. This resulted in much higher expenditure and debt paths compared to a counterfactual neutral expenditure stance. Rules- based spending policies could have led to much safer fiscal positions much more in line with the EU’s Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). The policy recommendations from these findings are obvious: countries should focus on reducing public spending in the context of ambitious reform programmes. Spending based consolidation efforts need to be complemented by structural reforms, notably with a view to removing rigidities in national labour and product markets, to reduce macroeconomic imbalances, improve competi- tiveness and support potential growth. This will be particularly important for the vulnerable countries in the euro area which do not have available the exchange rate mechanism to improve exter- nal competitiveness. Latest projections suggest that governments’ consolidation plans in a number of countries indeed put a focus on reducing government expenditure as a ratio to GDP in the coming years. However, the benefits of reforms are only going to materia- 337
  • 336. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? lise under one condition, namely that all these plans are fully and adequately implemented. This is their main challenge. In addition, the empirical evidence on the determinants of euro area countries’ expenditure stance provide a number of policy implications. First, strong national budgetary institutions seem to limit expansionary spending biases. Second, the European institu- tional framework needs to feature prominently expenditure moni- toring and control. The incorporation of an expenditure bench- mark in the preventive arm of the Stability and Growth Pact in the context of the recent “Six-Pack” reform therefore constitutes a step in the right direction. An effective enforcement of this rule should help to limit overly expansionary spending policies in the future. Furthermore, this chapter argues that a potential growth rule with an extra ½ percentage point deduction from the resulting annual expenditure growth targets would be a sufficiently prudent and, thus, advisable expenditure rule for euro area countries. As economic (e.g., population aging) and political economy reasons suggest that overestimating potential growth could also occur in the future, such a rule could provide a reasonably prudent bench- mark for a neutral expenditure stance looking forward. How does the debate on the overhaul of European economic gover- nance fare against these conclusions? At the time of completing this study (March 2012), EU member states have set up new EU economic governance principles with a view to ensuring a tighter and more 338
  • 337. The Future of the Euro effective surveillance of economic and fiscal policies at the European level. At the same time, policy makers have agreed - in the context of the new fiscal pact - to strengthen national fiscal frameworks. All in all, a stringent implementation and enforcement of the fiscal surveillance at European level could well ensure the necessary break with past expenditure trends and thus also secure sustainable deficits and debt dynamics in the future. However, it remains to be seen whether the main obstacle of the “old framework”—lack of incentives and enforcement—is really sufficiently remedied. Bibliography - Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1995) Fiscal expansions and adjustments in OECD countries, Economic Policy, vol. 10, pp. 205–48. - Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1997) Fiscal adjustments in OECD countries: Composition and macroeconomic effects, IMF Staff Papers, vol. 44, pp. 210–48. - Brück, T. and R. Zwiener (2006) Fiscal policy rules for stabilisation and growth: A simulation analysis of deficit and expenditure targets in a mone- tary union, Journal of Policy Modeling, 28, 357–369. - Cimadomo, J. (2008) Fiscal policy in real time, Working Paper 919, European Central Bank. 339
  • 338. Public expenditure policies during the EMU period: Lessons for the future? - Coenen, G, C., Erceg, C. Freedman, D. Furceri, M. Kumhof, R. Lalonde, D. Laxton, J. Lindé, A. Mourougane, D. Muir, S. Mursula, C. de Resende, J. Roberts, W. Roeger, S. Snudden, M. Trabandt and J. in’t Veld (2010) Effects of fiscal stimulus in structural models, Working Paper, 10/73, International Monetary Fund. - Debrun, X., L. Moulin, A. Turrini, J. Ayuso-i-Casals and M. Kumar (2008) Tied to the mast? National fiscal rules in the European Union, Economic Policy, 23 (54), 297–362. - European Commission (2006) Public finances in EMU - 2006, European Economy, 3, Brussels. - Hauptmeier, S., M. Heipertz and L. Schuknecht (2007) Expenditure reform in industrialised countries: a case study approach, Fiscal Studies, 28 (3), 293-342. - Hauptmeier, S., A.J. Sánchez-Fuentes and L. Schuknecht (2007) Towards expenditure rules and fiscal sanity in the euro area, Journal of Policy Modeling, 33, 597-617. - Holm-Hadulla, F., S. Hauptmeier and P. Rother (2010) The impact of numerical expenditure rules on budgetary discipline over the cycle, Working Paper 1169, European Central Bank. - International Monetary Fund (2011) Shifting Gears Tackling Challenges on the Road to Fiscal Adjustment, IMF Fiscal Monitor, April 2011, Washington D.C. 340
  • 339. The Future of the Euro - Menguy, S. (2008) A dynamic rule applied to the threshold imposed on the European budgetary deficits, Journal of Policy Modeling, 30, 1093–1105. - Morris, R. and L. Schuknecht (2007) Structural balances and revenue windfalls - the role of asset prices revisited, Working Paper 737, European Central Bank. - Poterba, J. and J. Von Hagen (eds.) (1999) Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. - Schuknecht, L. (2009) Booms, Busts and Fiscal Policy. Public Finances in the Future? London: Politeia. - Schuknecht, L. (2011) Fiscal activism in booms, busts and beyond, forth- coming in Banca d’Italia, 2011. - Tanzi, V. and L. Schuknecht (2000) Public Spending in the 20th century: a global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. - Turrini, A. (2008) Fiscal policy and the cycle in the Euro Area: The role of government revenue and expenditure, European Economy - Economic Papers 323, European Commission. - Van Riet, A. (ed.) (2010) Euro area fiscal policies and the crisis, Occasional Paper 109, European Central Bank. - Wierts, P. (2008) How do expenditure rules affect fiscal behaviour?, DNB Working Paper 166. 341